Hostname: page-component-586b7cd67f-rcrh6 Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-11-25T23:04:52.411Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

LEARNING AND THE SIZE OF THE GOVERNMENT SPENDING MULTIPLIER

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  13 June 2018

Ewoud Quaghebeur*
Affiliation:
Ghent University
*
Address correspondence to: Ewoud Quaghebeur, Ghent University, Sint-Pietersplein 6, B-9000 Ghent, Belgium; e-mail: [email protected]

Abstract

This paper examines the government spending multiplier when economic agents combine adaptive learning and knowledge about future fiscal policy to form their expectations. The analysis shows that the effects of a government spending shock substantially change when the rational expectations hypothesis is replaced by this learning mechanism. In contrast to the dynamics under rational expectations, a government spending shock in a small-scale new Keynesian DSGE model with learning crowds in private consumption and is associated with a positive comovement between real wages and hours worked. In the baseline calibration, the output multiplier under learning is above one and about twice as large as under rational expectations.

Type
Articles
Copyright
Copyright © Cambridge University Press 2018 

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

Footnotes

I would like to acknowledge the academic, financial, and technical support of Ghent University. I wish to express my very special thanks to Freddy Heylen for his support and useful comments throughout the development of this paper. I would also like to thank Brecht Boone, Tim Buyse, Gerdie Everaert, Punnoose Jacob, Gert Peersman, Céline Poilly, Raf Wouters, and two anonymous referees for helpful comments.

References

REFERENCES

Aiyagari, S. Rao, Christiano, Lawrence J., and Eichenbaum, Martin (1992) The output, employment, and interest rate effects of government consumption. Journal of Monetary Economics 30, 7386.Google Scholar
Basu, Sasanto and Kimball, Miles S. (2002) Long-Run Labor Supply and the Elasticity of Intertemporal Substitution for Consumption. Mimeo, University of Michigan and NBER.Google Scholar
Baxter, Marianne and King, Robert G. (1993) Fiscal policy in general equilibrium. American Economic Review 83, 315334.Google Scholar
Bilbiie, Florin O. (2009) Nonseparable preferences, fiscal policy puzzles, and inferior goods. Journal of Money, Credit and Banking 41, 443450.Google Scholar
Bilbiie, Florin O. (2011) Nonseparable preferences, Frisch labor supply, and the consumption multiplier of government spending: One solution to a fiscal policy puzzle. Journal of Money, Credit and Banking 43, 221251.Google Scholar
Blanchard, Olivier and Perotti, Roberto. (2002) An empirical characterization of the dynamic effects of changes in government spending and taxes on output. Quarterly Journal of Economics 117, 13291368.Google Scholar
Branch, William A. and Evans, George W. (2006) A simple recursive forecasting model. Economics Letters 91, 158166.Google Scholar
Calvo, Guillermo A. (1983) Staggered prices in a utility-maximizing framework. Journal of Monetary Economics 12, 383398.Google Scholar
Christiano, Lawrence, Eichenbaum, Martin, and Rebelo, Sergio (2011) When is the government spending multiplier large? Journal of Political Economy 119, 78121.Google Scholar
Christiano, Lawrence J., Eichenbaum, Martin, and Evans, Charles L. (2005) Nominal rigidities and the dynamic effects of a shock to monetary policy. Journal of Political Economy 113, 145.Google Scholar
Coenen, Günter, Erceg, Christopher J., Freedman, Charles, Furceri, Davide, Kumhof, Michael, Lalonde, René, Laxton, Douglas, Lindé, Jesper, Mourougane, Annabelle, Muir, Dirk, Mursula, Susanna, de Resende, Carlos, Roberts, John, Roeger, Werner, Snudden, Stephen, Trabandt, Mathias, and Veld, Jan in 't (2012) Effects of fiscal stimulus in structural models. American Economic Journal: Macroeconomics 4, 2268.Google Scholar
Eusepi, S. and Preston, B. (2011) Expectations, learning, and business cycle fluctuations. American Economic Review 101, 2844–72.Google Scholar
Evans, George W. and Honkapohja, Seppo (2001) Learning and Expectations in Macroeconomics. Princeton, New Jersey: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Evans, George W., Honkapohja, Seppo, and Mitra, Kaushik (2009) Anticipated fiscal policy and adaptive learning. Journal of Monetary Economics 56, 930953.Google Scholar
Evans, George W., Honkapohja, Seppo, and Mitra, Kaushik (2012) Does Ricardian equivalence hold when expectations are not rational? Journal of Money, Credit and Banking 44, 12591283.Google Scholar
Evans, George W., Honkapohja, Seppo, and Mitra, Kaushik (2016) Expectations, Stagnation and Fiscal Policy. Bank of Finland discussion papers 25/2016.Google Scholar
Fatás, Antonio and Mihov, Ilian (2001) The Effects of Fiscal Policy on Consumption and Employment: Theory and Evidence. CEPR discussion papers no. 2760.Google Scholar
Fragetta, Matteo and Gasteiger, Emanuel (2014) Fiscal foresight, limited information and the effects of government spending shocks. Oxford Bulletin of Economics and Statistics 76, 667692.Google Scholar
Galí, J., López-Salido, J. D., and Vallés, J. (2007) Understanding the effects of government spending on consumption. Journal of the European Economic Association 5, 227270.Google Scholar
Gasteiger, Emanuel and Zhang, Shoujian. (2014) Anticipation, learning and welfare: The case of distortionary taxation. Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control 39, 113126.Google Scholar
Guse, Eran A. (2008) Learning in a misspecified multivariate self-referential linear stochastic model. Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control 32, 15171542.Google Scholar
Honkapohja, S., Mitra, K., and Evans, G. W. (2013) Notes on agents' behavioral rules under adaptive learning and studies of monetary policy. In Sargent, T. J. and Vilmunen, J. (eds.), Macroeconomics at the Service of Public Policy, Chapter 4, pp. 6379. Oxford, United Kingdom: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
King, Robert G., Plosser, Charles I., and Rebelo, Sergio T. (1988) Production, growth and business cycles: I. The basic neoclassical model. Journal of Monetary Economics 21, 195232.Google Scholar
Leeper, E. M., Plante, M., and Traum, N. (2010) Dynamics of fiscal financing in the united states. Journal of Econometrics 156, 304321.Google Scholar
Leeper, Eric M., Traum, Nora, and Walker, Todd B. (2015) Clearing up the fiscal multiplier morass. CAEPR working papers 2015-013, Classification-C, Center for Applied Economics and Policy Research, Economics Department, Indiana University Bloomington.Google Scholar
Linnemann, Ludger (2006) The effect of government spending on private consumption: A puzzle? Journal of Money, Credit and Banking 38, 17151735.Google Scholar
Linnemann, Ludger and Schabert, Andreas (2003) Fiscal policy in the new neoclassical synthesis. Journal of Money, Credit and Banking 35, 911–29.Google Scholar
Lucas, Robert E. and Prescott, Edward C. (1971) Investment under uncertainty. Econometrica 39, 659681.Google Scholar
Milani, Fabio (2007) Expectations, learning and macroeconomic persistence. Journal of Monetary Economics 54, 20652082.Google Scholar
Mitra, Kaushik, Evans, George W., and Honkapohja, Seppo (2013) Policy change and learning in the RBC model. Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control 37, 19471971.Google Scholar
Mitra, Kaushik, Evans, George W., and Honkapohja, Seppo (2016) Fiscal Policy Multipliers in an RBC Model with Learning. Mimeo, University of St Andrews.Google Scholar
Mountford, Andrew and Uhlig, Harald (2009) What are the effects of fiscal policy shocks? Journal of Applied Econometrics 24, 960992.Google Scholar
Nakamura, Emi and Steinsson, Jón (2008) Five facts about prices: A reevaluation of menu cost models. Quarterly Journal of Economics 123, 14151464.Google Scholar
Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development (OECD) (2014). OECD Tax Database. www.oecd.org/ctp/taxdatabase.Google Scholar
Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development (OECD) (2014). OECD. Stat database. doi: 10.1787/data-00285-en.Google Scholar
Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development (OECD) (2014). Taxing Wages 2014. doi: 10.1787/tax_wages-2014-en.Google Scholar
Orphanides, Athanasios and Williams, John C. (2005) The decline of activist stabilization policy: Natural rate misperceptions, learning, and expectations. Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control 29, 19271950.Google Scholar
Orphanides, Athanasios and Williams, John C. (2007) Robust monetary policy with imperfect knowledge. Journal of Monetary Economics 54, 14061435.Google Scholar
Perotti, Roberto (2008) In search of the transmission mechanism of fiscal policy. In Acemoglu, Daron, Rogoff, Kenneth, and Woodford, Michael (eds.), NBER Macroeconomics Annual 2007, vol. 22, NBER Chapters, pp. 169226. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
Ramey, Valerie A. (2011) Can government purchases stimulate the economy? Journal of Economic Literature 49, 673685.Google Scholar
Ramey, Valerie A. and Shapiro, Matthew. D. (1998) Costly capital reallocation and the effects of government spending. Carnegie-Rochester Conference Series on Public Policy 48, 145194.Google Scholar
Rotemberg, Julio J and Woodford, Michael (1992) Oligopolistic pricing and the effects of aggregate demand on economic activity. Journal of Political Economy 100, 11531207.Google Scholar
Slobodyan, Sergey and Wouters, Raf (2012) Learning in an estimated medium-scale DSGE model. Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control 36, 2646.Google Scholar
Smets, F. and Wouters, R. (2003) An estimated dynamic stochastic general equilibrium model of the euro area. Journal of the European Economic Association 1, 11231175.Google Scholar
Smets, Frank and Wouters, Rafael (2007) Shocks and frictions in US business cycles: A Bayesian DSGE approach. American Economic Review 97, 586606.Google Scholar
Woodford, Michael (2003) Interest and Prices: Foundations of a Theory of Monetary Policy. Princeton, New Jersey: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar