A. Introduction
The EU faces a conundrum: The organization of economic activity remains transnational, whilst the turn to populism, nationalism, and even nativism, heightens the political shift to viewing the national level as the only legitimate site of regulation. After Brexit and in the era of Trump and resurgent nationalism, what are the prospects for the EU to (re)gain legitimacy as a source of transnational regulation?
The focus of this Article is on the (perceived) unresponsiveness of elite institutions, most notably the EU, to popular interests wary of globalization, from both the political left and right. The EU has been described as a “market without a state,”Footnote 1 with the concomitant problems of political legitimacy and democratic accountability which arise when market integration and economic governance take place at supranational level in the absence of a supranational polity. This rightly gives rise to concerns about the viability of democratic control over capitalism. The irony is, however, that the regionalism of the European Union is—or rather, has in the past been—an important institutional counterpoint to, and bulwark against, the worst effects of neoliberal globalization.
B. Then: Embedding Capitalism Nationally—and Regionally
It is clear that “economic law,” in other words, law which “institutionalizes markets and provides for their functioning,”Footnote 2 and which encompasses private economic ordering—of contracts, of corporations, of private property, of competition—as well as public ordering through social regulation—such as product safety, environmental law, labor and social welfare law—has increasingly been relocated away from the state.
Historically, liberal market economies, such as those of the states of the EU, were able to establish social cohesion and solidarity, and to govern or embed capitalism, for example, in order to enact labor standards.Footnote 3 Labor law scholarship has traditionally focused on the role of the state and its capacity, or otherwise, to regulate a territorially bounded market to socialize economic risk and uncertainty. But capital and the sphere of economic interaction are increasingly de-territorialized. Therefore, we also need to ask whether, from the perspective of labor regulation, economic activity—in particular that which crosses national borders—can any longer be contained within or constrained by state regulation, and the attendant role of regulation on the regional or transnational plane. Alain Supiot describes the social state as merely a mode for the realization of the objective of social solidarity. He talks of conceiving “an international legal order that will prohibit the use of open borders to escape the duties of solidarity inherent in the recognition of economic and social rights.”Footnote 4
This state capacity was considerably bolstered by being part of a regional integration project, an international legal order, namely the European Union. One might even argue that a significant source of legitimacy for EU action was precisely its ability to institutionalize markets which are no longer territorially bound; to embed markets at the regional level, and thus enable national, democratic control over capitalism.
This might not have been the original understanding of the EEC project. Although ordoliberal theory is by no means the only conception of the economy to inform European integration, it has shaped legal discourse, in particular, in its view that the original treaties entrenched a particular version of the free market economic constitution.Footnote 5 The German ordoliberal conception of the competitive market order argues that the economy functions best when self-coordination of economic actors through market transactions or competition is left unimpeded by law. Whilst it did require a coherent legal framework to guarantee individual freedoms and the economic process, ordoliberal thinkers perceived the original Treaty of Rome, and the creation of supranational European integration project, as “taming” the nation state in order to make the region a better home for free-moving capital.Footnote 6 The Treaty of Rome is therefore idealized by ordoliberals as the paradigm economic constitution in that it appeared to concern exclusively economic rights; those elements of the Treaty, as subsequently amended, which go beyond pure market integration are considered as imperfections. Yet, it is precisely those imperfections that enable the EU regionalism project to operate to embed capitalism. As Floris de Witte notes, contrary to the ordoliberal paradigm, the aim of integration in the form of completion of the internal market was not to free the economy from political constraints, “but rather to support and insulate the capacity to constrain the economy at the national level, where sufficiently strong political structures existed.”Footnote 7
Thus, whilst there are tensions between nationalism and the transnational, it is not necessarily the case that in an era of multi-level governance, the regional or transnational is inherently about dispossessing, disembedding, or weakening the social for the sake of the market.Footnote 8
Nevertheless, is the postwar marriage of democracy and capitalism, as Wolfgang Streeck has suggested,Footnote 9 at an end? I would answer this question with the observation that democracy is not compatible with market fundamentalism, but that in the global North in the postwar era, it was, in large part, compatible with an “embedded liberal” bargain. As Polanyi observed, “[t]he road to a free market was opened and kept open by an enormous increase in continuous, centrally organized and controlled interventionism;” laissez faire was planned.Footnote 10 Whether within liberal market economies or coordinated market economies, there was an acceptance that capitalism or trade liberalization had to be embedded in society and hence in democracy and some version of collectivism.Footnote 11
Where I disagree with Streeck is in the role he attributes to supranational, regional bodies such as the EU: Doubting the possibility of the EU project being constitutionalized, or the scope for a supranational democracy to emerge from international capitalism.Footnote 12 Nevertheless, this rejection of the region as a legitimate site of regulation ignores the history of how for industrialized economies of the global North, including those in Europe, the protection of society from the market occurred due to the evolution in the protective capacities of individual states, but crucially also the evolution in the protective capacities of the region.
C. Now: The EU’s Role in Hastening the Disembedding of Capitalism
The period during which the EU integration project and, in particular, its social policy, served as a bulwark to the ability of member states to embed the market, has come to an abrupt end—ironically, at the same time that the Treaties commit the Union to creating “a highly competitive social market economy.”Footnote 13 The response of EU institutions to the sovereign debt crisis has led to a weakening of social and labor rights, and an erosion of social solidarity, which has contributed to the intensification of populist tendencies.Footnote 14 Long before this current crisis, the Lisbon Strategy, the Employment Strategy, and the “open method of coordination” (OMC)Footnote 15 can be said to have undermined the very social objectives which might ameliorate the operation of markets. The background values and norms of EU economic policy in general, and the Stability and Growth Pact and Economic and Monetary Union in particular,Footnote 16 constrain national employment and economic policy and necessitate strict fiscal discipline, restrictions on public expenditure, modernization of social protection systems, and structural reforms to make labor markets economically responsive and enhance their competitiveness. As van Apeldoorn observes, such asymmetric multilevel governance ensures that socio-economic policy-making is structurally biased towards policies of neoliberal restructuring.Footnote 17
Social objectives and governance have lost way to, and been subsumed within, the broader economic policy governance of the European Semester: An annual cycle of coordination and surveillance of the EU’s economic policies, involving detailed scrutiny of Member States’ plans for macroeconomic, budgetary, and structural reforms.Footnote 18 An optimistic reading is that economic policy coordination has been “socialized” with social policy objectives—for example, poverty and social inclusion—increasingly being included in the—relatively “hard law”—institutional and policy framework of the European Semester.Footnote 19 A more convincing reading, however, is that EU social policy lacks autonomy and is increasingly contained within an institutional framework, which requires such policy to be “growth–friendly” and to ensure fiscal stability. Rather than shielding workers—and others—from the market, the aim of EU social policy becomes to facilitate their operation in the market whilst also facilitating market integration.Footnote 20
And the role of the EU in exacerbating such disembedding—in urging the retrenchment of national welfare states, in downgrading the redistributive aspirations of social policy, and in the general incursions against labor law and labor market institutions—ensures it is a strong target for anti-globalization sentiment.
D. Next: A Category Error — Market Fundamentalism Turned Inwards
The resistance from countries in the global South to forms of transnational regulation, for example of the sort imposed by structural adjustment, is now, through curious reversal, being mirrored by opposition to transnational regulation in countries in the global North. The slogan of the Leave campaign in the UK, advocating the UK’s exit from the European Union, was “take back control;” that resonated with the claim of Donald Trump to “Make America Great Again” and to place “America First.” Both sets of slogans imply a nostalgia, or rather a fantasy, for a lost state: One which is fully sovereign, unfettered by international or supranational obligations, freed from the constraints of a liberalized global trading regime, whose rules it had been responsible for crafting, and—most significantly—almost entirely free from migrants.
One of the examples of the unease being expressed by observers in the global North is in relation to mega-regional trade agreements, such as the now-defunct Transatlantic Trade and Investment Partnership (TTIP).Footnote 21 TTIP, if ratified, would have imposed an investment law regime stripping these sovereign states of their policy space and regulatory autonomy, and doing so in a manner reminiscent of the experience of states of the global South, which witnessed investment treaty law and bilateral agreements as a continuation of predatory capitalism and neocolonialism in a supposed postcolonial era. There is a similar symmetry between the deregulatory reform policies being imposed on those EU member states receiving financial support from the Troika of the European Commission, European Central Bank and IMF, and the effect of structural adjustment programs implemented by the IMF and the World Bank on markets in developing states from the 1970s onwards. In both cases—neocolonial trade agreements compared with the new wave of “mega-regional” agreements and structural adjustment compared with austerity as a response to sovereign debt crisis—the techniques of neoliberal governance are following a pattern first trialed on the global South. European states are experiencing this as a category error, in part because they have not been on the receiving end of such policies, but most importantly because it is the rest of the world which has been subject to the economic power of their corporations and investment law regimes.
This market fundamentalism is now turned inwards on the EU states themselves. Whether we agree with Hien and Joerges that Anglo-American neoliberalism rather than German ordoliberalism has been in the ideational driver’s seat of EU economic policy since the 1980s,Footnote 22 it is clear that the original imperatives behind Europe’s economic constitution have returned with a vengeance. A major challenge for the 2020s is whether the EU can finally address the question of what it means to construct a polity that proceeds from economic rationality to social justice. At certain points in its evolution, it has been able to adopt alternative visions of the economy, which do allow for the possibility of market–correcting intervention. Nonetheless, on current form—illustrated by neoliberal responses to the present crises—it is difficult to envisage how the EU can succeed in institutionalizing a labor or social constitution (Arbeitsverfassung) to hold in check or counter the emergence of an economic constitution (Wirtschaftsverfassung).Footnote 23
Streeck argues that democracy can be made compatible with contemporary capitalism, but only by safeguarding or shielding the redistributive potential of democratic politics from the worse aspects of free markets, from financialized disembedded capitalism. The surrendering of state sovereignty to global finance capital and the withdrawal of the EU from its sometimes role in supporting such state capacity certainly makes it much more difficult to create or maintain democratically determined collective values and institutions.