In recent years increasing attention has been paid to formal institutions in authoritarian regimes such as elections and legislatures. From the conventional wisdom of seeing them as mere democratic facades, scholarship has moved to identify a number of ways in which legislatures, in particular, can prolong authoritarian rule (Gandhi and Przeworski Reference Gandhi and Przeworski2007). Dictators can avoid being overthrown, for instance, by coopting regime opponents into assemblies (Gandhi Reference Gandhi2008). Legislatures can also preempt coups from the dictator's inner circle by providing a credible power-sharing mechanism among elites (Svolik Reference Svolik2012). Both mechanisms can either work through making policy concessions or by distributing rents and material perks (Gandhi Reference Gandhi2008; Lust-Okar Reference Lust-Okar2006; Magaloni Reference Magaloni2006; Blaydes Reference Blaydes2011).
Most of the literature on authoritarian legislatures has focused on dictators’ reasons for establishing them in the first place, yet the roles and actions of individual delegates are similarly important (Art Reference Art2012). In fact, members of assemblies in authoritarian regimes can show remarkable levels of commitment and passion for participating in their activities as for instance delegates of China's National People's Congress and People's Political Consultative Conference do (Truex Reference Truex2016; Chen Reference Chen2019). To be sure, delegates also exhibit remarkable differences in their levels of activity (Krol Reference Krol2020; Malesky and Schuler Reference Malesky and Schuler2010). In Russia, for instance, some delegates are very active in amending bills (e.g., Noble Reference Noble2020) but at the same time, the Russian leadership had to reform internal rules of the State Duma to persuade other members to even fulfill minor tasks (Szakonyi Reference Szakonyi2017). This elicits the question of which elites are active and engage in policy-related efforts in authoritarian regimes, and which ones are not.
Prior research on delegates in authoritarian assemblies has highlighted that financial rewards can explain why someone would want to become a member of parliament but does not go into detail in explaining delegates’ activity once they are part of the legislature (Blaydes Reference Blaydes2011; Truex Reference Truex2014). Other research, inspired by cooptation theory, more explicitly focuses on the question of delegates’ activity (Desposato Reference Desposato2001; Malesky and Schuler Reference Malesky and Schuler2010; Krol Reference Krol2020; Simison Reference Simison2020). These studies often primarily focus on electoral cooptation mechanisms and, as a result, can relatively clearly distinguish between regime insiders and outsiders. In “closed regimes” (Diamond Reference Diamond2002), however, recent research has dismissed cooptation theory as an explanation for delegates’ work due to the absence of an opposition (e.g., Truex Reference Truex2016; Lü, Liu, and Li Reference Lü, Liu and Li2020; Schuler Reference Schuler2021). Nevertheless, regimes such as China and Vietnam have also successfully coopted other elites such as private entrepreneurs (e.g., Dickson Reference Dickson2003; Hou Reference Hou2019) and thus, the theory may also be valuable in regard to authoritarian assemblies.
Adopting a delegate-centered perspective, this article explores why some delegates actively participate in authoritarian assemblies and how we can explain the variance in delegates’ behavior. I argue that delegates’ activity can be explained by a combination of both cooptation theory and an understanding of delegates’ position within the authoritarian regime and hierarchy. The results highlight that core elites—powerful, agenda-setting delegates with more direct means of influencing policymaking—will forego assemblies and advance their interests through other channels such as party institutions. In contrast, peripheral elites—delegates that lack other institutional means of access to decision-makers—have to voice their demands in an authoritarian assembly. I particularly highlight these results regarding delegates’ occupational backgrounds, but they also apply to their social backgrounds, including aspects such as gender, ethnicity, and whether or not they are members of the governing party.
I place this argument in the context of China and, in particular, the provincial People's Political Consultative Conferences (PPCC/sheng zheng xie),Footnote 1 in which the main task of delegates is to submit policy proposals to the government. Previous analyses of the PPCCs have either analyzed only the proposals of a certain group (Chen Reference Chen2015; Huang and Chen Reference Huang and Chen2019) or related to a certain issue (Lü, Liu, and Li Reference Lü, Liu and Li2020). Therefore, this article is the first substantial analysis of the dynamics of proposal-writing. In this background, the results firstly show significant differences between government officials. Provincial government officials are the most powerful actors on this level and can make use of more direct channels to influence government actions. In contrast, cadres working on lower levels are the most active delegates and channel local knowledge and demands into the official processes. Given their lack of other channels to transmit demands vertically, they have to utilize an authoritarian assembly to appeal to the provincial government and request resources.
Secondly, I find that some coopted groups such as academics and professionals are also among the most active delegates in providing recommendations to the government. Since they tend to be sidelined in other decision-making processes, for both groups these assemblies are the only way of airing demands. Academics can channel their research findings and academic expertise into official policy-making processes through this mechanism whereas professionals know working conditions and environment “on the ground” and can relay their professional expertise. The results also suggest that private entrepreneurs tend to participate less in formal institutions despite also lacking direct access to decision-making. This may be explained by the fact that private entrepreneurs in particular benefit from material rewards of becoming members of the institution and thus, abstain from voicing too much criticism towards the government.
The main contributions of this article to the literature on comparative authoritarianism are twofold. First, it contributes to the increasing understanding that even in dictatorships many actors have different and even conflicting interests (e.g., Kim and Sudduth Reference Kim and Sudduth2021). In the case of this article, for instance, government officials have different motives depending on the administrative level they work on. Thus, the findings of this article highlight the need to disaggregate important groups of actors in authoritarian regimes more finely to illustrate their diverging interests. In addition, doing so not only sheds light on their motivations but also helps in understanding the different channels of action available to them. This article, for example, illustrates how the career backgrounds make it necessary for some actors to engage in assembly work while others remain inactive in this context.
Secondly, by explicitly differentiating between groups of actors this article further clarifies important functions fulfilled by institutions in authoritarian regimes. For one, this study shows that cooptation cannot only be a strategy of incorporating regime outsiders into policymaking (Gandhi and Przeworski Reference Gandhi and Przeworski2006; Gandhi Reference Gandhi2008; Reuter and Robertson Reference Reuter and Robertson2015) but that a closed regime like China also uses it to keep peripheral elites engaged in official institutions. This is similarly of vital importance to an authoritarian regime as it can prevent insiders from turning into or reaching out to outsiders. On the other hand, it places limits on views that emphasize institutions’ role in power-sharing mechanisms (e.g., Svolik Reference Svolik2012; also see Li Reference Li2020). The findings of this study suggest that it is precisely high-ranking elites who do not publicly declare their preferences but instead bargain over policies in smaller circles.
Core elites, peripheral elites, and activity in authoritarian assemblies
In recent years, research has singled out nominally democratic institutions as cornerstones of dictatorships and highlighted the mechanisms through which they can prolong authoritarian rule (Magaloni Reference Magaloni2006; Gandhi Reference Gandhi2008; Svolik Reference Svolik2012). These approaches have highlighted that authoritarian institutions can help to coopt opposition forces and incorporate them into policy-making processes (Gandhi Reference Gandhi2008; Gandhi and Przeworski Reference Gandhi and Przeworski2007; Reuter and Robertson Reference Reuter and Robertson2015), facilitate power-sharing among the authoritarian elite (Svolik Reference Svolik2012; Gehlbach and Keefer Reference Gehlbach and Keefer2011), and collect information about elites’ and citizens’ preferences (Truex Reference Truex2016; Manion Reference Manion2015; Ong Reference Ong2015). Yet, the individual delegates within authoritarian assemblies equally deserve attention.
In order to explain delegates’ activity in authoritarian assemblies, scholars followed the theoretical premise of cooptation theory (Desposato Reference Desposato2001; Malesky and Schuler Reference Malesky and Schuler2010; Simison Reference Simison2020). Although it is primarily concerned with why dictators would establish institutions in the first place, cooptation theory also offers insights on how delegates might behave in assemblies. The establishment of legislatures is primarily aimed at opposition forces that previously had no opportunity to voice their demands (Gandhi and Przeworski Reference Gandhi and Przeworski2006; Gandhi Reference Gandhi2008). Thus, in assemblies that function as a forum for policymaking with eventual policy concessions, regime outsiders can be expected to make more use of the institutional mechanisms (Malesky and Schuler Reference Malesky and Schuler2010). Regime insiders, however, do not need the additional opportunities of assemblies since they are key decision-makers or have closer links with them to begin with. Prior studies that followed the cooptation approach focused often primarily on electoral cooptation mechanisms (Desposato Reference Desposato2001; Malesky and Schuler Reference Malesky and Schuler2010; Simison Reference Simison2020).
‘Closed regimes’ (Diamond Reference Diamond2002), however, are not open to any form of electoral competition and do not allow regime outsiders in their legislatures. Thus, recent research has dismissed cooptation theory as plausible explanation for delegates’ activism entirely (e.g., Truex Reference Truex2016, Lü, Liu, and Li Reference Lü, Liu and Li2020; Schuler Reference Schuler2021). Nevertheless, the distinction between regime insiders and outsiders are not always clear-cut there either. In fact, research in other areas has long highlighted how a wide range of actors can be coopted through mechanisms other than elections. Prominent cases include private entrepreneurs (Dickson Reference Dickson2003; Huang and Chen Reference Huang and Chen2019), religious actors (Payne Reference Payne2010), the media (Wiebrecht Reference Wiebrecht2018), lawyers (Liu and Stern Reference Liu and Stern2020), and civil society groups (Mattingly Reference Mattingly2019). Thus, cooptation theory may hold merit even in the absence of a formal opposition.
An alternative perspective sees institutions such as assemblies not as mechanisms for cooptation but rather as arenas for competition between different government agencies for state resources (Lust-Okar Reference Lust-Okar2006). Lü, Liu, and Li (Reference Lü, Liu and Li2020) for instance put forward the perspective that government departments actively encourage deputies in China's legislatures to submit proposals and build ‘policy coalitions.’ In consequence, they see intra-institutional processes as characterized by bureaucratic struggles over influence in policymaking rather than by conflicts between regime insiders and outsiders (Noble Reference Noble2020). This is an important perspective to understand dynamics in authoritarian assemblies, but it neglects the strict hierarchy of authoritarian regimes and legislatures (Schuler Reference Schuler2021). As some actors start from a much more powerful position to influence policymaking than others, not all of them need to compete for influence in legislatures equally (Wu Reference Wu2020).
In an effort to synthesize the aforementioned competing perspectives, I propose to further differentiate actors in authoritarian institutions. In contrast to aggregating delegates into categories of regime insiders and outsiders, I argue that it is primarily their position in the authoritarian regime and hierarchy that predicts their levels of activity in an authoritarian assembly. While even in authoritarian regimes actors have many competing and divergent preferences (Williamson and Magaloni Reference Williamson and Magaloni2020; Kim and Sudduth Reference Kim and Sudduth2021), their ability to ultimately influence policymaking varies. Just as in democracies (Cox and McCubbins Reference Cox and McCubbins2005; Gailmard and Jenkins Reference Gailmard and Jenkins2007), some actors in authoritarian regimes are more powerful than others regarding policymaking and agenda-setting and can bypass legislative bargaining more easily (Wu Reference Wu2020; Schuler Reference Schuler2021). They may prefer to advance their interests either through alternative decision-making organs such as party institutions (Svolik Reference Svolik2012; Gehlbach and Keefer Reference Gehlbach and Keefer2011; Malesky, Abrami, and Zheng Reference Malesky, Abrami and Zheng2011) or through informal connections (Jiang and Zhang Reference Jiang and Zhang2020). These agenda-setting elites are what I call core elites.
In contrast, authoritarian assemblies also accommodate several actors that lack any direct institutional access to decision-makers and for whom assemblies are the only formal channel through which they can transmit their demands. I call these actors peripheral elites because they are generally privileged and well-respected in authoritarian politics and society, but they are not ultimate decision-makers. They can be less advantaged in comparison to core elites in terms of their occupational, social, ethnic, or geographical background. They may be comparable to backbenchers in majority parties in democratic regimes as their influence on policymaking is also limited and their chances of success in parliament relatively low (Searing Reference Searing1993; Hasson Reference Hasson2010). In order to voice their preferences to the leaders of the authoritarian regime, they will have to make use of institutions and attempt to influence policymaking in assemblies.
Thus, my argument builds on the abovementioned cooptation approach but generalizes it to dictatorships in which regime insiders and outsiders are not easily identifiable. In addition, it complements the bureaucratic competition approach with an emphasis on the hierarchical structure. This argument can be extended to more competitive assemblies in which opposition forces would fall below peripheral elites in the authoritarian hierarchy. However, this argument comes with two qualifications. For one, as the legislative process may not guarantee them a high chance of success in influencing policymaking, peripheral elites are also susceptible to alternative channels. If they have access to alternative and more direct channels to decision-makers such as informal connections, they will prefer to use them. The second qualification concerns the role of private rents. If delegates are primarily interested in private financial gains rather than influencing policymaking, they will abstain from voicing too much criticism to retain their position (Reuter and Robertson Reference Reuter and Robertson2015).
I will begin by providing some background on the institutions before introducing the empirical strategy.
Background: The People's Political Consultative Conferences (PPCC)
The PPCCs have a long history, as the first institution of this kind was held in 1946 and attended by the Communist Party, the Kuomintang, and other political parties in China at the time. In the immediate aftermath of the Communist victory, the national PPCC was promoted as the main legislative institution, but it was later replaced in that function by the National People's Congress (Chen Reference Chen2015). Consequently, the institution did not possess state power and was relegated to the status of a consultative body. While it did not survive the Cultural Revolution, the political elite of the reform and opening-up period re-discovered the advantages of the system and revitalized the PPCCs from the early 1980s onwards (Yan Reference Yan2011). According to its charter, consultation is the principal function of the PPCCs (Article 3) with “assist[ing] state organs in carrying out structural and institution reform, improving work, raising efficiency, overcoming the practice of formalities for formalities’ sake, bureaucratism, hedonism, and extravagance, and building a clean government” (Article 7) stated as some of the main objectives.
As one of the most inclusive political institutions in China, they are a key element in the party-state's system of coopting important sectors of society (e.g., Yan Reference Yan2011). Prior research has particularly focused on their ability to incorporate influential actors in society into the realm of the state, going as far as calling the institutions “rich people club” (Chen Reference Chen2015; Sagild and Ahlers Reference Sagild and Ahlers2019; Jeffreys Reference Jeffreys2016). While it was primarily concerned with coopting the minor political parties in China in the founding days of the People's Republic (Groot Reference Groot2004), more recently private entrepreneurs have become the center of its cooptation work (e.g., Yan Reference Yan2011; Chen Reference Chen2015; Heberer and Schubert Reference Heberer and Schubert2019; Huang and Chen Reference Huang and Chen2019). For the Chinese regime, the PPCCs with their diverse membership composition deliver welcome images illustrating how inclusive political institutions in China can be. The assemblies also offer a forum for interacting and maintaining patronage relationships with the government and prior research confirms that entrepreneurs benefit from their membership (e.g., Sun, Zhu, and Wu Reference Sun, Zhu and Wu2014).
The mechanisms of selecting PPCC delegates are non-transparent but recommendations from other delegates seem crucial (Sagild and Ahlers Reference Sagild and Ahlers2019). While political loyalty is a prerequisite to be considered as delegate, candidates’ social standing also appears crucial. For private entrepreneurs, for instance, business success and prior philanthropic engagement are key (Sagild Reference Sagild2019). Thus, delegates are generally elites in their respective fields that the regime considers valuable and important to establish formal connections with. Figure 1 highlights the share of the three largest groups of delegates in the two PPCCs selected for this study. These are government officials, academics, and private entrepreneurs that altogether constitute slightly above 70 percent of all delegates. The remaining delegates are professionals, state-owned enterprise executives, government-affiliated organization representatives, and military cadres. Statistics on members’ occupations have largely remained stable over time but can vary across provinces depending on regional characteristics. Province 2 for instance has a higher number of universities which is reflected in the higher share of academics in its PPCC.
Although the institution is lacking formal authority to enact laws it does offer opportunities for delegates to make their voices heard. In addition to attending training sessions and participating in inspections and research tours, the delegates’ most important task is to submit formal policy proposals (ti'an) to which the relevant government departments are required to respond within a set period of time (Chen Reference Chen2019).Footnote 2 The number of proposals has skyrocketed in recent decades (Lü, Liu, and Li Reference Lü, Liu and Li2020) and yet they have not been subject to comprehensive empirical studies. Past research has either focused on the proposals of a particular group, e.g., entrepreneurs (Chen Reference Chen2015), or on proposals centering around an individual issue such as education (Lü, Liu, and Li Reference Lü, Liu and Li2020).
Contrary to prior studies that have focused on the national (Lü, Liu, and Li Reference Lü, Liu and Li2020) and local (Sun, Zhu, and Wu Reference Sun, Zhu and Wu2014) levels, this study will draw on two provincial-level PPCCs for several reasons. First, similar to those on other administrative levels, provincial PPCCs have also been very active in writing proposals and experienced significant growth in activity in past decades.Footnote 3 Second, provinces have become places of active lawmaking in recent decades that are just as “fragmented” (Mertha Reference Mertha2009) as the national level but often more innovative and “progressive.” The central government often learns from provincial policy successes and failures (Xia Reference Xia2008). Delegates on the provincial level may therefore also be more confident in proposing pioneering policies. Third, provinces take a unique position in the Chinese administrative hierarchy in the center of vertical relationships between top-down orders and local demands. As Jaros and Tan (Reference Jaros and Tan2020) highlight, provinces function as “gatekeepers” between the affluent central state and the underprivileged local governments. Fourth, in comparison to the local PPCCs, which are likely to deal with more mundane issues such as a lack of parking spots in the respective city (Chen Reference Chen2015), proposals on the provincial level tend to be more substantive and policy oriented, for instance calling for the establishment of a province-wide traffic accident rescue fund.
Hypotheses
In this section, I lay out the theoretical expectations of PPCC delegates’ behavior in accordance with the argument highlighted above. The focus in this analysis will be on the delegates’ occupational backgrounds as these are most important in determining one's status within the authoritarian regime.
The membership composition of the PPCCs reveals that most delegates are indeed government officials. The view on authoritarian institutions as arenas for bureaucratic competition (Lü, Liu, and Li Reference Lü, Liu and Li2020; Noble Reference Noble2020) suggests that government agencies are competing for influence inside them and that government officials act as their “proxy fighters.” However, I suggest that not all government bodies and officials follow this pattern equally. Provincial government officials are by definition among the most authoritative actors on this level and therefore have alternative channels to influence policies according to their preferences. In particular, the elevated role of party organs for policymaking has been highlighted in prior research (Svolik Reference Svolik2012; Gehlbach and Keefer Reference Gehlbach and Keefer2011; Malesky, Abrami, and Zheng Reference Malesky, Abrami and Zheng2011). Consequently, in their position as core elites, they will invest fewer resources and effort in engaging in an assembly.
On the other hand, local government officials (i.e., prefecture or county-level) are peripheral for provincial-level decision-making processes. There are no institutionalized channels through which local governments can advance their interests vis-à-vis provincial actors other than PPCCs and People's Congresses (Manion Reference Manion2014). Missing alternative promising channels, local government officials will feel compelled to make use of the institutions. However, not only do local governments lack alternative channels to appeal to higher-level governments, but they also often compete for resources (Lü and Landry Reference Lü and Landry2014; Zhu Reference Zhu2014). Thus, local governments and their “proxy fighters” will appeal to provincial institutions more actively because the latter “have considerable control over the localities’ … economic and institutional resources” (Jaros and Tan Reference Jaros and Tan2020, 81). Thus, particularly on the provincial level, local government officials can be seen as peripheral elites.
The efforts to convince the provincial government of the need for additional resources are also visible in many submitted proposals. Local government officials often draw attention to local issues. A municipal department head in a prefecture-level city in Province 2, for instance, appealed to the provincial government to support the city in establishing copper futures delivery warehouses in 2018. In 2005 a municipal department head in a county-level city in Province 1 similarly urged the provincial authorities to open a wind power plant there as soon as possible. A number of additional examples from Province 2 in 2005 are provided in Table 12 in the Appendix. Thus, bureaucratic competition in institutions is to be expected primarily in the form of parochialism, that is, among local governments competing for resources allocated by the provincial government (Manion Reference Manion2014). However, the same cannot be expected for provincial-level agencies that can be classified as core elites.
Thus, Hypotheses 1a and 1b target the relationship between government officials on different levels and their activity in the PPCCs:
H1a: Provincial-level government officials are less active in submitting proposals through PPCCs compared to other delegates.
H1b: Local government officials (i.e., prefecture and county-level) are more active in submitting proposals through PPCCs compared to other delegates.
A second large group of delegates in the PPCCs is that of academics and professionals. Academics in particular, often function as policy entrepreneurs, irrespective of political regimes, characterized by their high degree of social acuity (Bakir and Jarvis Reference Bakir and Jarvis2017). On the other hand, in authoritarian regimes, they often lack institutionalized channels through which they can communicate their research and participate in the policymaking processes (Kaczmarska Reference Kaczmarska2019). This has also been recognized as an issue in China with many academics missing access to the governments’ administrative channels (Zhu Reference Zhu2016). With the PPCCs as one of few institutionalized mechanisms in which they can offer recommendations, academics are likely to be more active than other groups of delegates in the institution.
The institution provides academics, whether they are natural or social scientists, with the chance to relate their research to questions of governance. The proposals submitted to the PPCCs highlight that many of them follow precisely this approach. An economics professor from Province 2 for instance, in line with his research interests, proposed to improve the single window of international trade and to promote the integrated development of customs clearance in the region in 2020. In another case, familiar with the local infrastructure, a professor of sports sciences in Province 1 recommended the provincial government to accelerate the construction of additional sports facilities in the province in 2008. These examples are typical of the nature of academic engagement in the PPCCs.
The same can be said of professionals such as lawyers and medical professionals, who come across societal issues daily but do not have alternative institutionalized channels to inform the government. Professionals can often relay experiences from their work and submit proposals either directly related to their occupation or to issues they are aware of through their engagement with and in society. For instance, in 2020 a lawyer-delegate formulated recommendations regarding the provincial “Regulations on the Protection of Intellectual Property Rights” that also fall into his professional expertise. In Province 1, a medical doctor authored the “Suggestions on Strengthening Hospital Policing Management and Protecting the Personal Safety of Medical Staff” and submitted them in 2014. A variety of exemplary proposals by academics as well as professionals from Province 1 in 2008 are included in Table 11 in the Appendix. Based on these proposals, this article's second hypothesis tests whether academics and professionals are in fact more active than other delegates:
H2: Academics, as well as professionals, are more active in submitting proposals through PPCCs compared to other delegates. Footnote 4
A third notable group of delegates in PPCCs but also authoritarian institutions more broadly are private entrepreneurs as envoys of the economic sector. In fact, based on interviews conducted by other scholars, they are often said to be particularly active in authoritarian institutions (e.g., Hou Reference Hou2019; Chen Reference Chen2015). Private entrepreneurs also lack alternative formal channels in which they could voice their policy preferences, and thus, in line with the argument of this article, one might expect them to be very active. However, it appears that for private entrepreneurs, rather than through policy concessions, cooptation is primarily advanced through material rewards. In many cases, actors have been coopted primarily through financial remunerations or closer access to resources (Lust-Okar Reference Lust-Okar2006; Blaydes Reference Blaydes2011). In the Chinese context, these advantages have also been shown impressively in particular for private entrepreneurs (Sun, Zhu, and Wu Reference Sun, Zhu and Wu2014; Truex Reference Truex2014).
Yet, this material approach of cooptation may instead lead to the opposite outcome of stifling incentives for active participation in authoritarian institutions. Previous research has shown that attracting overt attention is not helpful for actors in public positions in authoritarian regimes (e.g., Gueorguiev and Schuler Reference Gueorguiev and Schuler2016). Recent high-profile cases such as Jack Ma, Xiao Jianhua, Ye Jianming, and Wu Xiaohui illustrate that voicing political concerns or getting involved in factional politics is still a risky and dangerous undertaking for private entrepreneurs in China. Since membership in the institution often leads to better-protected property rights (Hou Reference Hou2019), entrepreneurs may want to refrain from attracting attention by overly criticizing the regime. Instead, it is conceivable that private entrepreneurs can be ‘bought off’ through such benefits in order to abstain from voicing criticism (Lust-Okar Reference Lust-Okar2006; Reuter and Robertson Reference Reuter and Robertson2015; Blaydes Reference Blaydes2011). While other delegates also benefit from their membership in an authoritarian institution, these advantages tend to be more important for private entrepreneurs’ careers and businesses. Hypothesis 3 will test private entrepreneurs’ levels of participation.
H3: Private entrepreneurs are less active in submitting proposals through PPCCs compared to other delegates.
Empirical Strategy
In order to analyze the individual levels of activity, this article utilizes an original dataset of proposals submitted to two PPCCs in China from 2005 to 2020.Footnote 5 While many provinces and municipalities make a selection of proposals available, the provinces analyzed here are the only ones to publish all proposals of this period online and visible to the public.Footnote 6 This article will be the first substantial analysis on the dynamics on the provincial level that despite strong centralization efforts under Xi Jinping continues to play an important role (Jaros and Tan Reference Jaros and Tan2020). The unit of analysis used in this article is the delegate-year for which the dataset includes a total of 14,236 observations. Table 4 in the Appendix highlights that both provinces are close to the mean and median values of all Chinese provinces for a variety of indicators. The only exception is that Province 1 is smaller in size than the average province and has a smaller population.
The analyses will use a count variable of how many proposals each delegate has submitted to every annual meeting as dependent variable taken from the PPCCs’ online platforms. Included in the analysis are all proposals written by individual delegates, either single-authored or jointly signed whereas group proposals for instance in the name of the minor parties and mass organizations have been excluded. The independent variables are based on the individual biographies of the delegates. The name lists of the delegates are taken from the PPCC websites. Further biographical information has been collected from Baidu Encyclopedia that has also been used for other studies (Jiang Reference Jiang2018; Truex Reference Truex2014) and university and company websites. As outlined above, the delegates’ occupations are the main variables of interest since they carry theoretical significance. Additional personal details such as delegates’ gender, education level, ethnicity, birthplace, party membership, and whether they are part of the institutional leadershipFootnote 7 function as control variables.
Prior research especially from democratic parliaments showed that some of these social characteristics are also important in predicting legislative activity. Female and ethnic minority legislators for instance tend to be more active as they are typically in an institutionally disadvantaged position (Akirav Reference Akirav2018; Salmond Reference Salmond2006; Becker and Saalfeld Reference Becker, Saalfeld, Doring and Hallerberg2004; Wängnerud Reference Wängnerud2009). In addition, experience within the institution has been highlighted as an important factor in parliaments since it allows MPs to understand institutional procedures better (Mayhew Reference Mayhew2000; Katz Reference Katz1999). The models in this article illustrate experience as a dichotomous variable of whether a delegate has been a member of the PPCC in a previous five-year session. The descriptive data (pre-and post-imputation) are available in the Appendix.
Delegates in provincial-level PPCCs are not particularly prominent public figures which is why it is difficult to collect some of their biographies. While records on government officials are relatively accessible and complete, personal details such as age and education are often unidentifiable for non-Party members. Therefore, to address the problem of missing data a data imputation approach has been applied in this study (King et al. Reference King, Honaker, Joseph and Scheve2001). The results presented here are based on the mean values of 35 imputation runs on the original dataset. More details on how many observations are missing and were imputed are provided in the Appendix (Table 3). In this study, multiple imputation is particularly helpful since the auxiliary variables are mainly affected by missingness but not the variables of main interest (Arel-Bundock and Pelc Reference Arel-Bundock and Pelc2018). The empirical analysis has been conducted with a negative binomial regression (NBREG) model specification. Since the high number of delegates with zero submitted proposals leads to an over-dispersion in the data, NBREG is more appropriate in this case than the more commonly used Poisson models (Cameron and Trivedi Reference Cameron and Trivedi1998).
Results
Descriptive statistics on proposal-writing reveal that, in fact, most delegates do not submit a single proposal in a given year. While 26 and 11 percent of delegates submit one and two proposals respectively, delegates that submit more than that are rare. Nevertheless, there are significant differences across occupational groups, as Figure 2 below illustrates. These statistics hint at the validity of the aforementioned hypotheses. While among provincial government officials more than 70 percent of delegates do not submit a single proposal, the rates of non-submission are lower for local government officials and especially for academics and professionals. Further evidence for this impression is provided by the regression analyses below.
Table 1 highlights the baseline results in six different models. Model 1 disaggregates government officials into local and provincial-level position holders and Model 2 illustrates the coefficients of academics and professionals. Model 3 focuses on entrepreneurs as independent variables in its analysis. Models 4–6 each include all independent variables with the difference that Model 5 includes year-fixed effects and Model 6 adds province-fixed effects. The results from the baseline models largely confirm the theoretical expectations. First, there are significant differences between government officials on different administrative levels. Provincial government officials are significantly less likely to submit proposals to the PPCCs in all models. In contrast, local government officials submit around 20 percent more proposals than other delegates. The coefficients of both groups also remain highly significant in all analyses.
Note: † p < 0.1, *p < 0.05, **p < 0.01, ***p < 0.001, Standard errors in parentheses.
Secondly, academics and professionals are also more active in writing proposals than other delegates. Model 4 for instance highlights that both groups write about 11 and 16 percent more proposals than their delegate colleagues. Their coefficients remain significant throughout the models except for that of academic delegates in Model 6. It appears that the effect for academics is not equally strong across the two provinces which, however, cannot be said about professionals. In contrast, entrepreneurs are significantly less likely to participate actively with recommendations in the PPCCs. They tend to submit up to 17 percent fewer proposals than other delegates and this coefficient remains significant in all models except Model 6.
In addition to the focus on occupations, the empirical analysis also highlights how other personal characteristics shape delegates’ levels of activity. The coefficients for party membership are the strongest predictors of activity, namely that CCP party members submit significantly fewer proposals than non-CCP party members. The same applies to the delegates that are members of the institutional leadership. Female delegates are significantly and substantially more active than their male counterparts and so are delegates who have had prior experience in the institution. Delegates’ higher levels of education do not lead them to submit more proposals but instead stifle their activity in some models even significantly. As expected, delegates of ethnic minorities tend to be more active when compared to majority Han Chinese delegates. Finally, the local connection of delegates to their provinces only appears to explain their activity in one province, as its coefficient in Model 6 is not statistically significant.
I have also conducted several robustness tests in order to corroborate the results of the above analyses. First, I have run the same analyses with the non-imputed dataset. Those models confirm the results presented here (Table 5 in Appendix). Secondly, a few delegates stand out because of their high number of proposals submitted reaching a maximum of 30. Thus, I have excluded outliers with more than 20, 15, and 10 proposals in any given year in separate analyses. The results remain largely the same (see Tables 6–8 in Appendix). As a further robustness test, I have also removed delegates that are not based in the two respective provinces. These are mainly from Hong Kong and Macau and the results of this analysis can be found in Table 9 in the Appendix.
In order to assess the representativeness of the results from two Chinese provinces, this study has conducted additional robustness tests with (limited) data from a third province. In light of Chinese governments’ increased transparency, a rich coastal province (Province 3) has also recently started to publish the entirety of the submitted proposals online. This data adds further geographical variation to the sample of the provinces used in this study and is therefore useful in complementing the baseline results despite the limited temporal horizon in which data is accessible (2019–2021). The separate results from Province 3 are shown in Tables 10 (imputed) and 11 (not imputed) in the Appendix. They add further support to the baseline results and show very similar mechanisms. Local government officials and professionals are also the most active delegates in this province while provincial government officials and entrepreneurs tend to submit fewer proposals than other delegates. The baseline results also remain largely unchanged when adding data from Province 3 into the baseline analyses (Tables 12 and 13 in Appendix). Thus, while all provinces show some variations as, for instance, academics in Province 3 are less active than their colleagues in Provinces 1 and 2, the general theoretical arguments apply across provincial borders.
A competing perspective could see parochial interests at the center of activity not only for local government officials but for all delegates. Academics, professionals, entrepreneurs, and other delegates in the same municipality may notice the same local issues and report them to the higher level. To investigate such a potential mechanism, I have also coded the locations of the delegates’ workplaces. In this case, one would expect delegates from certain localities to be more active than delegates based in other cities. However, the results from location-fixed effects do not show significant differences in delegate behavior across localities (Table 10 in Appendix). Indeed, only local government officials appear to be more active in highlighting issues particular to their constituencies. Quantitative evidence supports the abovementioned examples of their parochial activism as Table 3 below shows. A random sample of 6,620 individually submitted proposals from both provinces have been examined and coded in regard to whether the issue that delegates present is one that is specific to a local context (municipal, county, or village-level) or relevant for the entire province. Relevant examples of the former can be found in Table 12 in the Appendix. More than one third of local government officials’ proposals deal with local issues whereas local issues only amount to 12 to 19 percent of other delegates’ proposals.
Data from: Compiled by author
The baseline results above thus confirm the argument that primarily peripheral elites, i.e., actors who lack alternative institutional channels to voice their demands, are active in institutions. For instance, government officials do not act as a uniform group of delegates but exhibit different levels of activity with local government officials being the most active group. I provide further support to this line of argument by underlining the importance of informal connections for delegates. As policy changes are far from guaranteed for peripheral elites in any authoritarian assembly, they may opt to use informal institutions to influence decision-making provided they have such access. The importance of informal institutions and patronage has previously been highlighted in the Chinese context especially within the government and party apparatus (Jiang Reference Jiang2018).
I highlight that preferred alternative channels for influencing policymaking are not necessarily limited to formal mechanisms but can also exist in the form of informal connections. Thus, this article analyzes the most active group of delegates, namely that of local government officials, and tests whether those who have informal channels are also more likely to forego using the formal institutions. From the delegates’ biographies, it can be determined whether local government officials have prior experience working in provincial-level government agencies. With this experience, it can be assumed that these delegates are closer to the upper echelons of decision-making on the provincial level and have informal connections they can make use of. Shared workplaces, among others, have long been used as indicators of informal connections in China (e.g., Ma Reference Ma2016).
Figure 3 illustrates the results from the analysis on local government officials. The left subgraph shows the model with year-fixed effects while the subgraph on the right also adds province-fixed effects to the analysis. The results do not vary substantially between the graphs, but both highlight the strong and significant effect that prior work experience on the provincial level has on the activity of local government officials. In both models, those who have had posts in provincial government agencies are submitting about 50 percent fewer proposals than those who have not. Importantly, both groups of local government officials show similar values for their mean and median age as well as tenure in their current position. Thus, we can rule out the possibility that only younger local government officials appeal to the provincial government in their hope to receive investments, generate economic growth, and finally get promoted. These results confirm the argument of this article that delegates who are not able to voice their preferences through alternative channels, including through informal connections, are more likely to actively engage in assemblies.
Discussion and Conclusion
Following the “fragmented authoritarianism” model (Lieberthal and Oksenberg Reference Lieberthal and Oksenberg1988; Lieberthal and Lampton Reference Lieberthal and Lampton1996) there are many different actors who choose a variety of institutional and non-institutional channels attempting to influence policymaking even in closed authoritarian regimes. As the first substantial analysis of delegate activity in two PPCCs in China, this article underscores this idea by highlighting which delegates will attempt to advance their interests through formal institutions. The results show that it is predominantly peripheral elites, as opposed to core elites, who actively engage in institutions. For the former, institutions are often the only channel through which they can engage with decision-makers, while the latter make decisions in other settings such as party organs (Svolik Reference Svolik2012; Gehlbach and Keefer Reference Gehlbach and Keefer2011; Malesky, Abrami, and Zheng Reference Malesky, Abrami and Zheng2011).
Thus, instead of dismissing cooptation theory in closed authoritarian regimes, this article shows that it has some merit even in the absence of an opposition. Nevertheless, even government officials display important differences depending on their ranks, and delegates’ positions in the authoritarian hierarchy thus also needs to be included in a theory of delegate activity. Despite this article's primary focus on the occupational background of delegates, the argument also extends to other aspects. Social characteristics such as gender or ethnicity, for instance, often hint at less privileged positions.
While this study has focused particularly on the consultative institutions of the PPCCs, the findings also resonate with previous research from other contexts that signaled that the distinction between regime insiders and outsiders is not the only fault line in authoritarian assemblies. Malesky and Schuler (Reference Malesky and Schuler2010), for example, highlight important differences even between elites of the Communist Party of Vietnam, whereas Manion (Reference Manion2014) and Desposato (Reference Desposato2001) illustrate the importance of parochialism for local rather than central-level elites in China and Brazil. In the case of Taiwan's Legislative Yuan, there were also considerable differences across the ranks of the ruling Kuomintang (Tien and Cheng Reference Tien and Cheng1997).
For the comparative study of authoritarian regimes and institutions, this study has three main implications. First, it highlights the need for disaggregating broader groups of actors that in the interest of parsimony were previously often subsumed under categories such as regime insiders and outsiders or ruling elite (Gandhi Reference Gandhi2008; Svolik Reference Svolik2012). As the results of this study show, even among delegates who would all be considered regime insiders, I find considerable differences in their interests and actions. Thus, in order to understand the political dynamics of authoritarian regimes and institutions better, we need to apply a more fine-grained approach as recent studies on intra-elite bargaining have shown (Kim and Sudduth Reference Kim and Sudduth2021; Noble Reference Noble2020; Lü, Liu, and Li Reference Lü, Liu and Li2020). On the other hand, this also means that institutions may serve the regime in more than just one purpose. They may simultaneously fulfil the function of power-sharing, collecting information and expertise, and coopting regime outsiders, by including delegates from different occupational backgrounds.Footnote 8
Secondly, the findings add to our understanding of cooptation through legislatures. Instead of incorporating opposition parties into decision-making, assemblies in closed authoritarian regimes such as China are designed to keep peripheral elites close. Marginalized elites can potentially turn into challengers or act as challengers’ allies and thus, keeping them engaged in formal institutions is also a matter of regime stability. In traditional China, for instance, Perry notes that “members of the local elite—linked by education and personal friendships to state agents and institutions—played a central role in the development of anti-state protest” (Reference Perry2002, 69). In fact, the involvement of elites (even if only peripheral ones) often tends to add fuel to the flames of protests, leading to the escalation of popular collective action into major concerns for stability maintenance (Slater Reference Slater2009). It is thus of vital importance to keep marginalized elites engaged, as Burawoy and von Holt remark: “Games obscure the conditions of their own playing through the very process of securing participation. Just as one cannot play chess and at the same time question its rules” (Reference Burawoy and von Holdt2012, 189).
Finally, while other studies have primarily focused on institutions’ role in either providing policy concessions (Gandhi and Przeworski Reference Gandhi and Przeworski2006, Reference Gandhi and Przeworski2007; Gandhi Reference Gandhi2008) or material benefits (Truex Reference Truex2014; Blaydes Reference Blaydes2011), I show that institutions can provide diverse cooptation instruments for different actors. Since separate groups of delegates seek different benefits, they demonstrate different behavioral patterns. In this background, the PPCCs are particularly helpful to the regime as they consistently provide peripheral insiders with the incentives to join and opportunities for participation even though the category of peripheral elites also varies and changes. Future research may want to follow this line of argument and empirically establish to what extent policy concessions are in fact provided to peripheral insiders.
Acknowledgments
I would like to thank two research assistants whose names shall remain anonymous but who have provided extremely valuable help in collecting data for this study. In addition, I thank Chen Xi, Pierre Landry, Vivian Zhan Jing, Wang Juan, Zheng Ruoting, Yang Kai, and two anonymous reviewers for helpful comments and suggestions.
Funding Declaration
This research received no specific grant from any funding agency, commercial or not-for profit sectors.
Conflicts of interests
The author declares none.
Supplementary Material
The supplementary material for this article can be found at https://doi.org/10.1017/jea.2022.19