Hostname: page-component-cd9895bd7-dzt6s Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-12-23T14:25:57.718Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Introducing upfront losses as well as gains decreases impatience in intertemporal choices with rewards

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  01 January 2023

Cheng-Ming Jiang*
Affiliation:
Center for Brain and Management Science, College of Economics and Management, Zhejiang University of Technology, 288 Liuhe Road, Xihu District, Hangzhou (310023), P.R.China
Feng-Pei Hu
Affiliation:
Center for Brain and Management Science, College of Economics and Management, Zhejiang University of Technology
Long-Fei Zhu
Affiliation:
Center for Brain and Management Science, College of Economics and Management, Zhejiang University of Technology
*
Rights & Permissions [Opens in a new window]

Abstract

People tend to prefer smaller and sooner (SS) rewards over larger and later (LL) ones even when the latter are much larger. Previous research have identified several ways to enhance people’s patience. Adding to this literature, the current paper demonstrates that introduction of upfront losses as well as gains to both SS and LL rewards can decrease people’s impatience. This effect is incompatible with both the normative exponential and descriptive hyperbolic discounting models, which agree on the additive assumption and the independence assumption. We also exculde the integration explanation which assumes subjects integrate upfront money with final rewards and make a decision with bottom line at the end. We consider several possible explanations, including the salience hypothesis, which states that introducing upfront money makes the money dimension more salient than not and thus increases the attractiveness of LL options.

Type
Research Article
Creative Commons
Creative Common License - CCCreative Common License - BY
The authors license this article under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution 3.0 License.
Copyright
Copyright © The Authors [2014] This is an Open Access article, distributed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution license (http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/3.0/), which permits unrestricted re-use, distribution, and reproduction in any medium, provided the original work is properly cited.

1 Introduction

Intertemporal choices, or decisions whose outcomes are determined over time, such as choosing between saving money for education and spending it on a luxury item, are ubiquitous and important in everyday life. The disposition to choose a larger, later reward over a tempting, sooner one and the tendency to focus on the future relate to important individual outcomes, such as academic achievement (Duckworth & Seligman, Reference Duckworth and Seligman2005). Sooner rewards are usually difficult to resist. Excessive discounting can disrupt the achievement of long-term goals.

To study intertemporal choices, researchers (e.g., Estle, Green, Myerson, & Holt, Reference Estle, Green, Myerson and Holt2007) have typically instructed subjects in their studies to choose between smaller and sooner (SS) rewards and larger and later (LL) ones (e.g., gaining CNY 210 in a week versus gaining CNY 250 in five weeks in the present study). People generally tend to be impatient in such situations, and most prefer SS rewards over LL rewards (even with a yearly interest rate of 965% in the above example).

Researchers have identified several ways to enhance people’s patience. For example, Urminsky and Kivetz (Reference Urminsky and Kivetz2011) demonstrated that adding an immediate token reward to both options increases the preference for LL rewards. Magen, Dweck, and Gross (Reference Magen, Dweck and Gross2008) showed that explicitly referring to the hidden zero in each option (e.g., gaining CNY 210 in a week and CNY 0 in five weeks versus gaining CNY 250 in five weeks and CNY 0 in a week) would decrease the willingness of subjects to choose immediate rewards. Read, Frederick, Orsel, and Rahman (Reference Read, Frederick, Orsel and Rahman2005) found that framing delays (e.g., in a period of six months) in corresponding calendars (e.g., on October 17) promotes the attractiveness of LL rewards.

The present paper introduces a novel way to decrease people’s impatience. The hypothesis is that adding upfront losses as well as gains, even small ones, to both options (i.e., SS and LL rewards) can enhance people’s patience and encourage them to choose LL options. The hypothesis is built on the assumption that introducing losses as well as gains may make the money dimension more salient and thus increase the attractiveness of LL options.

Experiment 1 shows that introducing upfront losses to both intertemporal options (i.e., SS and LL rewards) reduces people’s impatience in both between- and within-subject designs and excludes the normative exponential and descriptive hyperbolic discounting models, which share assumptions of additivity and independence. Experiment 2 excludes an integration explanation, which assumes subjects integrate upfront money with final rewards and make a decision with bottom line at the end. The experiment also corroborates the previous reported upfront gain effect (Urminsky & Kivetz, Reference Urminsky and Kivetz2011): adding upfront gains (rather than losses) to both SS and LL options can also enhance people’s patience. In the general discussion, we consider the possible causes for this upfront loss as well as gain effect.

2 Experiment 1

2.1 Method

In Experiment 1A, 209 undergraduates (55 males, Mage= 21.3, SD = 1.4) from Shangdong Normal University and Shanghai Second Polytechnic University attended in a class. Each of the subjects was randomly assigned to one of two conditions. Subjects in the pure gain condition responded to typical choice pairs (e.g., gaining CNY 210 in a week versus gaining CNY 250 in five weeks), whereas those in the mixed condition had the same choices except that both options begin with a same immediate loss (e.g., losing CNY 11 now and gaining CNY 210 in one week versus losing CNY 11 now and gaining CNY 250 in four weeks).

To ask whether the results hold for different rewards as well as for different upfront losses, we varied the rewards (from CNY 100 to CNY 8,000) and the upfront losses (from 5% to 89% of some sooner rewards) over a wide range. The subjects indicated their preferences in the questionnaire, which consisted of four pairwise choices and was presented on paper (Table 1).

Table 1: Questionnaire items and summary of the results for Experiments 1A and 1B. (Φ is effect size.)

The pure gain condition in Experiment 1B is the same as that in Experiment 1A. In the mixed condition, different upfront losses were introduced into the SS and LL options. That is, the losses in the LL option are always CNY 5 more than those in the SS options (e.g., losing CNY 11 now and gaining CNY 210 in a week versus losing CNY 16 now and gaining CNY 250 in five weeks) (Table 1).

Experiment 1B used a within-subjects design, in which each subject responded to each condition. A total of 106 subjects (54 males, Mage= 22.5, SD = 1.9) from China Agricultural University were approached in classrooms when they were studying by themselves and were asked to respond to a questionnaire. The questionnaire was consisted of eight choices (each condition had four pairs of choices) and were presented on paper. The order of the two conditions was counterbalanced. That is, half of the subjects first answered the questions of the mixed condition followed by those of the pure gain condition, and the other half answered the questions in the reverse order. The subjects were presented with a small gift for their cooperation.

2.2 Results and discussion

Consistent with the hypothesis, both Experiments 1A and 1B demonstrate that the introduction of upfront losses to both intertemporal options (i.e., SS and LL) reduces people’s impatience regardless of whether the immediate losses are small or large. Table 1 summarizes the results. These results are directly inconsistent with the established models of intertemporal choice. Both the (normative) exponential model (i.e., discounted-utility, Samuelson, Reference Samuelson1937) and (descriptive) hyperbolic discounting models (e.g, hyperbolic discounting model, Mazur, Reference Mazur1984; quasi-hyperbolic discounting model, Laibson, Reference Laibson1997) generally agree on the additivity assumption and the independence assumption when these models are applied to intertemporal choice between pairs of multiple-dated outcomes (Rao & Li, Reference Rao and Li2011). The additivity assumption means that preferences for multiple-dated outcomes are based on a simple aggregation of their individual components within intertemporal options (Loewenstein & Prelec, Reference Loewenstein and Prelec1993) and the independence assumption means that the utility of an outcome in one period is independent of outcomes in other periods (Prelec & Loewenstein, Reference Prelec and Loewenstein1991). This implies that the relative evaluations of the options in the pure gain and mixed conditions are equivalent in Experiment 1A and should be biased towards SS options in the mixed conditions of Experiment 1B. In Experiment 1A, if people prefer SS options over LL ones in the pure gain condition, they should also prefer the same options in the mixed condition because the common elements of loss should not change their preference. In Experiment 1B, in which the upfront losses in the SS options are always less than those in the LL ones in the mixed condition, if people prefer SS options over LL ones in the pure gain condition, they will also prefer the corresponding SS options in the mixed condition. However, the preferences in Experiment 1A and 1B were both changed in favor of LL in the mixed conditions. Thus, the exponential discounting model and hyperbolic discounting models, both of which assume additivity and independence, cannot account for this upfront loss effect.

Now we consider whether or not the integration hypothesis (Thaler, Reference Thaler1985), which does not assume additivity and independence, can account for the observed effect. This hypothesis posits that, when people face problems such as choosing between “losing CNY 100 now and gaining CNY 120 in a week” and “losing CNY 100 now and gaining CNY 150 in 4 week,” they need to think only about the bottom line at the end and subtract the initial loss from the final reward, which is “CNY 20 in a week” versus “CNY 50 in four weeks” in this example. This process increases the ratio of outcomes of LL options to those of SS options and may encourage the subjects to choose the LL options. Therefore, in the next experiment, we check whether the integration hypothesis can account for this effect.

3 Experiment 2

3.1 Experiment 2A

We assumed that, if the integration hypothesis is correct, people will integrate an initial reward — if the initial outcome is a reward instead of a loss (e.g., gain CNY 100 now and gain CNY 120 in a week) — with the final reward in a mixed intertemporal choice option. In Experiment 2A, we used pairwise options that begin with a constant gain, rather than a loss, to examine the integration hypothesis. It can be assumed that the difference in delay between SS and LL options has the effect of multiplying u(M SS) by a constant K that is greater than 1, where M SS is the amount of money received in the SS option and u(M SS) is its utility. Thus, a LL option will be chosen if u(M LL)/u(M SS) > K, a SS option will be chosen if u(M LL)/u(M SS) < K, and a subject will be indifferent if u(M LL)/u(M SS) = K, where M LL is the amount of money received and u(M LL) is its utility in a LL option. Now we consider that an amount C > 0 is added to both M LL and M SS. Most studies on intertemporal choice assumed linear utility and some assumed concave utility for gains and convex utility for losses (e.g., Loewenstein & Prelec, Reference Loewenstein and Prelec1992). A few empirical studies have confirmed the latter (Abdellaoui, Attema, & Bleichrodt, Reference Abdellaoui, Attema and Bleichrodt2009). Thus, we can assume linear utility or concave utility for gains here. Since C > 0 and M LL > M SS, u(M LL+C)/u(M SS+C) < u(M LL)/u(M SS). This implies that, if u(M LL)/u(M SS) < K, u(M LL+C)/u(M SS+C) < K according to the transitivity rule.Footnote 1 In sum, if subjects prefer SS over LL options in the pure condition, and if the integration hypothesis is correct, they should also prefer SS over LL options in the mixed condition in which pairwise options begin with a same immediate gain. This inference can also be extended to the situation in which immediate reward has greater impact than final reward, because we only need to adjust the impact of C by a weight greater than 1.

3.1.1 Method

In Experiment 2A, 171 students (82 males, Mage= 20.8, SD = 1.5) from Zhejiang University of Technology were approached in the library and randomly assigned to either one of two conditions: In the pure gain condition, the subjects responded to typical choice pairs as in Experiment 1A (e.g., gaining CNY 210 in a week versus gaining CNY 250 in five weeks), whereas those in the mixed condition responded to choice pairs beginning with the same upfront rewards (e.g., gaining CNY 11 now and gaining CNY 210 in a week versus gaining CNY 11 now and gaining CNY 250 in four weeks) (Table 2). Choice pairs was presented on paper. The subjects were given a small gift for their cooperation.

Table 2: Questionnaire items and summary of the results for Experiments 2A, 2B, and 2C. (Φ is effect size.)

3.1.2 Results and discussion

The results demonstrate that the introduction of upfront rewards to both intertemporal options (i.e., SS and LL) reduces impatience. Table 2 summarizes the results. These results are consistent with those of Urminsky and Kivetz (Reference Urminsky and Kivetz2011), although the time of the upfront gains (i.e., now) recieved in this study is a little differred from theirs (i.e., 1 day or 3 days delayed). These results however, are in opposition to the prediction of the integration hypothesis.

Although the results of Experiment 2A help to rule out the integration explanation, the subjects may possibly integrate the upfront losses but not the upfront rewards with the final rewards in the mixed conditions. In Experiments 2B and 2C, we directly exclude the integration hypothesis.

3.2 Experiments 2B and 2C

We introduced larger losses to the LL options than to the SS options so that the ratio of the introduced losses in the LL options to those in the SS options would be equal to or a little larger than the ratio of rewards in LL options to those in the SS options (Table 2). We assume that, if the subjects subtract the initial losses from the final rewards as hypothesized by the integration hypothesis, this integration will not change or even decrease the ratio of the integrated amounts of the LL options to those of the SS options in the mixed condition, compared with the ratio of rewards of the LL options to those of the SS options in the pure condition. Therefore, the preference of subjects should change in favor of, or at least not in the opposite direction of, the SS options based on the magnitude effect found in previous studies (Chapman & Winquist, Reference Chapman and Winquist1998; Loewenstein & Prelec, Reference Loewenstein and Prelec1992; Prelec & Loewenstein, Reference Prelec and Loewenstein1991). That is, by the integration hypthesis, decision makers should show a large temporal discount rate for small magnitudes than for large ones.

Experiments 2B and 2C used between- and within-subjects designs, respectively, with choice options presented to the subjects with little variation.

3.2.1 Method

In Experiment 2B, students from Zhejiang University of Technology were approached in the library and were randomly assigned to either of the pure or mixed condition groups, each of which had two pairwise choices (Table 2). The options were presented with other unrelated questions and was given on paper. Five students did not respond in one or both pairwise choices and were therefore excluded. A total of 103 students remained (40males, Mage= 21.5, SD = 1.7) for the analysis.

Experiment 2C used a within-subjects design, in which each subject responded to each condition. Another 104 students (61males, Mage= 21.1, SD = 1.9) from Zhejiang University of Technology were approached in the library and asked to respond to the questionnaire consisting of four pairwise choices (with each condition having two pairs of choices) and other unrelated questions, which was given on paper. The order of the two conditions was counterbalanced. Thus, half of the subjects first answered the questions of the mixed condition followed by those of the pure gain condition, and the other half answered in the reverse order.

All the subjects were presented with a small gift for their participation.

3.2.2 Results and discussion

The results of both Experiments 2B and 2C demonstrate that the introduction of upfront losses to both intertemporal options (i.e., SS and LL) made the subjects more prone to choose the LL options rather than the SS options, contrary to the prediction of the integration hypothesis. Table 2 summarizes the results. Therefore, we can conclude that the integration explanation cannot account for the upfront loss effect.

4 General discussion

This paper shows that introducing upfront losses as well as gains decreases people’s impatience in intertemporal choices. In particular, the upfront loss effect has never been reported before. We also excludes the (normative) exponential model and (descriptive) hyperbolic discounting model, as well as the integration hypothesis, as an account of these effects.

Although the aim of this paper is primarily to document the effect of upfront money, particularly, of upfront losses, we consider several other possible explanations for this effect. The first explanation is the salience hypothesis, which states that introducing losses as well as gains makes the money dimension more salient than not and thus increase the attractiveness of LL options. This account is comprehensive because it can account for all the results of the current study. Moreover, this hypothesis may explain the hidden zero effect and the mere token effect (Magen, Dweck, & Gross, Reference Magen, Dweck and Gross2008; Urminsky & Kivetz, Reference Urminsky and Kivetz2011): The explicating of hidden-zero and the offering of a small token reward may make the money dimension more salient and thus increase the attractiveness of LL options.Footnote 2

The second explanation is the time scale hypothesis, which assumes that the presentation of the 0-delay amount anchors the time dimension at 0.Footnote 3 Thus, in the pure condition, subjects maybe compare the delays beween SS and LL options and consider the delay of LL option with the reference point at the delay of SS option. For example, when facing a choice between “gaining CNY 320 in 7 weeks and gaining CNY 380 in 10 weeks”, the subjects might put the reference point at 7 weeks and think the delay of the LL reward is 3 weeks. In the mixed conditions, the subjects are more likely to look at the time ratios rather than their differences and thus feel the delays beween SS and LL options are much shorter than in the pure condtions. Therefore, they are more likely to choose LL options in the mixed conditions than in the pure conditions.

The third explanation is the decision mode hypothesis, which posits that upfront losses may prompt people to adopt different modes of cognitive processing. In the pure gain condition, the subjects may respond with an automatic cognitive mode, whereas in the mixed conditions, they may respond with a deliberate cognitive mode (Dunegan, Reference Dunegan1993), therefore increasing the attractiveness of the LL options over the SS ones in the latter situation. This explantion, however, is confined to the effect of upfront loss and can not account for the general effect of upfront money. Further research is required to elucidate the underlying mechanism of the effects reported here.

We used intervals no shorter than a week to study impatience. Although they are consistent with some research (e.g., Urminsky & Kivetz, Reference Urminsky and Kivetz2011), we should point out that most studies on impatience in intertempral choice used very short intervals, such as immediacy (e.g., Magen et al., Reference Magen, Dweck and Gross2008). Further research need to consider very short intervals.

Another limitation of the current study is that we used hypothetical rather than real money as outcomes, because executing real losses (e.g., CNY 4250) with the subjects was impossible. Although several previous studies have shown that hypothetical financial intertemporal choice outcomes yield the same results as real outcomes (Bickel, Pitcock, Yi, & Angtuaco, Reference Bickel, Pitcock, Yi and Angtuaco2009; Johnson & Bickel, Reference Johnson and Bickel2002; Madden et al., Reference Madden, Raiff, Lagorio, Begotka, Mueller, Hehli and Wegener2004), additional research is required to test the effect reported in this study with real money in real-world settings. However, if further confirmed, this effect has practical implications for policy makers and managers, specifically in encouraging citizens or employees to choose LL rewards instead of SS ones by letting them incur some losses first, even small ones.

Footnotes

This research was partially supported by the Zhejiang Provincial Philosophy and Social Science Planning Project of China (No. 14NDJC172YB), the Zhejiang Provincial Natural Science Foundation of China (No. LY14C090002), and the National Social Science Foundation of China (No. 14BSH070). The authors would like thank the two anonymous referees and Editor Jonathan Baron for their valuable comments and suggestions on the draft of this paper. The authors also wish to thank Ren Yanju, Zhen Shiliang, Dong Huahua, and Kong Lin for collecting the data used in this study.

1 Thanks to Editor Jonathan Baron for helping us to clarify this integration hypothesis.

2 Magen et al.(Reference Magen, Dweck and Gross2008) speculated that the preference for sequences that improve over time or the attention to the opportunity cost of each choice induced by the explicit-zero format may account for the hidden zero effect. The improve-over-time explanation of Magen et al. (Reference Magen, Dweck and Gross2008) posits that people compare later rewards with earlier losses or gains. This comparison may increase the attractiveness of LL options in our study. This explanation, in some degree, is similar to (and perhaps can be incorporated into) the salience hypothesis, which states that people focus more on the money dimension when the upfront amounts are introduced. The opportunity-cost explanation of Magen et al. (Reference Magen, Dweck and Gross2008) is that explication of zero may reminds people that future (immediate) rewards are the opportunity costs of immediate (future) rewards. This cannot account for the reported effects here. Urminsky and Kivetz (Reference Urminsky and Kivetz2011) argued that offering a small token reward reduced peoples’ choice conflict between their desire for an immediate reward and a higher payoff available by waiting, making them easier to ignore the temptation of immediacy and hold out for LL rewards. This explanation cannot account for the effect of upfront losses, because adding an upfront loss would be expected to increase peoples’ desire for an immediate reward.

3 Thanks Editor Jonathan Baron for putting forward this explanation, which is similar to a proposal of Scholten and Read (Reference Scholten and Read2010).

References

Abdellaoui, M., Attema, A. E., & Bleichrodt, H. (2009). Intertemporal tradeoffs for gains and losses: An experimental measurement of discounted utility. he Economic Journal, 120(545), 845866.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bickel, W. K., Pitcock, J. A., Yi, R., & Angtuaco, E. J. C. (2009). Congruence of bold response across intertemporal choice conditions: Fictive and real money gains and losses. The Journal of Neuroscience, 29(27), 88398846.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Chapman, G. B., & Winquist, J. R. (1998). The magnitude effect: Temporal discount rates and restaurant tips. Psychonomic Bulletin & Review, 5(1), 119123.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Duckworth, A. L., & Seligman, M. E. (2005). Self-discipline outdoes IQ in predicting academic performance of adolescents. Psychological Science, 16(12), 939944.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Dunegan, K. J. (1993). Framing, cognitive modes, and image theory: Toward an understanding of a glass half full. Journal of Applied Psychology, 78(3), 491503.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Estle, S. J., Green, L., Myerson, J., & Holt, D. D. (2007). Discounting of monetary and directly consumable rewards. Psychological Science, 18(1), 5863.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Johnson, M. W., & Bickel, W. K. (2002). Within-subject comparison of real and hypothetical money rewards in delay discounting. Journal of the Experimental Analysis of Behavior, 77(2), 129146.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Laibson, D. (1997). Golden eggs and hyperbolic discounting. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 112(2), 443478.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Loewenstein, G. F., & Prelec, D. (1992). Anomalies in intertemporal choice: Evidence and an interpretation. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 107(2), 573597.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Loewenstein, G. F., & Prelec, D. (1993). Preferences for sequences of outcomes. Psychological Review, 100(1), 91108.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Madden, G. J., Raiff, B. R., Lagorio, C. H., Begotka, A. M., Mueller, A. M., Hehli, D. J., & Wegener, A. A. (2004). Delay discounting of potentially real and hypothetical rewards: II. Between-and within-subject comparisons. Experimental and Clinical Psychopharmacology, 12(4), 251261.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Magen, E., Dweck, C. S., & Gross, J. J. (2008). The hidden-zero effect: Representing a single choice as an extended sequence reduces impulsive choice. Psychological Science, 19(7), 648649.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Mazur, J. E. (1984). Tests of an equivalence rule for fixed and variable delays. Journal of Experimental Psychology: Animal Behavior Processes, 10, 426436.Google Scholar
Prelec, D., & Loewenstein, G. F. (1991). Decision making over time and uncertainty: A common approach. Management Science, 37(7), 770786.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rao, L. L., & Li, S. (2011). New paradoxes in intertemporal choice. Judgment and Decision Making, 6(2), 122129.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Read, D., Frederick, S., Orsel, B., & Rahman, J. (2005). Four score and seven years from now: The date/delay effect in temporal discounting. Management Science, 51(9), 13261335.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Samuelson, P. A. (1937). A note on measurement of utility. The Review of Economic Studies, 4(2), 155161.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Scholten, M., & Read, D. (2010). The psychology of intertemporal tradeoffs. Psychological Review, 117(3), 925944.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Thaler, R. (1985). Mental accounting and consumer choice. Marketing Science, 4(3), 199214.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Urminsky, O., & Kivetz, R. (2011). Scope insensitivity and the “mere token” effect. Journal of Marketing Research, 48(2), 282295.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Figure 0

Table 1: Questionnaire items and summary of the results for Experiments 1A and 1B. (Φ is effect size.)

Figure 1

Table 2: Questionnaire items and summary of the results for Experiments 2A, 2B, and 2C. (Φ is effect size.)

Supplementary material: File

Jiang et al. supplementary material

Jiang et al. supplementary material 1
Download Jiang et al. supplementary material(File)
File 2.5 KB
Supplementary material: File

Jiang et al. supplementary material

Jiang et al. supplementary material 2
Download Jiang et al. supplementary material(File)
File 2.4 KB
Supplementary material: File

Jiang et al. supplementary material

Jiang et al. supplementary material 3
Download Jiang et al. supplementary material(File)
File 2 KB
Supplementary material: File

Jiang et al. supplementary material

Jiang et al. supplementary material 4
Download Jiang et al. supplementary material(File)
File 1.2 KB
Supplementary material: File

Jiang et al. supplementary material

Jiang et al. supplementary material 5
Download Jiang et al. supplementary material(File)
File 1.4 KB