Hostname: page-component-78c5997874-j824f Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-11-18T01:22:30.846Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Two decades after Korpi and Palme’s “paradox of redistribution”: What have we learned so far and where do we take it from here?

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  12 January 2021

Dimitri Gugushvili*
Affiliation:
Centre for Sociological Research, KU Leuven, Leuven, Belgium
Tijs Laenen
Affiliation:
Centre for Sociological Research, KU Leuven, Leuven, Belgium
Rights & Permissions [Opens in a new window]

Abstract

Over two decades ago, Korpi and Palme (1998) published one of the most influential papers in the history of social policy discipline, in which they put forward a “paradox of redistribution”: the more countries target welfare resources exclusively at the poor, the less redistribution is actually achieved and the less income inequality and poverty are reduced. The current paper provides a state-of-the-art review of empirical research into that paradox. More specifically, we break down the paradox into seven core assumptions, which together form a causal chain running from institutional design to redistributive outcomes. For each causal assumption, we offer a comprehensive and critical review of the relevant empirical literature, also including a broader range of studies that do not aim to address Korpi and Palme’s paradox per se, but are nevertheless informative about it.

Type
Research Article
Creative Commons
Creative Common License - CCCreative Common License - BY
This is an Open Access article, distributed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution licence (http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/), which permits unrestricted re-use, distribution, and reproduction in any medium, provided the original work is properly cited.
Copyright
© The Author(s), 2021. Published by Cambridge University Press on behalf of Social Policy Association

Introduction

Over two decades ago, the Swedish scholars, Walter Korpi and Joakim Palme (hereinafter referred to as K&P) published one of the most influential papers in the history of social policy discipline, in which they put forward a “paradox of redistribution”: the more countries target welfare resources exclusively at the poor, the less redistribution is actually achieved and the less income inequality and poverty are reduced (Korpi & Palme, Reference Korpi and Palme1998).Footnote 1 This paradox has subsequently been a major source of inspiration for many welfare state scholars. Not only is K&P’s article one of the most frequently cited in social policy literature,Footnote 2 several studies have also stated the explicit objective of revisiting the original analysis on which it was based. K&P’s findings remained practically unchallenged for more than a decade but subsequently, a number of comparative studies started re-examining the links between universalism/selectivism,Footnote 3 social spending, and redistribution, taking advantage of more advanced quantitative methods, larger selections of countries, and longer time periods. Among the first to do so were Kenworthy (Reference Kenworthy2011) and Marx, Salanauskaite, and Verbist (Reference Marx, Salanauskaite and Verbist2013), who reproduced and updated K&P’s empirical analyses, using similar data and methods. Their main conclusions are twofold: (1) the empirical evidence supporting the paradox of redistribution has always been somewhat weak and (2) the paradox might have been valid in the 1980s when K&P carried out their analyses but it certainly no longer applies to the twenty-first century welfare states. Based on the assumption that K&P’s argument was “theoretically sound but inadequately operationalized” (Jacques & Noël, Reference Jacques and Noël2018, p. 71), later studies moved beyond mere replication and found that by using novel measurements for some of K&P’s key concepts – such as universalism – the paradox of redistribution is far from dead and buried. Brady and Bostic (Reference Brady and Bostic2015, p. 290), for one, claim that “K&P’s conclusions are robust and remain significant two decades later in rich democracies and in a broader sample of developed and developing countries” (see also Jacques and Noël (Reference Jacques and Noël2018)).

Thus, the scholarly debate surrounding the empirical validity of K&P’s paradox of redistribution remains far from settled. Nor has it lost its tremendous societal relevance, especially at present, when increasing inequality and financial insecurity, transforming labour markets, migration and demographic changes exert additional pressures on welfare states and raise important questions about their overall legitimacy and future directions (Taylor-Gooby, Leruth, & Chung, Reference Taylor-Gooby, Leruth and Chung2017). At one extreme, major international organizations, such as the International Monetary Fund (IMF), EU, Organization for Economic Co-operation and Development (OECD) and World Bank, continue to present means-tested, low-income targeting as one of the most appropriate and promising paths for the future welfare state (Schoukens, Reference Schoukens2016). At the other extreme, different types of universal basic income schemes, granting financial assistance to all citizens or residents regardless of their actual needs are being proposed and even experimented within a number of countries (van Parijs & Vanderborght, Reference van Parijs and Vanderborght2017).

Against this background, the present article contributes to the debate by responding to K&P’s call to “open the black box of causal processes assumed to mediate the effects from institutions to redistributive outcomes” (Korpi & Palme, Reference Korpi and Palme1998, p. 673). In what follows, we provide a state-of-the-art (though certainly not an exhaustive) review of major empirical research into K&P’s paradox of redistribution. More specifically, we break down the paradox into several core assumptions, which together form a causal chain running from institutional design (ie. universalism vs selectivism) to redistributive outcomes (ie. the reduction of poverty and income inequality). For each causal assumption, we provide a comprehensive and critical review of the relevant empirical literature, also including a broader range of studies that do not aim to address K&P’s paradox of redistribution per se but are nevertheless informative about it. The main advantage of our approach is that we move beyond a simple test of the “end product” (ie. are selective systems less redistributive than universal ones?) to a much more sophisticated examination of its underlying, in-between mechanisms. While our intention is not to provide the ultimate answer to the central question of the debate, our findings do provide valuable insights that can inform future studies on universal versus selective welfare provision. First, we show that most of K&P’s causal assumptions cannot be taken for granted as the relevant empirical evidence tends to be highly conflicting. We also discuss alternative theoretical mechanisms put forward to make sense of the findings that are at odds with K&P assumptions. Second, we identify areas where additional research is very much needed, especially concerning the link between institutional settings, support for redistribution, and the size of redistributive budget. These may be the weakest links in K&P’s model as they have not been tested empirically in the original analysis. In addition, the distributional effects of private welfare provision remain under-researched. Third, in practical policy terms, we argue that selectivity can play a role in anti-poverty strategies, but, for this, a number of preconditions – such as extending coverage to more “deserving” groups like the working poor – need to be fulfilled.

The political economy of universalism and selectivism

The fact that distributional justice principles and the methods for selecting beneficiaries can have major implications regarding political support for welfare provision – which in turn might affect the programmes’ generosity, quality and sustainability – has perhaps been acknowledged since the introduction of the Poor Laws in England. Not surprisingly, it has attracted the attention of many prominent scholars, including Besley (Reference Besley1990), Goodin and Le Grand (Reference Goodin and Le Grand1987), Korpi (Reference Korpi1980), Marshall (Reference Marshall1950), Pierson (Reference Pierson1994), Sen (Reference Sen, Van de Walle and Nead1995), Rothstein (Reference Rothstein1998), Tawney (Reference Tawney1952), and Titmuss (Reference Titmuss1968). In the United States, a major milestone in the debate was the publication of an influential book, The urban underclass in Reference Skocpol, Jencks and Peterson1991. In this work, two American scientists – Skocpol and Greenstein – put forward competing views about which of the two approaches offered more potential for tackling the persistent poverty in the United States. Contrasting the failure of three major targeted programmes (the nineteenth-century poorhouses, pensions for single mothers, and the “Great Society” programmes) with the success of more universal programmes (such as civil war benefits, health education for mothers and children and old-age pensions), Skocpol argues that “when U.S. anti-poverty efforts have featured policies targeted on the poor alone, they have not been politically sustainable, and they have stigmatised and demeaned the poor” (Skocpol, Reference Skocpol, Jencks and Peterson1991, p. 14). The implications have been a gradual reduction in spending and ultimately the abandonment of the programmes. To avoid the same pitfall, Skocpol urges the advocates of the poor to promote “targeting within universalism”: ie. universal programmes in which most people, especially the middle class, would have a direct stake and which would provide disproportionately larger benefits to the disadvantaged.

While not denying that universal programmes tend to have wider electoral appeal and are less stigmatizing than the means-tested alternatives, Greenstein (Reference Greenstein, Jencks and Peterson1991) argues that universalism is not the decisive factor determining the political support for a programme. To substantiate this claim, Greenstein provides a detailed analysis of changes in spending on various social protection programmes during the budget cuts initiated by the Reagan administration, showing that most-targeted programmes fared much better than universal ones, such as disability pensions and unemployment insurance. Based on this evidence, Greenstein argues that targeted programmes can attract substantial political support when, in addition to the very poor, they also incorporate low-income and moderate-income working families, serve more “deserving” groups, such as pregnant women and children, are linked to work and viewed as effective, and do not provide cash benefits to able-bodied people. Thus, instead of “targeting within universalism,” Greenstein places greater emphasis on a mixture of universal and means-tested programmes, with a substantial role for targeting, especially given the tight fiscal constraints (and public opposition to higher taxes) prevalent in the United States at the time. Even though the two papers provide sound theoretical reasons for how the underlying distributional principles and other factors might influence the outcomes of welfare programmes, their main limitation is their focus on a single country, which is generally viewed as an exceptional, rather than a typical case of a Western welfare state.

In contrast, K&P sought to approach the issue from a cross-national perspective, focusing on the link between different types of social policy models and aggregate outcomes, such as poverty and inequality. K&P’s theoretical starting point is that the Western welfare states differ in institutional structures, as they pursue different “strategies of equality” (Reference Korpi and Palme1998, p. 664). The targeted model uses a “Robin Hood” strategy, by providing low-level transfers to people on a low income. The basic security model adopts a “simple egalitarian strategy,” by giving low-level but equal benefits to everyone, which, in relative terms, is more important for those on low incomes. In contrast, the corporatist model uses a “Biblical Matthew principle,” by giving more to the better-off to reward the contributions they have made through making social insurance contributions. The encompassing model also uses this strategy but unlike the corporatist model – which excludes non-contributors – it also provides generous support to low-income families. The crucial difference between the three strategies lies in the use of targeting through means testing, which plays a major role in the targeted models, a lesser one in the basic security models, and a minimal one in the corporatist and encompassing models. Another distinction is in the level of transfers, which are low in targeted and basic security models, and high in corporatist and encompassing models.

K&P’s central hypothesis, regarding the link between the institutional model and redistributive outcomes to an extent, echoes the one put forward by Skocpol (Reference Skocpol, Jencks and Peterson1991) but entails a more complex causal mechanism that can be broken down into seven core assumptions (see Figure 1). The causal mechanism starts with the prevailing institutional structure of the welfare state, which influences the formation of class coalitions and levels of public support for redistribution (1). Where means testing dominates, the middle-class allies itself with the upper class to contain welfare spending from which it benefits little, driving down public support for redistribution. Where universalism prevails, the middle-class forms coalitions with the working class to alter the market distribution of resources, by redistributing incomes from the upper-income class. The type of class coalitions and levels of support are, in turn, critical for determining the size of the redistributive budget (2). In democracies, sustaining high levels of public spending requires support from a broad coalition of the middle and working classes. For this reason, more universalist welfare states have larger redistributive budgets than selective welfare states (3). The logical next step is that larger volumes of social spending lead to more redistribution (4). In addition, generous welfare benefits reduce the need for private alternatives, which entail no redistribution and would, therefore, lead to less-equal outcomes (5 and 6). Cumulatively, a large volume of spending and limited private provision is the mechanism that explains the “paradox of redistribution”: the less the countries resort to targeting through means testing, the more they reduce poverty and inequality. Conversely, the more they try to channel resources to the poor, the less effective they are in achieving their egalitarian objectives (7).

Figure 1. The causal assumptions in K&P’s paradox of redistribution.

K&P’s empirical analysis draws on micro-level data from the Luxembourg Income Study (LIS), while also utilizing several macro-level indicators from the International Labour Organization (ILO) and the OECD. Most of the analysis covers 11 affluent democracies, using LIS data from 1985, and involves a combination of descriptive statistics and bivariate correlations. It shows that more universal welfare states indeed spent a larger proportion of GDP on social protection and had considerably lower rates of inequality and poverty. The relative size of the redistributive budget was found to be strongly positively correlated with redistribution (measured as the difference between Gini coefficients of market and disposable incomes divided by Gini coefficient of market income), while the correlation between the degree of targeting and redistribution was weaker and negative, implying that welfare states relying more on means testing achieve less redistribution. Furthermore, greater selectivity was associated with lower levels of transfers for both social insurance and means-tested benefits. The assumptions concerning the link between institutional design and private provision were tested using the income distribution of pensioners. While public pensions were found to be the most unequal (measured as the difference between the maximum and the average pensions) in the most universalist countries, the opposite was true for pensioners’ disposable income. Further analysis confirmed K&P’s assumptions, as countries with more equal pensions were found to spend more on private pensions, and, in turn, the spending on private pensions was strongly positively correlated with inequality in the gross income of older people. In sum, the results provided support for most of K&P’s assumptions, although it should be stressed that the first two fundamental assumptions concerning the relationships between the institutional design, class coalitions and the size of the redistributive budget were not subjected to empirical testing due to lack of relevant micro data. In the remainder of this paper, we review more recent empirical evidence concerning each of the steps in the causal mechanism.

Reviewing the empirical evidence concerning K&P’s causal assumptions

Do universal welfare systems generate broader class coalitions and thus greater public support for redistribution?

Most studies examining the link between institutional design and popular welfare attitudes have approached the issue from the perspective of Esping-Andersen’s (Reference Esping-Andersen1990) well-known welfare regime framework. The standard hypothesis is that universalist social-democratic regimes generate higher levels of support than selectivist liberal regimes, with corporatist-conservative regimes falling somewhere in between.Footnote 4 However, public opinion studies typically conclude that the empirical evidence for the regime hypothesis is “inconclusive” (Kangas, Reference Kangas2003), “inconsistent” and “ambiguous” (Wendt, Mischke, & Pfeifer, Reference Wendt, Mischke and Pfeifer2011), “mixed” (Blekesaune & Quadagno, Reference Blekesaune and Quadagno2003; Jæger, Reference Jæger2006), “contradictory” (Larsen, Reference Larsen2006), “limited” (Svallfors, Reference Svallfors2013) or “weak” (Bean & Papadakis, Reference Bean and Papadakis1998). There are simply too many country cases that deviate from the expected regime pattern, and the within-regime differences often prove to be as large as the between-regime differences (see also Arts and Gelissen, Reference Arts and Gelissen2001; Dallinger, Reference Dallinger2010; Fraile & Ferrer, Reference Fraile and Ferrer2005; Gelissen, Reference Gelissen2000; Gevers et al., Reference Gevers, Gelissen, Arts and Muffels2000; Jakobsen, Reference Jakobsen2011; Papadakis & Bean, Reference Papadakis and Bean1993; Svallfors, Reference Svallfors2012; Taylor-Gooby, Reference Taylor-Gooby2001).

It has become increasingly clear, however, that it matters a great deal for which specific dependent variables are being studied. When public opinion towards broad and encompassing programmes (such as pensions and healthcare) are scrutinized, no clear-cut regime pattern unfolds, for the simple reason that such programmes are supported by clear majorities in all countries (Bean & Papadakis, Reference Bean and Papadakis1998; Blekesaune & Quadagno, Reference Blekesaune and Quadagno2003; Gelissen, Reference Gelissen2001a; Gevers et al., Reference Gevers, Gelissen, Arts and Muffels2000; Wendt et al., Reference Wendt, Mischke and Pfeifer2011). Some argue that only popular attitudes towards redistribution and aid to the poor/unemployed, which tend to vary much more across countries, follow a regime logic (Jæger, Reference Jæger2006; Larsen, Reference Larsen2006; Svallfors, Reference Svallfors and Vogel2003, Reference Svallfors2004), at least when attention is limited to some of the closest representatives of Esping–Andersen’s worlds of welfare (see eg. Andreβ & Heien, Reference Andreβ and Heien2001; Linos & West, Reference Linos and West2003). In liberal countries, where reliance on means-tested benefits is greater, the support base for redistribution from higher to lower incomes (which is at the core of K&P’s argument) does tend to be smaller than in social-democratic and conservative countries, where social benefits are distributed on a more universal basis. The few studies conducted outside of the dominant welfare regime framework – using more direct measurements of institutional design – seem to confirm that selectivism is indeed associated with lower popular support for redistribution (Brady & Bostic, Reference Brady and Bostic2015; Jacques & Noël, Reference Jacques and Noël2018).

However, the higher levels of support for redistribution found in universal systems are most definitely not due to the formation of broader class coalitions, as K&P suggested. As far as class conflicts are concerned, the existing body of literature is unequivocal: patterns of attitudinal divisions among different social classes are relatively similar in different worlds of welfare (Blekesaune & Quadagno, Reference Blekesaune and Quadagno2003; Edlund, Reference Edlund2006; Gelissen, Reference Gelissen2000; Jaeger, Reference Jaeger2009; Larsen, Reference Larsen2006; Svallfors, Reference Svallfors1997, Reference Svallfors and Vogel2003, Reference Svallfors2004, Reference Svallfors2012; Taylor-Gooby, Reference Taylor-Gooby2001; Wendt et al., Reference Wendt, Mischke and Pfeifer2011). To the best of our knowledge, only one study suggests otherwise. In revisiting Linos and West (Reference Linos and West2003) and Svallfors (Reference Svallfors1997) concluded that class does matter more in liberal regimes (ie. Australia and the United States) than it does in social-democratic (ie. Norway) and conservative (ie. Germany) ones. However, because most other studies have failed to confirm that different regime types create different class cleavages, there is strikingly little evidence that polarization across classes is sharper in selectivist liberal regimes. Furthermore, at the level of specific social policy programmes, there is little clear-cut empirical support for the claim that the middle classes unite with the higher classes in their support for universal benefits and their opposition to means-tested ones (Forma, Reference Forma1997; Goul-Andersen, Reference Goul-Andersen2011; Kangas, Reference Kangas1995; Pettersen, Reference Pettersen2001). Thus, even though K&P were correct in arguing that universal systems generate higher support for redistribution, this cannot be explained from the perspective of class interests and coalitions. Instead, others suggest that it has more to do with short-term self-interest (Pierson, Reference Pierson and Pierson2001), norms of procedural fairness (Rothstein, Reference Rothstein1998) and popular deservingness beliefs (Larsen, Reference Larsen2006). That is, universal systems may yield more public support because they (1) have larger welfare constituencies, irrespective of social classes, (2) are perceived to function better in terms of, eg. administrative cost, complexity and benefit abuse and (3) nurture less-divisive public discussions about the deservingness of welfare recipients (Blomberg & Kroll, Reference Blomberg and Kroll1999; Laenen, Reference Laenen2018; Roosma, van Oorschot, & Gelissen, Reference Roosma, van Oorschot and Gelissen2014; Rothstein, Reference Rothstein1998; van Oorschot & Roosma, Reference van Oorschot, Roosma, van Oorschot, Roosma, Meuleman and Reeskens2017).

Are higher levels of public support for redistribution associated with larger redistributive budgets?

One of K&P’s implicit causal assumptions is that broader class coalitions and higher levels of public support for redistribution will ultimately lead to larger redistributive budgets because political elites operating in democratic polities have strong electoral incentives to be responsive to mass opinion (Burstein, Reference Burstein2003; Jacques & Noël, Reference Jacques and Noël2018; Page & Shapiro, Reference Page and Shapiro1983). Therefore, a certain degree of correspondence between the preferred size of the redistributive budget among the public and the actual size of that budget is to be expected. Only a few studies, however, have examined this opinion-policy link empirically (Myles, Reference Myles2006). In line with K&P’s assumption, Brooks and Manza (Reference Brooks and Manza2006b, Reference Brooks and Manza2006a, Reference Brooks and Manza2007) found that both between and within countries, higher levels of public support for redistribution give rise to higher levels of social expenditure (measured as a percentage of GDP). A few years later, Kenworthy (Reference Kenworthy2009, p. 739) replicated Brooks and Manza’s empirical analyses but came to the opposite conclusion: “the empirical case for public opinion’s influence [on social expenditure] remains to be made.” His first argument is that there is no evidence whatsoever for an over-time association between support and spending within countries. The second argument is related to a concern regarding reverse causality, as the “positive cross-country correlation could well be a function of earlier programme generosity causing public support, rather than of public support influencing programme generosity” (Kenworthy, Reference Kenworthy2009, pp. 732–733), see also Myles (Reference Myles2006)).

Of course, the idea that public policies also shape public opinion is nothing new in comparative welfare state research. In fact, it is one of the central tenets of policy feedback theory and a common assumption in welfare attitudes research (Campbell, Reference Campbell2012; Kumlin & Stadelmann-Steffen, Reference Kumlin and Stadelmann-Steffen2014; Larsen, Reference Larsen2006). Most studies within this field treat support for redistribution as an individual-level, dependent variable and social expenditure as a context-level, independent variable. However, the empirical evidence is inconclusive. Without establishing causality, some studies find a positive relationship between social spending and citizens’ support for redistribution (Brady & Finnigan, Reference Brady and Finnigan2014; Dallinger, Reference Dallinger2010; Jæger, Reference Jæger2006) but others report a non-significant association (Jaeger, Reference Jaeger2013; Van Oorschot & Meuleman, Reference Van Oorschot, Meuleman, Kumlin and Stadelmann-Steffen2014), or even a negative one (Burgoon, Koster, & van Egmond, Reference Burgoon, Koster and van Egmond2012; Jaeger, Reference Jaeger2013). Much seems to depend on the specific selection of countries, time periods, public opinion measurements, control variables and statistical techniques. To make sense of the contrasting findings, some researchers have argued that the relationship between social spending and support for redistribution is perhaps not linear, as is typically assumed but curvilinear. According to the “saturation” (Dallinger, Reference Dallinger2010) or “growth to limits” (Jæger, Reference Jæger2006) hypothesis, popular demand for redistribution is curbed once the maximum amount of taxes that citizens are willing to pay for the financing of redistributive policies is reached. This should help to explain why Scandinavians, eg. are often found to be less supportive of further redistribution than Southern Europeans, given that they live in mature and already high-spending welfare states (Gelissen, Reference Gelissen2001b; Noël & Thérien, Reference Noël and Thérien2002). Some empirical studies have used a quadratic term for social spending to capture the curvilinear nature of the spending-support relationship, but have not corroborated it (Dallinger, Reference Dallinger2010; Jæger, Reference Jæger2006).

In sum, the most conservative conclusion that can be drawn from the studies discussed above is that there seems to be a positive, but not necessarily causal, correlation between public support for redistribution and the size of the redistributive budget; a relationship that exists only at the aggregate, between-country level. However, most studies have been so preoccupied with the causality issue that they seem to have forgotten the importance of “needs-adjusting” social spending figures (Clasen & Siegel, Reference Clasen and Siegel2007), which pose a serious threat to the validity of their findings. Because social expenditure is not only a product of welfare state generosity but also of population composition, the positive correlation with public support for redistribution might be driven by the needs of that population (eg. unemployment rates). Clearly, K&P’s causal assumption concerns the link between welfare state generosity and public support, not its relationship to population composition. Therefore, Brady and Bostic (Reference Brady and Bostic2015, p. 271) use “transfer share,” which they define as “the size or extent of the welfare state within the average household’s income” and consider “a household-level version of welfare effort” as an alternative measurement for the redistributive budget size. Their results show no significant association between transfer share and public support for redistribution, suggesting that the size of the redistributive budget perhaps does not increase with support levels, after all.

Is the size of the redistributive budget larger in universal welfare systems?

Research concerning the link between the institutional design and redistributive budgets has focused on two related, yet distinctive aspects of the latter: the volume of spending and resilience to retrenchment, either at the (welfare) state-level or that of or specific policies. With regard to the first, studies have sought to verify whether more universalist welfare states are indeed more generous in terms of overall spending. The empirical tests typically involve replicating the method used by K&P – bivariate plots of income redistribution and the volume of spending – as well as modifying the measurements of redistribution and spending in order to better align them with the theoretical framework. In addition, later studies have used more sophisticated regression models that allow several closely related variables to be controlled for, such as GDP per capita, unemployment, and dependency rates (eg. Jacques & Noël, Reference Jacques and Noël2018; Jesuit & Mahler, Reference Jesuit and Mahler2004). Several of these studies appear to support K&P’s assumption. In a comparative study of income redistribution using 59 LIS data from 13 OECD countries between the 1970s and 2000s, Jesuit and Mahler (Reference Jesuit and Mahler2004) report a strong negative correlation between the (low-income) targeting efficiency and the relative size of transfers (the proportion of public transfers in household income). Exploring the effects of taxes and transfers on income redistribution in 24 OECD countries by the mid-2000s, Whiteford (Reference Whiteford2008) found that countries with systems targeted less at the poor had higher social spending. Similarly, Marx et al. (Reference Marx, Salanauskaite and Verbist2013) identified a relatively weak but still positive, relationship between universalism and the generosity of welfare spending in 25 advanced welfare states. In a time-series cross-sectional analysis to revisit the “paradox of redistribution” using data from 2000 to 2011 in 20 OECD countries, Jacques and Noël (Reference Jacques and Noël2018) found that universalism was associated with higher public social spending as a proportion of GDP.Footnote 5 The same authors also identified a positive correlation between universalism and social spending in 21 OECD countries in a more recent paper (Jacques & Noël, Reference Jacques and Noël2020).

More ambiguous results were reported by Brady and Bostic (Reference Brady and Bostic2015, pp. 272–274), who argue that universalism and low-income targeting are not opposite sides of a continuum but represent two separate dimensions; with universalism being “homogeneity across the population in benefits, coverage and eligibility,” and low-income targeting a “disproportionate concentration of welfare transfers in low-income households.” Replicating the “paradox of redistribution” analysis using LIS data with two separate samples of 20 affluent democracies and 37 countries (including those 20 democracies), Brady and Bostic found that universalism was indeed positively correlated with higher spending. However, they also found that low-income targeting was associated with more generous welfare. In the case of the broader sample, they partially explained this seeming contradiction by pointing out that, in some developing countries, social spending was both low and skewed in favour of the higher income groups; once the poor started to be incorporated in the system, both low-income targeting and spending levels improved. However, the positive relationship between low-income targeting and welfare generosity also persisted in the case of the restricted sample. Another study focusing on the level of specific policies, rather than the welfare state level, also provides evidence that disputes the existence of the link between the provision mode and the size of the redistributive budget. In a study of targeting, child benefits, and child poverty in 26 EU countries, Van Lancker and Van Mechelen (Reference Van Lancker and Van Mechelen2015) found no correlation between the degree to which child benefits were targeted at low-income families and the proportion of GDP allocated for child benefits (including tax credits).

Even if universalism is indeed associated with more generous spending, this in itself does not guarantee immunity from cuts. This is particularly true for mature welfare states, in which there have been different degrees of retrenchment over the last three decades. As a matter of fact, Pierson (Reference Pierson1994) pointed out that the large size of the budget makes universal programmes a logical target for politicians seeking to roll back what they see as an overinflated welfare state. Pierson substantiated this argument by tracking the evolution of social protection programmes in the United States and the United Kingdom. during the times of retrenchment initiated by, respectively, Reagan and Thatcher. He found that despite the harsh rhetoric deployed against the beneficiaries of means-tested assistance, the actual retrenchment of these programmes was far less substantial than in the case of universal programmes such as unemployment benefits and child cash transfers. In addition to fiscal considerations, Pierson argues that both administrations also sought to avoid being seen as hostile to the poor; while the public might initially have shared the general criticism of “idle” recipients of social assistance, multiple polling results showed that the electorate did not react positively to cutting the already meagre support for the poor.

The results of comparative studies do not support the idea of selective benefits being more resilient than universal ones, but neither do they lend much support to the opposite hypothesis. In a study using the same sample of countries as K&P, but with longitudinal data for a period between the mid-1980s and the mid-2000s, Kenworthy (Reference Kenworthy2011) found no association between the degree of targeting and changes to redistribution, thus rejecting the idea that more universal systems are more capable of resisting spending cuts. Tracking the retrenchment of general means-tested assistance vis-à-vis three social insurance programmes – old-age pensions, unemployment insurance, and sickness insurance – in 18 OECD countries between 1990 and 2002, Nelson (Reference Nelson2007) found that the social insurance programmes fared better during this period. However, the observed difference between the two types of programmes was relatively small, as both were subject to a considerable decline in generosity when compared with the increases in wages. Moreover, in nearly half of the countries, means-tested assistance was found to be more resilient than at least one of the social insurance programmes. Furthermore, means-tested benefits appeared more vulnerable in more universalist countries than in those that aimed to provide basic security (mainly Anglo-Saxon states). In sum, it appears that more universal welfare states do have larger redistributive budgets, but the institutional design is not a safeguard against cuts.

Does the size of the redistributive budget matter for reducing poverty and income inequality?

The assumption that more spending leads to more poverty reduction appears to be well supported by empirical evidence. Jesuit and Mahler (Reference Jesuit and Mahler2004) regressed redistribution achieved through transfers on the size of social budgets, while also controlling for several macro variables, including the progressivity of transfers. They found that social spending had a positive and statistically significant effect. Similarly, using a multilevel model controlling for macro-level variables, Brady and Bostic (Reference Brady and Bostic2015) found that the volume of social spending had a strong negative effect on relative poverty. The same conclusion can be drawn from Jacques and Noël’s (Reference Jacques and Noël2018, Reference Jacques and Noël2020) studies using regression analysis, as they found strong effects of social spending on poverty and redistribution. Using LIS data from the mid-2000s for a sample of 40 high- and medium-income countries, Ferrarini et al. (Reference Ferrarini, Nelson and Palme2016) also reported that both bivariate correlations and multilevel regression models confirmed higher spending led to a lower incidence of relative poverty among elderly people. Likewise, in a study of single-mother poverty in 18 OECD countries, Brady and Burroway (Reference Brady and Burroway2012) found that two indicators of welfare generosity – a welfare state index derived through several welfare spending indicators and the average proportion of median income that households receive in social transfers – had strong negative effects on single mothers’ likelihood of being poor.

Further supporting evidence comes from a study by Nelson (Reference Nelson2004), although instead of directly comparing the effects of budget size (and targeting accuracy), Nelson sought to separate the poverty-reducing effects of social transfers into the contributions of means-tested and non-means-tested transfers in five countries: Canada, Germany, Sweden, the United States, and the United Kingdom. The analysis, based on LIS data from the mid-1990s, showed that in all countries, non-means-tested benefits lifted much larger proportions of people out of poverty. Moreover, Sweden and Germany – with much more generous and wider coverage (and thus more expensive) social insurance systems – were considerably more successful in reducing poverty through transfers than the Anglo-Saxon countries.

While the reviewed evidence unequivocally points to the importance of the redistributive budget size for redistribution and poverty reduction, it should be borne in mind that, in some cases, smaller welfare spending can be compensated for by accurate targeting. For example, the study by Whiteford (Reference Whiteford2008) confirmed the countries that achieved the largest reductions in inequality were universalist ones with large volumes of spending, such as Sweden, Belgium and Denmark. However, the analysis also shows that the United Kingdom achieved the same progress as Germany in reducing inequality, despite spending almost half as much, and Australia achieved the same as France, which spent twice as much. Moreover, zooming in on the proportion of transfers that reached the bottom income quintile, Australia was found to allocate the same volume of cash support (in relative terms) as Norway, despite spending two-thirds of the latter’s budget. Similarly, New Zealand allocated as much to the poorest 20 per cent as Luxembourg, despite spending less than half of what the latter did.

Does a larger redistributive budget lead to less private welfare provision, and less private provision to lower levels of poverty and income inequality?

Of all the assumptions in K&P’s thesis, the least controversial seems the idea that people are more likely to resort to private provision when they are dissatisfied with public benefits and services. Furthermore, that private provision leads to less-equal outcomes as, unlike social insurance, there is no (or very limited) risk pooling across different income groups. Perhaps, for this reason – but also because private welfare is a relatively under-researched topic in general – there is very limited empirical evidence available to test this assumption in a comparative perspective. This is unfortunate, as the scarce evidence points in opposite directions, suggesting that this assumption may also be contentious.

Some evidence in support of both mechanisms – private social arrangements being a substitute for (inadequate) public welfare provision and private social spending being less redistributive – is provided by a study by Castles and Obinger (Reference Castles and Obinger2007) into the determinants of social expenditure. In a sample of 18 OECD countries, with detailed data on different types of social spending since the 1990s, the authors identified a negative correlation between (gross) public social spending and (net) current private spending, and the latter was associated with higher levels of poverty and inequality. However, it should be noted that neither of these correlations was statistically significant, while a negative association was shown between higher public spending and inequality and poverty.

More robust evidence corroborating the lower redistributive effects of private spending is offered by Goudswaard and Caminada (Reference Goudswaard and Caminada2010). In an analysis covering 25 OECD countries, around 2005, they tested the correlation between redistribution and public and private social spending, with the types of spending expressed separately in gross, as well as net (after tax) terms. The analysis showed that higher public spending was associated with more redistribution, while higher private spending was correlated with less redistribution. However, when disaggregating the analysis at the programme level, Goudswaard and Caminada also found that, while higher spending on all public programmes except incapacity benefits was associated with more progress in reducing inequality, within private arrangements, only higher spending on pensions was correlated with less success in redistribution.

Some work, however, provides evidence that indirectly contests K&P’s assumptions. In a study covering 14 OECD countries using LIS data, Marier and Skinner (Reference Marier, Skinner, Béland and Gran2008) found that stronger reliance on private pension provision was not associated with larger gaps between women’s and men’s pensions. In a smaller sample of nine countries, they also found no evidence that more generous minimum pensions reduce the need to invest in private pension schemes. In addition, Gelepithis (Reference Gelepithis2016) pointed out that the link between the generosity of public pensions and private provision may work in a way that differs from that suggested by K&P: instead of prompting people to opt for private alternatives, means-tested pensions can reduce the incentives for building up private savings. This, she argues, explains why several OECD countries, especially the Anglo-Saxon ones – Australia, Ireland, New Zealand and the United Kingdom – have, since the 1990s, consistently tried to expand the coverage of contributory and universal schemes, in order to limit means testing and the associated disincentives for saving.

Do universal welfare systems redistribute income and reduce poverty more than selective systems?

Kenworthy’s (Reference Kenworthy2011) study was one of the first that produced results contradicting K&P’s ultimate causal link between institutional design and welfare outcomes. While confirming the strong correlation between redistribution and the level of universalism in 1985, Kenworthy found that it gradually weakened before disappearing completely by 2005, as some “universal” countries became more selective (Denmark), while “selective” ones became more universal due to the maturation of old-age pension systems (eg. the United States). To explain this phenomenon, Kenworthy suggested a refinement of K&P’s thesis. He speculated that universalism matters at the initial stage of welfare state development: universal social insurance programmes assure the middle classes that the welfare state is primarily a social risk management tool rather than a vehicle for redistribution from the rich to the poor. In this context, it is easier for policymakers to target other programmes to people on low incomes, as these programmes will be viewed as of minor importance. Kenworthy argued that this is why Danish policy-makers were able to resort to more selectivity without compromising the volume of spending and redistribution. On the other hand, the lack of similar large-scale universal programmes did not foster strong support for welfare provision among the American middle class; therefore, an increase in the total spending did not translate into more redistribution.

Further evidence of the weakening or disappearance of the link between universalism and redistribution was offered by Marx et al. (Reference Marx, Salanauskaite and Verbist2013, Reference Marx, Salanauskaite and Verbist2016), who explicitly sought to replicate the results of K&P’s and Kenworthy’s studies, as well as extending the analysis to a sample of 25 affluent countries. Particularly valuable in Marx and colleagues’ studies is the use of multiple redistributions (the difference between Gini coefficients before and after tax and transfers versus the difference between market and gross incomes), income rank measurements (gross income vs. disposable income versus market income), and the alternative treatment of mandatory private and occupational pensions (market income vs. social transfers). This provides solid robustness checks of their key findings. Depending on the methodological choice, Marx and colleagues found that, in the early 2000s, there was either no association or a very weak positive one between low-income targeting and redistribution. Furthermore, decomposing the achieved redistribution by benefit types, they found that social assistance benefits made a disproportionately large contribution to the reduction of inequalities compared with other benefits, and that all highly redistributive systems contained strongly selective subsystems. Marx and colleagues’ explanation for this echoes Kenworthy’s hypothesis that the overall universality of a system allows the introduction of selective transfers without much public resentment. However, they also emphasized the changing role of selectivity in advanced welfare states: whereas in the mid-1980s social assistance was associated with work disincentives and dependency culture, its subsequent extension to low-income employed people and linking to the activation agenda have made it more popular both among the electorate and policymakers.

Equivocal results were reported by Brady and Bostic (Reference Brady and Bostic2015). On the one hand, in contrast to K&P, they found that low-income targeting was negatively associated with relative poverty in both restricted (20 democracies) and extended (37 democratic and non-democratic countries) samples. However, once they simultaneously controlled for the transfer share and for universalism (defined as homogeneity in transfers, coverage, and eligibility, as noted above), the association between low-income targeting and poverty was no longer robust. Universalism was also negatively correlated with poverty in both samples, but after controlling for low-income targeting and transfer share this association was no longer statistically significant. Overall, while corroborating some of the key assumptions of K&P’s paradox, Brady and Bostic suggested two new paradoxes of social policy based on the relationships they identified between poverty, support for redistribution, and their measurements of universalism and low-income targeting. The “non-complementarity” paradox implies that there is a mismatch between the determinants of poverty and support for redistribution: on the one hand, a higher transfer share reduces poverty but it is not related to support for redistribution; on the other hand, low-income targeting reduces support for redistribution but is not related to poverty. A positive correlation between the transfer share and low-income targeting leads to the second, “undermining” paradox: a higher transfer share implies stronger low-income targeting, which leads to less support for redistribution, thus undermining the poverty-reducing efforts achieved by the higher transfer share.

Jacques and Noël (Reference Jacques and Noël2018) found a positive, bivariate correlation between universalism and poverty reduction, although, as noted before, this disappeared when they controlled for social spending in a regression model. Thus, they suggested that the effects of universalism on poverty are mainly indirect, as proposed by K&P: more universalism leads to higher social expenditure, which in turn reduces poverty. Based on this, Jacques and Noel argue that K&P’s thesis is theoretically correct and continues to be valid in the first decade of the twenty-first century. However, they suggest that K&P’s operationalization of universalism was not appropriate, as it was measured by the concentration of transfers, which is influenced by factors other than low-income targeting, such as pre-transfer income distribution and the demographic profile of welfare beneficiaries. For example, if families with children are more likely to be poor than others, a universal benefit for them will appear as targeted towards low-income groups. Jacques and Noel proposed that this misspecification can be avoided if universalism is measured through policy design instead of redistribution outcomes. Hence the rationale for the measurement of universalism they used in their analysis; an index comprising two indicators: (1) the proportion of social benefits that are means tested and (2) the proportion of private spending in the total social expenditure.

In a later study, using an almost identical sample, Jacques and Noël (Reference Jacques and Noël2020) again reaffirmed the superiority of universalism but they added important qualifications to their argument. Within universalism, they propose a critical difference is made by the balance between old-age pensions and benefits for working-age population. Old-age pensions, especially those with strong second tier (contributory element), tend to favour the better-off, whereas benefits for working-age people are more pro-poor even without means testing due to the vulnerable situation of the recipients (ie. unemployed, families with many children, disabled people). Therefore, with a similar level of spending, those universal welfare states that direct a higher proportion of total spending towards working-age population reduce poverty more effectively than those that prioritize old-age pensions more.

Similar to Jacques and Noël (Reference Jacques and Noël2018), Van Lancker and Van Mechelen (Reference Van Lancker and Van Mechelen2015) also argued that assessments of policy intentions are more appropriate to capture the extent of universalism of a system than measurements of policy outcomes derived through transfer concentration indices. Thus, they constructed a targeting indicator measuring the variation in average child benefits that families with different income levels were entitled to. On this basis, Van Lancker and Van Mechelen found that, contrary to K&P’s findings, a higher degree of selectivism was associated with a greater reduction in child poverty, mainly because in more selective systems, low-income families received more generous benefits. However, they also stressed that the size of the redistributive budget matters, and that the countries in which the largest progress in reducing child poverty was achieved were those that used targeting within universalism, ie., universal systems with higher benefits for low-income groups (see also Skocpol, Reference Skocpol, Jencks and Peterson1991).

Conclusion

While certainly not the first to explore the political economy of universal and selective welfare provision, K&P’s investigation made an immense contribution to the study of the subject by developing a sophisticated multi-stage causal model and testing it empirically in a comparative context. What is more, like any exceptional study, it has inspired a large body of research, which with an increasing availability of high-quality comparative data and more advanced methods has provided a more nuanced understanding of the distributional implications of the institutional setup of Western welfare states.

However, 20 years after K&P’s initial study, there are substantial reasons to cast doubt on the validity of the causal model, even though the original empirical analysis has withstood rigorous re-examinations. As our review shows, the only assumption, ie., unequivocally supported by more recent studies is that higher welfare spending is associated with lower poverty and inequality but even in this regard there is some indication that countries can compensate for lower spending by more accurate targeting of low-income families. Furthermore, there is ample evidence that the very first stages in the causal mechanism – institutional structures of the welfare state influencing the formation of class coalitions and the latter affecting the size of the redistributive budget – are simply not correct, as class coalitions do not differ between welfare regimes. Perhaps, one of the main drawbacks of K&P’s study is that the very foundations of the causal mechanism were taken for granted based on theoretical reasoning instead of empirical material.

There are several other reasons, both objective and subjective, for the assumptions and the overall thesis possibly not being valid at present. One is that Western welfare states have changed substantially in the past 20 years. To deal with the persistent problem of “in-work poverty,” governments have extended the coverage of selective programmes to also incorporate people in paid work but on low incomes, who attract more sympathy from the public (and policy-makers) than the “idle” poor (Marx et al., Reference Marx, Salanauskaite and Verbist2013). At the same time, governments in most Western countries have sought to foster private provision, eg. by encouraging and mandating participation in private pension schemes (Ebbinghaus, Reference Ebbinghaus2015). These changes have undoubtedly affected the mechanisms in K&P’s causal chain. In addition, strong emphasis on activation policies and tougher conditionality placed on the recipients of social assistance (and unemployment benefits) may have also softened their image in the eyes of the wider public.

Other issues are the data limitations and methodological and theoretical choices made by K&P. A sample of 11 countries is far too small to draw conclusions that can be generalized to all welfare states, especially when using the relatively basic method of bivariate correlations. For example, if the original sample had included Mediterranean welfare states, which combine low levels of selectivity with low levels of redistribution, and are also characterized by a great deal of occupational segmentation in their social insurance systems, the observed associations would have undoubtedly become far weaker.Footnote 6 Furthermore, while it is often used to measure the progressivity of social transfers, a concentration index is a somewhat imperfect measurement of redistribution, as it is also influenced by the demographic profile of the sample and the pre-transfer distribution of incomes. Similarly, it has been shown that when the focus is shifted from gross to net social spending to take into account the fact that some countries tax certain social transfers while others do not, some countries (especially the universalist Scandinavian ones) are not as high spenders as is commonly assumed (Adema, Fron, & Ladaique, Reference Adema, Fron and Ladaique2011).

Despite these substantial causes for scepticism about the validity of K&P’s causal chain, the fact remains that more universalist countries tend to have better redistributional outcomes. In this respect, perhaps we should bear in mind the caution expressed by K&P (Reference Korpi and Palme1998, p. 673) that “Institutional structures, however, are only one of many factors that affect the distribution of income in a country … Political traditions, demographic composition, labour force participation rates, levels of unemployment, wage setting practices, and industrial structures are also important.” In addition to these matters, there is a strong rationale for considering a confounding variable problem suggested by Marx et al. (Reference Marx, Salanauskaite and Verbist2013, p. 8):

An extensive welfare state, as well as a limited degree of wage inequality may both be the result of variables that determine both… A society in which the value of solidarity is widely shared may simultaneously support pay norms, collective agreements and adequate minimum wages, as well as quasi-universal and generous benefits.

Beyond the purely academic value, the reviewed evidence has practical implications that can be taken on board by both policymakers and those who advocate on behalf of the poor. While any general recommendation risks the fallacy of one-size-fits-all, it seems reasonable to suggest that in their pure forms neither universalism nor selectivism can be the most optimal remedy for addressing poverty and inequality. Targeting, however, seems to work best when embedded within the overall framework of universalism (Marx et al., Reference Marx, Salanauskaite and Verbist2013, Reference Marx, Salanauskaite and Verbist2016; Van Lancker & Van Mechelen, Reference Van Lancker and Van Mechelen2015). Hence the rationale for a combined approach of deploying selective measures alongside and within universal programmes. The required balance between universalism and selectivism will inevitably vary across countries but in any context, it seems important that selective policies are not too narrowly targeted at the very poor. Instead, they should also include low-income groups; especially those viewed as more deserving, either because they lack control over their situation (eg. children), or because they pay back society in some way (eg. people who work in low-paid jobs) (van Oorschot, Reference van Oorschot2006). In this respect, working tax credits and wage supplements seem particularly promising. In parallel, other ways of improving targeting of low-income people within the universal framework, eg. by redirecting expenditure from old-age pensions towards certain categorical working-age benefits as proposed by Jacques and Noël (Reference Jacques and Noël2020), also appear promising and deserve further consideration.

Before concluding, we would like to point out several potential avenues for further research in addition to the need for considering the confounding variable issue and a more comprehensive set of structural determinants of income distribution, as argued above. There is surprisingly limited empirical evidence on the social legitimacy of universal vis-à-vis selective welfare provision. Future studies could narrow this gap by analysing the primary divisions (ie. socio-demographic and ideological) in these preferences and how (and why) these vary across countries and over time. Similarly, research into private welfare provision has not kept pace with the actual policy developments in this field. In addition to analysing the distributional implications of increased reliance on private provision, future research could also shed light on the drivers of the general trend: whether it is inadequate public benefits that push people towards private alternatives or whether it is the high costs of universal provision that prompts policymakers to encourage (and mandate) the privatization of social risks. Lastly, it should be stressed that with the notable exception of Brady and Bostic (Reference Brady and Bostic2015) and Ferrarini et al. (Reference Ferrarini, Nelson and Palme2016), almost all of the available evidence comes from developed welfare states. Extending the geographic coverage to less-developed countries could help to determine how universal the political economy of universalism versus selectivism is.

Acknowledgement

The authors would like to thank the anonymous reviewers and the journal editors for their constructive feedback which certainly helped improve the paper. The authors are also grateful to Joakim Palme and other participants of the Redistribution Panel of the 26th International Research Seminar on Issues in Social Security (organised by the Foundation for International Studies on Social Security (FISS) in Sigtuna, Sweden, on 11 July, 2019) for their comments and suggestions. Also, valuable feedback was received from the participants of Tilburg-Leuven-Antwerp joint seminar (held in Leuven, Belgium, on 5 March, 2019). Any remaining errors remain the authors’ sole responsibility.

Notes on contributors

Tijs Laenen a social worker turned social scientist, currently working as a post-doctoral researcher at the Centre for Sociological Research (CESO) at KU Leuven, Belgium. His main research interest and expertise lies in studying popular attitudes towards differently targeted and differently organized welfare state policies.

Dimitri Gugushvili is a post-doctoral researcher at the Centre for Sociological Research (CESO) at KU Leuven, Belgium. His research interests include social protection systems and welfare attitudes in former communist countries, redistributional effects of universal and means-tested social policies, and child poverty.

Footnotes

1 It should be noted, however, that in its original formulation, the paradox also refers to the second core aspect of social transfers – the level of benefits. That is, K&P (Reference Korpi and Palme1998, p. 661) also argue that “the more concerned we are with creating equality via equal public transfers to all, the less likely we are to reduce poverty and inequality.” According to K&P’s analyses, earnings-related benefits are a more efficient redistributive strategy than flat-rate benefits. This benefit level component has, however, attracted considerably less interest in the debate compared to the benefit access component, which is why it is not included in the present review article.

2 According to Google Scholar, K&P’s article in the American Sociological Review, “The paradox of redistribution and strategies of equality: Welfare state institutions, inequality, and poverty in the Western countries,” has been cited 2,210 times. In Web of Science, which only keeps a record of peer-reviewed journal articles, 643 citations are noted.

3 Throughout the article, the term universalism refers to broad, encompassing social policies that are accessible to broad segments of the population – including the middle classes – on the basis of citizenship, residency, or in some cases work record. The term selectivism is used as a synonym for the concept of targeting, which in this article refers to social policies that are aimed exclusively at poor people, mostly (but not always) through means testing. These definitions are in line with the interpretations of K&P (Reference Korpi and Palme1998, p. 661), who argue that a targeted social policy is “organized for the poor only” while a universal policy “includes all citizens.”

4 The regime approach to welfare attitudes has always struggled to incorporate some of the additional regime types that have been identified over the years, such as the Mediterranean and post-communist types (Arts & Gelissen, Reference Arts and Gelissen2002). Expectations regarding the level of support in welfare regimes other than Esping–Andersen’s three worlds of welfare have never been clear-cut but prior research shows that Southern and Eastern European nations tend to rank highest of all in terms of public support for social welfare (Dallinger, Reference Dallinger2010; Svallfors, Reference Svallfors2012).

5 In this study, universalism was operationalized through an index comprising two components: (1) the proportion of social benefits that are means-tested and (2) the proportion of private spending in the total social expenditure.

6 The reason for focusing exclusively on mature democracies, while not discussed in detail, appears to be that in order for class coalitions to influence a policy, a country must have a democratic form of governance. However, this also implies that public preferences for welfare provision do not matter in non-democratic or newly (re)democratized states, which is a somewhat inaccurate assumption.

References

Adema, W., Fron, P., & Ladaique, M. (2011). Is the European welfare state really more expensive? Indicators on social spending, 1980–2012; and a manual to the OECD social expenditure database (SOCX). (OECD social, employment and migration, Working paper no. 124).Google Scholar
Andreβ, H.-J., & Heien, T. (2001). Four worlds of welfare state attitudes? A comparison of Germany, Norway, and the United States. European Sociological Review, 17(4), 337356.10.1093/esr/17.4.337CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Arts, W., & Gelissen, J. (2001). Welfare states, solidarity and justice principles: Does the type really matter? Acta Sociologica, 44(4), 283299.10.1177/000169930104400401CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Arts, W., & Gelissen, J. (2002). Three worlds of welfare capitalism or more? A state-of-the-art report. Journal of European Social Policy, 12(2), 137158.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bean, C., & Papadakis, E. (1998). A comparison of mass attitudes towards the welfare state in different institutional regimes, 1985–1990. International Journal of Public Opinion Research, 10(3), 211236.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Besley, T. (1990). Means testing versus universal provision in poverty alleviation programmes. Economica, 57, 119129.10.2307/2554085CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Blekesaune, M., & Quadagno, J. (2003). Public attitudes toward welfare state policies: A comparative analysis of 24 nations. European Sociological Review, 19(5), 415427.10.1093/esr/19.5.415CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Blomberg, H., & Kroll, C. (1999). Do structural contexts matter? Macro-sociological factors and popular attitudes towards public welfare services. Acta Sociologica, 42(4), 319335.10.1177/000169939904200403CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Brady, D., & Bostic, A. (2015). Paradoxes of social policy: Welfare transfers, relative poverty, and redistribution preferences. American Sociological Review, 80(2), 268298.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Brady, D., & Burroway, R. (2012). Targeting, universalism and single-mother povert: A multi-level analysis across 18 affluent democracies. Demography, 49(2), 719746.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Brady, D., & Finnigan, R. (2014). Does immigration undermine public support for social policy? American Sociological Review, 79(1), 1742.10.1177/0003122413513022CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Brooks, C., & Manza, J. (2006a). Social policy responsiveness in developed democracies. American Sociological Review, 71(3), 474494.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Brooks, C., & Manza, J. (2006b). Why do welfare states persist? The Journal of Politics, 68(4), 816827.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Brooks, C., & Manza, J. (2007). Why welfare states persist: The importance of public opinion in democracies. Chicago, IL: The University of Chicago Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Burgoon, B., Koster, F., & van Egmond, M. (2012). Support for redistribution and the paradox of immigration. Journal of European Social Policy, 22(3), 288304.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Burstein, P. (2003). The impact of public opinion on public policy: A review and an agenda. Political Research Quarterly, 56(1), 2940.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Campbell, A. L. (2012). Policy makes mass politics. Annual Review of Political Science, 15, 333351.10.1146/annurev-polisci-012610-135202CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Castles, F., & Obinger, H. (2007). Social expenditure and the politics of redistribution. Journal of European Social Policy, 17(3), 206222.10.1177/0958928707078364CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Clasen, J., & Siegel, N. A. (2007). Investigating welfare state change : The “dependent variable problem” in comparative analysis. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dallinger, U. (2010). Public support for redistribution: What explains cross-national differences? Journal of European Social Policy, 20(4), 333349.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ebbinghaus, B. (2015). The privatization and marketization of pensions in Europe: A double transformation facing the crisis. European Policy Analysis, 1(1), 5673.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Edlund, J. (2006). Trust in the capability of the welfare state and general welfare support: Sweden 1997–2002. Acta Sociologica, 49(4), 395417.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Esping-Andersen, G. (1990). The three worlds of welfare capitalism. Cambridge, UK: Polity Press.Google Scholar
Ferrarini, T., Nelson, K., & Palme, J. (2016). Social transfers and poverty in middle- and high-income countries – A global perspective. Global Social Policy, 16(1), 2246.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Forma, P. (1997). The rational legitimacy of the welfare state: Popular support for ten income transfer schemes in Finland. Policy and Politics, 25(3), 235249.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fraile, M., & Ferrer, M. (2005). Explaining the determinants of public support for cuts in unemployment benefits spending across OECD countries. International Sociology, 20(4), 459481.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gelepithis, M. (2016). Rethinking the paradox of redistribution: How private insurance and means testing can lead to universalizing reform. (LSE Europe in question discussion paper series no. 114/2016).10.2139/ssrn.2815442CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gelissen, J. (2000). Popular support for institutionalized solidarity: A comparison between European welfare states. International Journal of Social Welfare, 9, 285300.10.1111/1468-2397.00140CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gelissen, J. (2001a). Old-age pensions: Individual or collective responsibility? An investigation of public opinion across European welfare states. European Societies, 3(4), 495523.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gelissen, J. (2001b). Worlds of welfare, worlds of consent? Public opinion on the welfare state. [Doctoral dissertation]. Amsterdam: Thela Thesis.Google Scholar
Gevers, J., Gelissen, J., Arts, W., & Muffels, R. (2000). Public health care in the balance: Exploring popular support for health care systems in the European Union. International Journal of Social Welfare, 9, 301321.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Goodin, R. E., & Le Grand, J. (1987). Not only the poor: The middle classes and the welfare state. London, UK: Allen & Unwin.Google Scholar
Goudswaard, K., & Caminada, K. (2010). The redistributive effect of public and private social programmes: A cross-country empirical analysis. International Social Security Review, 63(1), 119.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Goul-Andersen, J. (2011). Ambivalent values : Universalism or targeting? Welfare state attitudes in Denmark.Google Scholar
Greenstein, R. (1991). Universal and targeted approaches to relieving poverty: An alternative view. In Jencks, C. & Peterson, P. E. (Eds.), The urban underclass. Washington, DC: The Brookings Institution.Google Scholar
Jacques, O., & Noël, A. (2018). The case for welfare state universalism, or the lasting relevance of the paradox of redistribution. Journal of European Social Policy, 28(1), 7085.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Jacques, O., & Noël, A. (2020). Targeting within universalism. Journal of European Social Policy. doi:10.1177/0958928720918973.Google Scholar
Jæger, M. M. (2006). Welfare regimes and attitudes towards redistribution: The regime hypothesis revisited. European Sociological Review, 22(2), 157170.10.1093/esr/jci049CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Jaeger, M. M. (2009). United but divided: Welfare regimes and the level and variance in public support for redistribution. European Sociological Review, 25(6), 723737.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Jaeger, M. M. (2013). The effect of macroeconomic and social conditions on the demand for redistribution: A pseudo panel approach. Journal of European Social Policy, 23(2), 149163.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Jakobsen, G. T. (2011). Welfare attitudes and social expenditure: Do regimes shape public opinion?. Source: Social Indicators Research, 101(3), 323340. Retrieved from http://www.jstor.org/stable/41476449 Google Scholar
Jesuit, D., & Mahler, V. (2004). State redistribution in comparative perspective: A cross-national analysis of the developed countries (No. 392).Google Scholar
Kangas, O. (2003). The grasshopper and the ants: Popular opinions of just distribution in Australia and Finland. The Journal of Socio-Economics, 31, 721743.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kangas, O. E. (1995). Attitudes on means-tested social benefits in Finland. Acta Sociologica, 38(4), 299310.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kenworthy, L. (2009). The effect of public opinion on social policy generosity. Socio-Economic Review, 7(4), 727740.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kenworthy, L. (2011). Progress for the poor. Oxford, UK: Oxford University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Korpi, W. (1980). Social policy and distributional conflict in the capitalist democracies. A preliminary comparative framework. West European Politics, 3(3), 296316.10.1080/01402388008424288CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Korpi, W., & Palme, J. (1998). The paradox of redistribution and strategies of equality: Welfare state institutions, inequality, and poverty in the western countries. American Sociological Review, 63(5), 661689.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kumlin, S., & Stadelmann-Steffen, I. (2014). How welfare states shape the democratic public: Policy feedback, participation, voting and attitudes. Cheltenham, UK: Edward Elgar.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Laenen, T. (2018). Do institutions matter? The interplay between income benefit design, popular perceptions, and the social legitimacy of targeted welfare. Journal of European Social Policy, 28(1), 417.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Larsen, C. A. (2006). The institutional logic of welfare attitudes: How welfare regimes influence public support. Comparative Political Studies, 41(2), 145168.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Linos, K., & West, M. (2003). Self-interest, social beliefs, and attitudes to redistribution: Re-addressing the issue of cross-national variation. European Sociological Review, 19(4), 393409.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Marier, P., & Skinner, S. (2008) Orienting the public-private mix of pensions. In: Béland, D., Gran, B. (Eds.) Public and Private Social Policy. Palgrave Macmillan, London. https://doi.org/10.1057/9780230228771_3 Google Scholar
Marshall, T. H. (1950). Citizenship and social class. Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Marx, I., Salanauskaite, L., & Verbist, G. (2013). The paradox of redistribution revisited: And that it may rest in peace? IZA Discussion Paper, 7414(7414), 150. Retrieved from http://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=2276306 Google Scholar
Marx, I., Salanauskaite, L., & Verbist, G. (2016). For the poor, but not only the poor: On optimal pro-poorness in redistributive policies. Social Forces, 95(1), 124.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Myles, J. (2006). Comment on Brooks and Manza, ASR, June 2006 : Welfare states and public opinion. American Sociological Review, 71(3), 495498.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Nelson, K. (2004). Mechanisms of poverty alleviation: Anti-poverty effects of non-means-tested and means-tested benefits in five welfare states. Journal of European Social Policy, 14(4), 371390.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Nelson, K. (2007). Universalism versus targeting: The vulnerability of social insurance and means-tested minimum income protection in 18 countries, 1990–2002. International Social Security Review, 60(1), 3358.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Noël, A., & Thérien, J-P (2002). Public opinion and global justice. Comparative Political Studies, 35(6), 631656. doi:10.1177/0010414002035006001.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Page, B., & Shapiro, R. (1983). Effects of public opinion on policy. The American Political Science Review, 77(1), 175190.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Papadakis, E., & Bean, C. (1993). Popular support for the welfare state: A comparison between institutional regimes. Journal of Public Policy, 13(3), 227254.10.1017/S0143814X00001057CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Pettersen, P. A. (2001). Welfare state legitimacy: Ranking, rating, paying: The popularity and support for Norwegian welfare programmes in the mid 1990s. Scandinavian Political Studies, 24(1), 2749.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Pierson, P. (1994). Dismantling the welfare state? Reagan, Thatcher and the politics of retrenchment. Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press.10.1017/CBO9780511805288CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Pierson, P. (2001). The new politics of the welfare state. (Pierson, P., Ed.). Oxford, UK: Open University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Roosma, F., van Oorschot, W., & Gelissen, J. (2014). The weakest link in welfare state legitimacy: European perceptions of moral and administrative failure in the targeting of social benefits. International Journal of Comparative Sociology, 55(6), 489508.10.1177/0020715214565932CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rothstein, B. (1998). Just institutions matter: The moral and political logic of the universal welfare state. Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Schoukens, P. (2016). The EU monitoring of social security systems: In search of the hidden European social model. In Inaugural address. Tilburg: Tilburg University 156.Google Scholar
Sen, A. (1995). The political economy of targeting. In Van de Walle, D., & Nead, K. (Eds.), Public spending and the poor: Theory and evidence. Baltimore, MD: Johns Hopkins University Press.Google Scholar
Skocpol, T. (1991). Targeting within universalism: Politically viable policies to combat poverty in the United States. In Jencks, C, & Peterson, P. (Eds.), The urban underclass (pp. 411436). Washington, DC: Brookings Institution.Google Scholar
Svallfors, S. (1997). Worlds of welfare and attitudes to redistribution: A comparison of eight western nations. European Sociological Review, 13(3), 283304.10.1093/oxfordjournals.esr.a018219CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Svallfors, S. (2003). Welfare regimes and welfare opinions: A comparison of eight western countries. In: Vogel, J (Ed.) European welfare production: Institutional configuration and distributional outcomes , pp. 171196. Dordrecht: Springer.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Svallfors, S. (2004). Class, attitudes and the welfare state: Sweden in comparative perspective. Social Policy and Administration, 38(2), 119138.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Svallfors, S. (Ed.). (2012). Contested welfare states. Welfare attitudes in Europe and beyond. Stanford: Stanford University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Svallfors, S. (2013). Government quality, egalitarianism, and attitudes to taxes and social spending: A European comparison. European Political Science Review, 5(3), 363380.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Tawney, R. H. (1952). Equality. London, UK: George Allen and Unwin.Google Scholar
Taylor-Gooby, P. (2001). Sustaining state welfare in hard times: Who will foot the bill? Journal of European Social Policy, 11(2), 133147.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Taylor-Gooby, P., Leruth, B., & Chung, H. (Eds.). (2017). After austerity. Welfare state transformation in Europe after the great recession. Oxford, UK: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Titmuss, R. M. (1968). Commitment to welfare. London, UK: Allen and Unwin.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Van Lancker, W., & Van Mechelen, N. (2015). Universalism under siege? Exploring the association between targeting, child benefits and child poverty across 26 countries. Social Science Research, 50, 6075.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
van Oorschot, W. (2006). Making the difference in social Europe: Deservingness perceptions among citizens of European welfare states. Journal of European Social Policy, 16(1), 2342.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Van Oorschot, W., & Meuleman, B. (2014). Popular deservingness of the unemployed in the context of welfare state policies, economic conditions and cultural climate. In Kumlin, S., & Stadelmann-Steffen, I. (Eds.), How welfare states shape the Democratic Public: Policy feedback, participation, voting, and attitudes (pp. 244268). Cheltenham, UK: Edward Elgar.Google Scholar
van Oorschot, W., & Roosma, F. (2017). The social legitimacy of targeted welfare and welfare deservingness. In van Oorschot, W., Roosma, F., Meuleman, B., & Reeskens, T. (Eds.), The social legitimacy of targeted welfare: Attitudes to welfare deservingness (pp. 336). Cheltenham, UK: Edward Elgar.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
van Parijs, P., & Vanderborght, Y. (2017). Basic income: A radical proposal for a free society and a Sane economy. Harvard, MA: Harvard University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wendt, C., Mischke, M., & Pfeifer, M. (2011). Welfare states and public opinion. Perceptions of healthcare systems, family policy and benefits for the unemployed and poor in Europe. Cheltenham, UK: Edward Elgar Publishing.Google Scholar
Whiteford, P. (2008). How much redistribution do governments achieve? The role of cash transfers and household taxes. In OECD (Ed.), Growing unequal?. Paris: OECD.Google Scholar
Figure 0

Figure 1. The causal assumptions in K&P’s paradox of redistribution.