Hostname: page-component-586b7cd67f-gb8f7 Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-11-25T08:21:13.819Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Introduction

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  12 June 2017

Bruno Jérôme*
Affiliation:
University of Paris II
Rights & Permissions [Opens in a new window]

Abstract

Type
Symposium: Forecasting the 2017 German Elections
Copyright
Copyright © American Political Science Association 2017 

In the past 40 years, few papers have focused on voting models of German elections. Certainly, Kirchgässner (Reference Kirchgässner1977; Reference Kirchgässner1991) or Rattinger (Reference Rattinger1991), developed Vote-Popularity (VP) functions predicting the German ruling parties’ performance based on unemployment as a dominant economic variable. Furthemore, Jérôme, Jérôme-Speziari and Lewis-Beck (Reference Jérôme, Jérôme-Speziari and Lewis-Beck2001) explored the possibility of a “yardstick” competition between French and German economic votes.

However, until 2013, only a handful of models attempted to forecast German elections. Using Vote Functions, Jérôme, Jérôme-Speziari and Lewis-Beck (Reference Jérôme, Jérôme-Speziari and Lewis-Beck1998) initially developed forecasting model where the rate of unemployment and the popularity of the FDP were the main predictors.

This seminal model correctly forecasted the CDU/CSU-FDP defeat. Thereafter, the same method has been successfully applied in 2005 and 2009 but failed in 2002 (Jérôme, Jérôme-Speziari and Lewis-Beck, Reference Jérôme, Jérôme-Speziari and Lewis-Beck2002, 2005 and Reference Jérôme, Jérôme-Speziari and Lewis-Beck2009). At last, in 2013 (see PS: Political Science & Politics 46(03)) the authors opted for a SUR (Seemingly Unrelated Regression) model in order to predict both vote shares and suitable coalitions in a context where hinge parties (FDP and Greens) and new parties (AFD) were increasingly key players. Here again, the incumbent’s political and economic accountability (Key Reference Key1966) still plays a major role except for “peripheral” political parties.

On their side, Norpoth and Gschwend (2000; Reference Norpoth and Gschwend2003) built a forecasting model where the desire for one of the main party’s to provide the Chancellor predicts the election result. This model is known as the “Chancellor model” (Norpoth and Gschwend Reference Norpoth and Gschwend2010; Reference Norpoth and Gschwend2013). While Jérôme-Speziari and Lewis-Beck is rather retrospective, Norpoth and Gschwend’s Chancellor model is mainly prospective. With a view to the next elections, the main predictor is the Chancellor support. Additionally, the model includes a second variable giving the partisan attachment and a third one reflecting the incumbent “fatigue,” in other words, the cost of ruling. Such a configuration allows provision of forecasted vote shares and probabilities for each feasible coalition.

In this 2017 mini symposium, we welcome two new teams with alternative methods. Mark Kayser and Arndt Leininger follow the tradition of pooled time series models using disaggregated or regional data (see Rosenstone (Reference Rosenstone1983) and Campbell (Reference Campbell1992) in the US case or Jérôme, Jérôme and Lewis-Beck (Reference Jérôme, Jérôme-Speziari and Lewis-Beck1999) for French legislative elections). Their political economy Länder-based model underlines the relevance of regional political and economic data to predict the partisan structure of the next Bundestag and who could be the next Chancellor.

Lastly, Andreas Graefe presents a combined forecast based on the PollyVote research project initially launched in 2004 (Cuzàn, Armstrong, and Jones Reference Cuzán, Scott Armstrong and Jones2005) to forecast US elections. In the German Case, a first attempt has been made during the 2013 elections. Gathering predictions issued from polls, prediction markets, experts and models, and treating them on average, PollyVote provides vote-share forecasts for each German party.

If German general elections were held in early March, three models out of four predict the CDU/CSU could win despite a significant loss of votes compared with 2013 (see table 1). However, Norpoth and Gschwend are dissonant to the extent that they forecast a 83% chance of winning for a coalition (red-red-green or “Traffic Light”) led by Martin Schulz.

Table 1 Forecast Models in this Symposium

On balance, the Grand Coalition could be reappointed but Angela Merkel seems to be on borrowed time.

References

REFERENCES

Campbell, James E. 1992. “Forecasting the Presidential Vote in the States.” American Journal of Political Science 36 (2): 386407.Google Scholar
Cuzán, Alfred G., Scott Armstrong, J., and Jones, Randall J. Jr.. 2005. “How We Computed the PollyVote.” Foresight: The International Journal of Applied Forecasting 1 (1): 5152.Google Scholar
Graefe, Andreas. 2015. “German Election Forecasting: Comparing and Combining Methods for 2013.” German Politics 24 (2): 195204. doi: 10.1080/09644008.2015.1024240.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gschwend, T. and Norpoth, H. 2000. “Soll und Haben: Die deutsche ählerschaft rechnet mit den Parteien”, ab. S: 389–409 in: Markus Klein, Wolfgang Jagodzinski, Ekkehard Mochmann und Dieter Ohr (Hg.): 50 Jahre Empirische Wahlforschung in Deutschland. Entwicklung, Befunde, Perspektiven, Daten. Wiesbaden: Westdeutscher Verlag.Google Scholar
Jérôme, Bruno, Jérôme-Speziari, Veronique, and Lewis-Beck, Michael S.. 1998. “prévisions politico - économiques et élections législatives allemandes de septembre 1998.” Cheminement du futur, Le Figaro économie, July 10.Google Scholar
Jérôme, Bruno, Jérôme-Speziari, Veronique, and Lewis-Beck, Michael S.. 1999. “Polls fail in France, forecasts of the 1997 Legislative election.” International Journal of Forecasting 15 (2): 163–74.Google Scholar
Jérôme, Bruno, Jérôme-Speziari, Veronique, and Lewis-Beck, Michael S.. 2001. “Evaluation économique et vote en France et en Allemagne.” l’Opinion européenne 2001, Presses de sciences Po., avril, p. 101122.Google Scholar
Jérôme, Bruno, Jérôme-Speziari, Veronique, and Lewis-Beck, Michael S.. 2002. “Pourquoi Stoiber peut (encore) gagner. ” Le Figaro, September 18, p.17.Google Scholar
Jérôme, Bruno, Jérôme-Speziari, Veronique, and Lewis-Beck, Michael S.. 2009. ElectionScope website. http://www.electionscope.fr/prévision-électorale/elections-législatives-allemandes/législatives-2009/ Google Scholar
Jérôme, Bruno, Jérôme-Speziari, Veronique, and Lewis-Beck, Michael S.. 2013. “A political-economy forecast for the 2013 German elections : who to rule with Angela Merkel ?” PS : Political Science & Politics 46 (3): 479–80.Google Scholar
Jérôme-Speziari, Veronique. 2005. “Prévision des élections allemandes de 2005 : vers une grande coalition.” Interview, BFM radio, September.Google Scholar
Key, V. O. 1966. The Responsible Electorate, New York, Vintage.Google Scholar
Kirchgässner, Gebhard. 1977. “Wirschaftslage und wähleverhalten”, Politische Vierteljahresschrift, 18:510536.Google Scholar
Kirchgässner, Gebhard. 1991. “Economic conditions and the popularity of the West Germany parties, before and after the 1982 government change.” In Economic and Politics, the Calculus of Support, 103–22. Ann Arbor, MI: University of Michigan Press.Google Scholar
Norpoth, Helmut and Gschwend, Thomas. 2003. “Against All Odds? The Red–green Victory.” German Political Studies 21 (1): 1534.Google Scholar
Norpoth, Helmut and Gschwend, Thomas. 2010. “The Chancellor Model: Forecasting German Elections.” International Journal of Forecasting 26 (1): 4253.Google Scholar
Norpoth, Helmut and Gschwend, Thomas. 2013. “Chancellor Model Picks Merkel in 2013 German Election.” PS: Political Science & Politics 46 (3): 481–82.Google Scholar
Rattinger, Hans. 1991. “Unemployment and elections in West Germany.” In Economic and Politics, the Calculus of Support, 4962. Ann Arbor, MI: University of Michigan Press.Google Scholar
Rosenstone, Steven J. 1983. Forecasting Presidential Elections. New Haven: Yale University Press.Google Scholar
Figure 0

Table 1 Forecast Models in this Symposium