Introduction
The deadliest garment factory accident in human history occurred when Rana Plaza, an eight-story commercial building located in Savar, Bangladesh, collapsed killing approximately 1,134 ready-made garment (RMG) factory workers on 24 April 2013.Footnote 1 Before its collapse, Rana Plaza illegally continued as a factory site with a politically influential building owner and economically powerful factory owners. The garment factories operating in Rana Plaza were either suppliers or sub-contractors to retailers or brands situated mostly in the industrialized countries of the North.Footnote 2 Offering the lowest production cost, Bangladesh is an attractive sourcing choice for foreign brands/retailers and ranks as the world’s second-largest RMG supplier.Footnote 3 Despite the fact that Bangladesh’s RMG sector creates employment opportunities for millions and earns a huge export income, the tragic nature of the Rana Plaza collapse depicts the bitter reality of the globalized market and exploitative work conditions in the factories of developing countries and the loose contractual relationship between brand/retailers and low-skill labourers. While brands/retailers from all around the world enjoy the mobility of sourcing from the lowest-cost producers, and producing firms/suppliers enjoy government patronage (through favourable tax and investment policies), millions of impoverished garment workers—mostly women—work at rock-bottom wages, with poor or negative work entitlements, and put their lives and wellbeing at risk.
Considering this background, this article critically reviews some scholarly proposals for linking transnational labour governance (TLG) to trade/economic cooperation agreements or arrangements.Footnote 4 It is claimed that if appropriately designed, these hybrid linkage mechanisms, with their region- or country-specific setting, context-sensitive analysis, and capacity to improve domestic labour regulatory capacity, would provide important market-complementary interventions. These TLG mechanisms seek to lessen the pressures of a globalized market and address multiple problems of labour deregulation by monitoring factory-level working conditions, offering assistance to national governments to monitor compliance with national or international labour standards, and/or tying preferential market access to conditions to strengthen or improve domestic labour regulatory institutions.
This article suggests that despite rich theoretical analyses on the structural form or design of TLG mechanisms, less attention has been paid to the narrow conceptualizations of the social or distributional issues.Footnote 5 While the concept of social or distributive justice covers wider issues such as allocation of resources, e.g., income, health, and education to weaker and marginalized/disadvantaged sections of society and assistance to displaced social groups,Footnote 6 this article uses the term social to refer mostly to labour issues.
Section 1 briefly summarizes how these narrow conceptualizations of the social issues affected the bargaining capacity of labourers and reshaped the function of labour law. While political disempowerment of labour as a group and freedom of corporate sourcing thwarted the bargaining capacity of labour, only labourers with a formal contractual relationship enjoyed limited work entitlements and the protection of labour law. A large majority of labourers was left at the mercy of producing/sourcing firms. Even the formal labourers became entitled to demand only fundamental labour rights and not the redistributive rights. The International Labour Organization’s (ILO’s) Declaration on Fundamental Principles and Rights at Work, adopted in 1998, commits member states to respect and promote four fundamental principles and rights at work: freedom of association, effective recognition of the right to collective bargaining, elimination of forced or compulsory labour and abolition of child labour, and elimination of discrimination in respect of employment and occupation. These ILO-prescribed rights widely referred to as core/fundamental labour rights do not include redistributive rights, i.e. minimum wages, work safety, maximum work hours, job security, unemployment benefits, etc.Footnote 7
The restrictive form of labour governance gave rise to some distributional problems, i.e. existing labour laws offered limited benefits only for formal workers, downplayed collective action rights, emphasized voluntary forms of factory monitoring, and weakened the participation of non-state actors in the monitoring process.
Section 2 discusses three different types of scholarly proposals for linkage: linkage through corporate social responsibility (CSR); linkage through global institutional framework; and finally, linkage through social clause mechanisms (SCM) in bilateral/regional trade or economic cooperation agreements or arrangements. Most of these proposals focus on domestic labour regulatory problems, in that they discuss how to improve the performance of domestic regulatory institutions. The distributional problems of labour and how these have contributed to labour deregulation remain largely unexplored in these analyses.
This article connects the theoretical analysis with some real-life examples. Referring to some of the challenges of labour governance in Bangladesh and the recent transnational safety initiatives (TSIs)Footnote 8 taken to ensure safety of RMG workers after the collapse of Rana Plaza,Footnote 9 this article posits that it is important to embrace a broader understanding of different rights of labourers and their conditions of work and bridge the existing gap between regulatory and distributional problems of labour.
1. Narrow Conceptualizations of the Social and the Effects on Labour Governance
After World War II, the market integration process ensured a “double movement” under which trade liberalization was accompanied by “social citizenship rights and social welfare entitlements, at least for the paradigmatic worker in the North.”Footnote 10 Influenced by Polanyi’s sociological theory of market “embeddedness,” Footnote 11 Ruggie’s famous “embedded liberalism” depicts this new form of state-market relationship where each state participating in the liberal market system reserved the power to determine its social policies and address social dislocations.Footnote 12
At around the same time, international development and financial institutions (IDFIs), such as the World Bank and the International Monetary Fund became involved in designing the national development policies of the newly independent developing countries. During the 1990s, these institutions supported neo-liberal responses and prescribed a single and uniform template of rules and institutions with which to build market-based societies and achieve economic development.Footnote 13 Strict separation was maintained between the process of constructing appropriate legal rules and institutions to promote economic development objectives and the process of addressing social justice concerns.Footnote 14 By erecting permanent barriers between questions of law and social justice, development and distributional policies, and market efficiency and social equity, neo-liberals promoted the neo-classical economic idea and suggested optimum allocation of resources to ensure efficiency in production. In the process of allocation of resources, they argued, it is not necessary to monitor the possible adverse impacts on different social groups.Footnote 15 No space was left to address the tensions, failures, risks, or externalities arising from market-based development.Footnote 16
The subordination of the social continued through neo-liberal assurances that adverse social/distributional consequences, if any, would be experienced for a short period of time, and in the long term, the “rising tide” of economic growth would lift “all boats.”Footnote 17 When the neo-liberal prescriptions failed, the IDFIs adopted a revised development policy, which became popularly known as the “post-Washington consensus.”Footnote 18 Even though social justice was a goal to be attained within the reformed development policy, market-oriented rules and institutions shaped the “conceptual” meaning of the social and determined the process of attaining social goals.Footnote 19 According to Rittich, this view created a particular framework for social concerns: these are “matters of politics” and would eventually be dealt with as a result of “spillover” benefits from economic growth.Footnote 20
These narrow conceptualizations prioritized the interests of capital owners and required that attention to labour issues be secondary. While at a national level neo-liberal prescriptions suggested limited governmental intervention to develop effective regulatory institutions or finance public goods, at the international level trade liberalization and mobility of capital allowed corporations unconditional freedom to source from business-friendly locations where labour laws or their enforcement are relaxed. Connecting these multiple effects of globalization, it can be seen that labour deregulation is not simply a result of poor regulatory institutions in developing countries. Although internal political problems, corruption, and policy choices have contributed to poor labour governance in developing countries, five far-reaching effects can be identified from the narrow conceptualizations.
First, a sharp division developed between fundamental and redistributive rights of labourers. Globalized production systems and unconditional mobility of capital gave rise to “market-centered model(s) of social inclusion and equality.”Footnote 21 Entitlements in the form of respect for fundamental rights were argued to provide the “entry point” for accessing the market.Footnote 22 These generalized fundamental rights emphasize only the “[e]nabling rights that allow workers to associate together and to bargain collectively. There has been a shift away from the state imposition of substantive standards towards the provision of procedures enabling the parties to establish their own norms. This is part of a broader shift from government to governance or from hard to soft law, particularly in the realm of the social.”Footnote 23 These “core labour rights co-exist comfortably with the idea that rights of workers need not be enforceable entitlements, nor need labour be consulted in the design of market institutions.”Footnote 24
These changes reshaped the function of labour law. Instead of limiting the market’s capability to affect labour rights, labour law emphasized compliance with some fundamental rights. Discussions on redistributive functions of labour law are marginalized or ignored.Footnote 25 No importance is placed on the mutually constitutive relationship between fundamental and redistributive rights in enhancing the dignity, wellbeing, and capability of labourers.
Second, unconditional mobility of capital caused significant changes in the bargaining capacity of labour. Constant fear stemming from capital’s power to relocate to more hospitable places created an increased “risk of underbidding” by labourers.Footnote 26 For many developing countries, where competitiveness is equated with low-cost labour, the primary question became not their workers’ right to earn a living wage or to work in a safe workplace, but how to retain competitiveness and avoid allegations of “social dumping” of goods and products in countries with higher social standards.Footnote 27
Third, a top-down formula of distribution developed. While most economic and trade literature promoted the idea that multilateral trade cooperation contributes to overall net economic gains, IDFIs prescribed that social/distributional concerns should be addressed at a national level and after economic growth has been achieved.Footnote 28 Poverty was explained as the inability of developing states to adapt to the demands of market, and accordingly, policies were prescribed in order to improve their market participation capacity.Footnote 29
Fourth, total or partial exclusion from the protection of labour law became the defining feature of the new “work relationships.”Footnote 30 The portion of informal labourers (in developing countries) and the portion of labourers who fell outside labour law (in developed countries) grew at an exponential rate. Only formal labourers became entitled to receive the protection of labour law.
Fifth, an individualized approach to the enforcement of labour laws restricted or opposed the exercise of collective rights. According to Lord Wedderburn, “individualization” of labour rights explains why collective bargaining and industrial pressure at a transnational level were the most difficult activities.Footnote 31 Only unionized formal labourers are allowed to take advantage of limited protections offered by national labour laws. As a result, no effective transnational labour class has emerged to confront the power and capacity of globalized production systems.Footnote 32
Without referring to the labour deregulation resulting from the narrow conceptualizations of the social, various proposals tried to link TLG with a trade or economic governance framework.
2. A Critical Review of the Proposals for Linkage
2.1 Linkage through Cross-border Extension of CSR
To minimize the power of capital to affect labour relations, some scholars proposed the cross-border extension of CSR to maintain minimum social rights in overseas production or supplier factories of multinational corporations (MNCs).Footnote 33 Most CSR approaches, such as Sullivan principles, social partnership, and socially minimum standards, rely on non-binding corporate commitment for ensuring effective labour governance. Under Sullivan principles, home states of MNCs would oblige them to invest in countries that follow minimum social and environmental standards.Footnote 34 The social partnership approach requires MNCs to follow CSR codes to improve the situations of their overseas employees. Socially minimum standards both for work entitlements and workplace conditions attempt to extend CSR to the supply chains of MNCs.Footnote 35
However, as discussed in the previous section, the emphasis on voluntary and flexible CSR codes can be connected to the neo-liberal prescription on labour deregulation. Most CSR codes are not only unilaterally adopted, but also choose selective fundamental rights, avoid legal enforceability of redistributive rights, focus on voluntary monitoring, and are “limited in coverage,” meaning that they apply only to the formal employees of a direct supply chain.Footnote 36
Recent research suggests that CSR codes—when combined with robust approaches, such as the inclusion of non-state actors in factory monitoring, regularity in the monitoring process, and technological and organizational assistance to suppliers—could improve factory-level working conditionFootnote 37 and complement domestic labour regulation.Footnote 38 Taking a cautious approach, Anne Trebilcock finds that it is difficult to monitor corporate compliance with due diligence, especially for ensuring collective labour rights or supply chain workers’ rights.Footnote 39 In a similar tone, Martin argues that although CSR codes have evolved by prescribing ILO standards, workers’ collective action rights are significantly downplayed. Footnote 40
Therefore despite its potential, CSR could be “used as a vehicle for a neo-liberal deregulatory agenda” and might promote a “technocratic” and “managerialist” type of “self-regulation” by powerful actors.Footnote 41 Shamir argues, tellingly, that in some situations, CSR is used in a way that “diffuses its potentially radical application to MNCs” and “fits the hegemonic neoliberal framework.”Footnote 42 For example, corporate freedom to relocate production or sourcing facilities creates “downward pressure” on the already low labour standards in developing countries,Footnote 43 and voluntary compliance with low-standard laws are deemed sufficient for doing business. It is alleged that some CSR codes are drafted without necessary inputs from labourersFootnote 44 and might undermine the development of effective public labour regulatory systems.Footnote 45 Also, factory monitoring with little or no participation from non-state actors or independence of auditors from the parent or sponsoring corporations raises significant doubts on the effectiveness of CSR.
Repeated factory accidents in Bangladesh vividly illustrate some of the limitations of CSR codes. Prior to the collapse of Rana Plaza, a fire at Tazreen fashions, another RMG factory in Dhaka, caused the death of approximately 112 factory workers who were trapped into a locked premise when the fire started.Footnote 46 Some of the brands/retailers for whom the suppliers or sub-contractors were producing at Rana Plaza and Tazreen were subject to corporate codes or monitoring. Yet, none could stop forced work when fire alarms sounded at Tazreen or visible cracks appeared in the building columns of Rana Plaza.Footnote 47 Some retailers and brands admit that inspections only cover factory-floor safety issues and do not cover the structural soundness of the factory building.Footnote 48
At the collapsed building site, although labour rights activists found documents and garments of twenty-nine brands and retailers, initially only half of the companies with recent or current orders to five garment factories committed to contribute to the Rana Plaza compensation fund.Footnote 49 Denying compensation, some reputed apparel brands questioned the existence of a formal relationship with the producing factories: one argued that there was “no formal contractual relationship” with the supplier and it was a “test” order; others argued that an unauthorized contractor was producing garments without their knowledge or no supply was due “at the time of collapse.”Footnote 50
After the Rana Plaza collapse, two corporate safety initiatives, North American Alliance and Accord,Footnote 51 attempted to cover fire and building safety for workers who have a formal employment relationship with the supplier companies. A narrow range of formal workers employed in 1,894 factories is covered out of the 5,000 to 6,000 garment factories in Bangladesh.Footnote 52 Subcontractors, who do not have direct and formal contractual relationship with brands or retailers, are excluded from the coverage of these corporate initiatives.
Thus, the effectiveness of CSR in addressing the deeper consequences of labour deregulation remains questionable. How should independent and transparent monitoring throughout the supply chain be established?Footnote 53 If monitoring covers compliance with fundamental rights, what about redistributive rights? How to ensure that CSR reserves some space for enforcement of collective rights of workers? How far can legal responsibility be extended not only for direct suppliers, but also for those connected directly or indirectly with the supply chain?Footnote 54 Recognizing the limitations of CSR, some scholars argue for labour governance through global institutional frameworks.
2.2 Linkage through Institutional Frameworks
Some linkage claims suggest that an effective global institution would delineate the appropriate relationship between market opening and labour governance and provide adequate threats or incentives to undertake necessary institutional reforms in developing countries.
2.2.1 Reforming the World Trade Organization (WTO)
Andrew Guzman proposes reforming the WTO by establishing two separate departments.Footnote 55 A trade department would deal with purely trade issues and a labour department would oversee compliance with labour issues.Footnote 56 While both departments would continue their functions on trade and labour issues respectively, neither would “negotiate agreements that bear directly on the other’s area of expertise.”Footnote 57 Only during periodic mega rounds would these departments initiate “cross-issue talks” and discuss appropriate relationships between labour and trade, attempting to reach a political solution. During mega rounds, states in favour of linking labour-based exceptions to trade obligations would offer further concessions, such as WTO-plus market access. For Guzman, the long and complex process through mega rounds, though imperfect, is the “best” chance to reach a “negotiated, consensual agreement on trade and labour issue[s]” within the WTO.Footnote 58
According to Guzman, the WTO’s political body is a better forum to address linkage of trade and labour than the ILO, since the latter lacks an effective enforcement mechanism to address violations of labour rights.Footnote 59 He discusses how the WTO can accommodate trade-based sanctions, though he acknowledges that the effectiveness of sanctions in improving labour conditions in a sanctioned state remains an open question.Footnote 60 Without connecting the exiting labour governance problems with neo-liberal prescriptions, he focused on how social commitments of developing countries can be broadened and enforced through trade-based sanctions.Footnote 61 He overlooked the fact that either by ratifying the ILO core conventions or entering into bilateral or regional trade agreements, most developing countries have already assumed broad social obligations. Thus it is not just the question of commitment to fundamental labour rights or their paper-based enforcement that matters for effective labour regulation; the deeper labour governance problems in developing countries need a holistic analysis. Bangladesh is an excellent example to prove this point.
The International Trade Union Confederation’s (ITUC) report, prepared in 2012 and submitted to the WTO General Council, vividly describes the disparities between Bangladesh’s formal international commitments and domestic labour rules and practices.Footnote 62 Although Bangladesh has ratified thirty-five ILO conventions, including seven fundamental conventions, and adopted the “ILO Declaration on Fundamental Rights and Principles at Work,” the report finds systematic violations of fundamental labour standards not only in practice, but also through existing rules.Footnote 63 Therefore, it is much more important to focus on designing an effective “incentive-based” (not sanction-based) institutional framework that can realistically address labour governance problems in developing countries.Footnote 64
2.2.2 Reforming the WTO and the ILO
Under Barry and Reddy’s incentive-based institutional mechanism, developing countries would commit to improve existing labour governance in return for developed countries’ positive inducements, such as WTO-plus market access and burden-sharing arrangements to fund necessary improvements.Footnote 65 According to Barry and Reddy, administration of the linkage system by a “rule-based” mechanism following “transparent, participatory and consensual” procedures would effectively address the problem of “opportunistic use” of social clauses in trade agreements.Footnote 66 With the ability to impose sanctions as a measure of last resort and only for “egregious and systematic” violations of labour rights, the proposed mechanism would be more acceptable to the developing countries who oppose linkage for fear of protectionism. They suggest that one such possible system is to reform both the ILO and the WTO to form an “Agency for Trade and Labour Standards.”Footnote 67
Barry and Reddy’s proposal focuses on the form of linkage rather than the contents of labour rights.Footnote 68 However, determining the form of linkage crucially depends on the labour rights that are intended to be protected. A focus on fundamental and redistributive rights would certainly entail a greater administrative and financial burden than a focus on fundamental rights only.
Their market-based linkage proposal focuses on improved labour governance through global financial assistance and monitoring and secures limited benefit for workers engaged with exporting firms. They do not explain what happens when exporting firms lose their competitive advantage. Broader issues like assistance to developing countries for retaining existing competitive advantages through improved labour skills or greater access to the “ideas” and “technologies” from MNCs or developed countriesFootnote 69 are not explored in their proposal. While it sounds too ambitious to consider such extended labour governance programs (including labour skill upgrading) through incentive based trade/economic agreements or arrangements, in a real-life scenario it is considered as one of the most efficient ways to prevent the race towards the bottom.Footnote 70 The terms of trade for RMG products “are failing at around 2 percent a year”Footnote 71 in Bangladesh. In order to maintain the existing competitive advantage in RMG manufacturing, the available options are either continuous lowering of production costs and labour entitlements or improvement of labour productivity. Without giving attention to the latter, it would be harder to sustain the improvements in labour governance.
According to Barry and Reddy, only with trade incentives is it possible to expect “action” in terms of financial commitment on the part of countries in the North that are “sites of ownership, registration and management of firms.”Footnote 72 Without any powerful incentive such as the “ability to impose limitations on rights to trade,” “it would be unfair to require Northern countries that do not actively participate in conduct that undermines labor standards to make net transfers to those that do….”Footnote 73 Barry and Reddy do not explore whether the North would still be interested in joining and funding an international linkage system if, through expansive bilateral or regional trade agreements, they could require signatory developing countries to follow fundamental labour standards.
Barry and Reddy’s argument that the North did not contribute to weakening of labour standards in developing countries remains a highly contested issue. Proposals for imposing minimum labour standards in developing countries have met counter-arguments, from global egalitarians, to adopting these with fair trade policies such as opening markets for developing countries’ goods and products, significant fund transfers to address effective labour governance, and ensuring fairness in competition.Footnote 74 It is argued that “sweatshop-labour” is itself a “product, at least in part, of decisions made over the decades by wealthier countries and consumers.”Footnote 75 Overlooking these reasoned arguments of global egalitarians, their proposal focuses on finding fairness for the North’s involvement in the global labour governance program and fails to explore the devastating outcome of neo-liberal prescriptions for developing countries, which are situated mostly in the South.
Finally, Barry and Reddy argue that increased market access and financial assistance from burden-sharing funds offers crucial incentives to secure the participation of developing countries in the linkage system. However, referring to Bangladesh’s RMG sector it can safely be argued that financial commitments alone cannot address some of the distributional problems of labour. In Bangladesh, the “outsized” influence of RMG factory owners in the Parliament not only ensures enactment of favourable tax and necessary legislation, but also causes a delay in regulatory reforms on labour law and impedes proposals for “oversight” of this important export sector.Footnote 76 Apart from the huge supply of unskilled workers, the political influence of the factory owners largely contributes to the prevalence of low wages and the negative entitlement of factory workers. Despite being the world’s second largest RMG supplier,Footnote 77 a Bangladeshi factory worker’s average monthly wage continues to remain the lowest in the world and work conditions “have been amongst the worst in the global garments industry.”Footnote 78
It is true that effective monitoring by an independent and credible global institution, financial commitments, and strong domestic institutions would improve labour conditions and wages for a limited time period. However, in order to sustain the improvements in labour governance, it is necessary to connect these multidimensional governance challenges and track down the root causes of the disparities between capital and labour. Only through a context-based analysis of all these challenges, i.e. why and how the political disempowerment of labour started and how the bargaining capacity of labour decreased, is it possible to design and sustain an effective labour regulatory framework that would distribute the social gains from increased economic growth.
2.3 Linkage through a Social Clause Mechanism (SCM)
In trade or economic cooperation agreements, a SCM aims to establish a minimum floor of rights in signatory countries as a condition for preferential market access. Within the WTO, developing countries’ fear of protectionism caused the demise of the proposal for inclusion of a SCM.Footnote 79 In 1995, the ILO’s Governing Council decided to suspend analyses on a SCM and the link between international trade and labour standards.Footnote 80
Proponents of a SCM argue that regions possess both a distinctive understanding of social dislocations and a capacity to tailor a region-specific approach.Footnote 81 As parties negotiate the terms of agreement, the prescribed standards are context-sensitive and monitoring compliance entails minimal cost.Footnote 82 Also, compliance by exporting firms would eventually cause spillover benefits for non-exporting firms and improve the public labour regulatory system of the developing partner.Footnote 83
Critics argue that a SCM prevents a “race towards the top” for fear of losing existing competitive advantage.Footnote 84 In situations of non-compliance, sanctions might be used for political or protectionist purposes against trading partners with weaker social institutions. Hepple argues that until now, a sanction-based social clause has neither “effectively barred” products/services from low-standard countries,Footnote 85 nor has it produced any positive result for their labourers.
Kevin Kolben suggests that the “state action-state sanction” model of linkage is “ill-suited to developing countries with dysfunctional regulatory regimes.”Footnote 86 Instead, an incentive-based SCM makes it easier to address specific problems of developing partners through “creative solutions.”Footnote 87 Kolben’s trade incentive–based “integrative linkage” (IL) accommodates a wider range of stakeholders than private labour regulatory mechanisms.Footnote 88 Including representatives from unions, businesses, non-state actors, government, and employers, his proposed trade and labour governance council (TLGC) would design and direct the IL mechanism through master and regional/local councils. The TLGC would decide the form of monitoring and choose an independent monitoring body to ensure compliance with a mandatory set of standards. Kolben insists that the local councils under the TLGC might develop “novel forms of mediation that bring together all stakeholders, including multinational corporations that do business in that industry.”Footnote 89
As an example of his IL model, Kolben cites the ILO’s Better Factories Cambodia programme.Footnote 90 Under the US-Cambodia Textile Agreement, US offered Cambodian garment exporters an increased quota bonus over and above the regularly agreed-upon yearly quota bonus. In exchange, Cambodia agreed to improve work conditions in its garment factories and allowed the ILO to inspect factory-level compliance with Cambodian labour law and international labour standards. The innovative features of the Better Factories Cambodia (such as, insistence on independent inspection through the ILO, public reporting on compliance, and tying Cambodia’s participation in the program to preferential market access) caused a unique integration of public-private labour regulatory regimes.Footnote 91
I agree with Kolben that, until now, the sanction-based social clause has only enriched the scholarly debates on linkage without producing any significant consensus at the political level.Footnote 92 However, in Kolben’s analysis, less attention has been given to some of the distributional problems of labour.
First, relying on Amartya Sen’s capability theory, Kolben creatively links the expansion of labour freedom with effective institutional development.Footnote 93 Yet, his IL model primarily emphasizes the ILO-prescribed fundamental labour rights. Although his proposed TLGC might include other labour rights or standards such as the right to a living wage,Footnote 94 there is no emphasis on the integral connection between fundamental and redistributive rights of labour.
The Rana Plaza collapse bitterly exposes this integral connection. Factory workers were forced to enter and continue working in the Rana Plaza, even though large cracks were visible in its columns and warnings were in place to avoid any use of the building.Footnote 95 Workers’ power to have a voice against conditions of work depends largely on the presence of effective factory-level unions. In Bangladesh’s RMG sector, there are “few factory-level organizations in the true sense of a trade union operation.”Footnote 96 While the absence of real unions weakens the voice of labour to demand work entitlements or workplace safety,Footnote 97 the absence of a living wage and other redistributive rights (such as maximum work hours and safe work conditions)Footnote 98 suppresses the voice of labour by corrupting or intimidating union leaders and/or activists.Footnote 99 A robust approach to labour governance thus requires not just a narrow focus on increased monitoring for formal workers of major exporting firms, but attention to the integral connections between the diverse rights of labour.
Second, for poor labour governance in developing countries, Kolben cites political and structural problems such as corruption, corporatist ties between the state, capital, and trade unions, and lesser allocation of government funds for labour ministries.Footnote 100 He finds that labour ministries are underfunded due to internal political choices such as the government’s priority to create an attractive investment environment.Footnote 101 His analysis of labour regulatory problems in developing countries places little emphasis on the disruptive influence of neo-liberal prescriptions in developing countries.
In Bangladesh, the political marginalization of labour started with the adoption of neo-liberal reforms towards the end of 1980s. International development and financial institutions’ prescribed institutional reforms changed both the capacity of union-based labour movements and government’s labour regulatory priorities; while union movements became highly “fractionalized,” demands for improved work conditions and wages became sporadic and unorganized, receiving limited political attention.Footnote 102 Upholding neo-liberal economic prescriptions, two bitterly divided political parties compete for power, emphasizing privatization, export-led growth, and trade liberalization. Neither has any substantial pro-labour agenda and, consequently, the labour ministry is under-funded. A weak regulatory capacity for labour governance in Bangladesh can be connected more with the “marginalization from current political settlement” than with the problem of resources.Footnote 103 Political disempowerment of labour and government’s minimal interest in effective labour regulation are reflected through the imbalanced ratio of inspectors to the number of factories. Despite having a 4.8% share in global clothing export, until the collapse of Rana Plaza, there were only 18 inspectors for 5,000 to 6,000 garment factories in Dhaka.Footnote 104
Third, Kolben finds that independent monitoring would generate information on compliance and, with such information, not only can consumers and businesses determine their buying and sourcing policies, but also NGOs, unions, and activists can pressure local employers and regulators to improve working conditions.Footnote 105 According to Kolben, while a factory-level performance comparison would pressure a race to the top, a comparative evaluation of public regulatory systems of trading partners would “potentially lead to greater regional integration in labor standards.”Footnote 106 In Kolben’s IL model, the emphasis is not on businesses’ responsibility to adopt an ethical sourcing strategy, but on their capacity to choose compliant producers or suppliers. The inevitable connection between corporate sourcing policies and poor working conditions in the factories of developing countries is not prioritized in his analysis.Footnote 107
Recently, under one of the corporate initiatives, the Accord, the signatory brands and retailers from over twenty countries in Europe, North America, Asia, and Australia committed to maintaining a long-term sourcing relationship and to negotiating contractual terms and pricing in a manner that would render it financially feasible for the suppliers to maintain a safe workplace and undertake necessary upgrades or remediation.Footnote 108 This “ethical” pricing policy attests to the essential relationship between labour conditions and corporate sourcing policies and practices.
It is necessary to connect the bargaining imbalances between labour and capital with the neo-liberal prescriptions. In accordance with the advice of IDFIs, national governments paved the way for doing business, privatized socio-economic responsibilities, and deregulated capital and financial markets. This allowed corporations unconditional freedom to transfer production facilities or to source from business-friendly locations where labour laws or their enforcement are relaxed. An effective TLG system should analyze these multi-dimensional effects of neo-liberal prescriptions in a holistic manner and not just rely on corporations’ goodwill to choose compliant sourcing factories.
Fourth, Kolben agrees that the monitoring under his IL model would cover only workers employed in major export industries that experience the “greatest rise in exports due to tariff liberalization.”Footnote 109 Kolben argues that the stakeholders in his IL model would eventually address the question of protecting labour in informal or non-export sectors.Footnote 110 What happens if indirect sourcing is a “routine” business practice of major exporting suppliers?Footnote 111 What happens if brands/retailers have de facto knowledge of the use of subcontractors? In a recent article, Baumann-Pauly, Labowitz, and Banerjee describe how indirect sourcing by Bangladeshi RMG suppliers is regularly tolerated by brands/retailers despite their written policy of zero tolerance for illegal sub-contracting.Footnote 112
As mentioned earlier, both corporate TSIs, North American Alliance and Accord, cover only the workers who have a formal contractual relationship with supplier companies. Though brands/retailers do not directly employ these low-cost and low-entitlement workers or allow unauthorized subcontracting, a connection exists between their high margin of profit and the use of these workers in their supply chains. There is evidence that most brands/retailers have de facto knowledge of their suppliers’ inability (in terms of number of machines and employees) to meet their large orders and their need to resort to the use of subcontractors. Yet they avoid direct contractual relationships with subcontractors in order to manage fewer contracts and still profit more from the lower price of bigger orders.Footnote 113
Thus despite the promises of the SCM, with emphasis on formal workers engaged by exporting firms and focus on multifaceted issues such as competition, investment, and intellectual property rights, in real-life these arrangements promote labour issues as a “secondary” concern.Footnote 114 The developing trading partners also appreciate limited attention to labour issues. The asymmetries between trade and labour agenda are reflected through the “means” used to enforce them; while trade opening is ensured through “hard” means, labour issues are addressed with “soft” means.Footnote 115 It is found that the EU’s bilateral trade treaties are mostly satisfied with dialogue-based cooperative mechanisms for improving labour standards of trading partners.Footnote 116
Deeper and broader redistributive questions, such as what social issues need to be addressed and who would be covered and how, remain on the periphery.Footnote 117 The “activist” and “robust” focus on market access without the necessary adjustment mechanisms being implemented at a bilateral or regional level “weakens nascent social integration in developing states.”Footnote 118
Therefore, any discussion on linkage should not focus only on the presence of a monitoring programme or the improvement of regulatory institutions that inspect compliance with national and international laws and standards. An effective linkage mechanism should cover broader redistributive questions, including the capacity of the developing partner(s) to design and fund an appropriate labour regulatory framework and connect labour governance with overall trade, economic, and redistributive policies. According to Kolben, “[i]t remains unclear … how much Cambodia’s regulatory capacity has grown [despite better monitoring].”Footnote 119 In a more recent publication, Kolben also argues for a “deeper market analysis” by the developed trading partner(s) to understand country-specific “structural organization” of labour market and impacts of trade liberalization, rather than taking a “formalistic, legal compliance oriented approach” to enforce labour rights.Footnote 120
Concluding Analysis
It is possible to extract some common features from the above-mentioned linkage proposals. Most scholars find that addressing the problems of poor regulatory institutions and low level of enforcement is the route to ensure effective labour governance in developing countries. Without connecting the existing disparities between developing and developed countries with regard to institutional development and capacity to offer social protection, the suggested mechanisms prefer effective monitoring or regulation. Discussions on neo-liberal policy prescriptions and governments’ minimum interest in labour regulation, the inherent connection between fundamental and redistributive rights of labour, the conditions of a semi-formal or informal workforce supplying to the exporting firms, and the connection between corporate sourcing policies and practices and poor work conditions do not receive any priority. Also, the prescribed mechanisms focus primarily on labourers engaged in exporting firms; improving labour skill and productivity or the importance of retaining existing competitive advantages for major exporting sector(s) of a developing country are not prioritized in these linkage proposals.
Particularly referring to some real-life challenges of Bangladesh’s RMG sector and the TSIs taken to improve labour governance, this article argues that, in order to design an effective TLG mechanism, the starting point should be a deeper and contextual analysis of the interconnected labour problems. It is necessary to consider the process of trade liberalization, the outcome of neo-liberal prescriptions, and the consequences of existing labour deregulation in a holistic frame. The suggestions of the IDFIs regarding the privatization of social responsibility, the deregulation of financial and capital markets, and reduced government spending for public institutions were different from the trade liberalization process undertaken as a result of accession to the GATT/WTO.Footnote 121 Yet due to the aggregate effect of promoting a liberalized market, corporate sourcing freedom, and reduced government spending on public goods, most low-income developing countries have experienced increasing levels of social inequities and poor human development despite increased trading.Footnote 122 Without giving appropriate attention to the root causes of these social disparities and labour deregulation and how these have created/aggravated the distributional problems of labour, the existing narrow focus on the structural form of linkage (such as CSR codes or global institutional monitoring or SCM) will not necessarily improve poor labour governance in developing countries, let alone develop the social institutions necessary to withstand the challenges of market integration.
Existing discussions on the structural form of linkage are important. Yet the incompatibility between the power and mobility of capital with vulnerability and immobility of labour at a global level creates a situation in which the pursuit of a redistributive agenda, through voluntary monitoring or through offering limited rights for formal workers, becomes questionable. An effective and sustainable labour governance through trade or economic agreements or arrangements needs to be viewed in the overall context of net economic benefits that a developing trading partner would receive (i.e., whether appropriate funds would be generated for improving the labour regulatory framework and undertaking broad redistributive programs),Footnote 123 the labour regulatory framework (covering labourers in sectors that would experience export growth), and social/redistributive policies (covering labourers dislocated due to trade opening). Any discussion on linkage of “the social into the economic”Footnote 124 thus requires a careful and detailed analysis of who (what development model is to be pursued), what (which labour rights are to be protected), and how. For example:
a. A development model that prioritizes market-based growth would only focus on monitoring and governance at exporting firms. On the other hand, attention to building a strong redistributive mechanism would focus on effective governance of formal, semi-formal, and informal labourers. The coverage of the latter is wider and enables us to focus beyond the economic empowerment of a narrow range of formal workers or voluntary forms of corporate responsibility. The broader mechanism realizes that improved labour governance does not routinely result from increased monitoring but starts by addressing the distributional problems that contribute to the uneven allocation of resources and power between workers and firms.
b. The protection of fundamental labour rights only entails a limited cost and offers limited and short-term benefit. On the other hand, if we consider that the protection of workplace entitlements, the economic and political empowerment of labour, and the strengthening of regulatory institutions are essentially interconnected, then a long-term and sustainable commitment on labour governance would be required.
c. Thirdly, it is important to consider how to realize these interconnected labour rights—how to fund and mobilize the development of necessary institutions and formulate necessary social/redistributive policies.Footnote 125 For example, in the case of bilateral or multilateral trade agreements or arrangements, it is necessary to consider the detailed framework of the governance of labourers who would be displaced due to trade opening.
Without a coherent and context-specific analysis of these interrelated issues, labour groups disadvantaged by market integration or disconnected from formal export sectors can expect very little from any linkage mechanism.