Introduction
In 1790, Mercy Otis Warren registered her collection of patriotic poems with the District Court for the District of Massachusetts, becoming one of the first women to register a copyright in the United States.Footnote 1 When copyright functions were centralized in the Library of Congress in 1870, several women songwriters were among the first to protect their original works by registering their music compositions.Footnote 2 Decades later, in 1905, Clare Kummer became the first woman to solely author and register a musical work with the United States Copyright Office (“USCO”).Footnote 3 Despite these early milestones in women’s authorship, women today remain underrepresented as copyright authors. An analysis of copyright registration data between 1978 and 2012 reveals that two-thirds of registered authors are men.Footnote 4 The gap between authorship by men and women varies by type of work, but the existence of a gap in every work category raises questions about who is benefiting from our copyright system and why women create and register works at lower rates than men do.
Although copyright registration became voluntary in 1978, the USCO has generally continued to process more than 300,000, and often 400,000, registrations each year. Registration is not required for copyright protection, but it entails several advantages. It is a necessary prerequisite for bringing an infringement action for a U.S. work and for receiving statutory damages and attorney’s fees.Footnote 5 It makes it easier for copyright owners to prevent the importation of infringing copies and, if the work is registered within five years of publication, the registration constitutes prima facie evidence of copyright validity and authorship in litigation.Footnote 6 In addition, registration reduces transaction costs and makes it easier for copyright holders to financially benefit from selling or licensing their works.Footnote 7 This is particularly helpful for entrepreneurs seeking legitimacy or an increase in their young company’s selling potential.Footnote 8 These benefits are intended to encourage registration and reward creativity.Footnote 9 But if women are not registering copyrights as frequently as men, do the benefits of registration appeal less to women? Or are there structural, systemic, industry-specific, or other barriers to women’s participation in the copyright system?
These questions are difficult to answer fully, but it is possible that rather than women failing to appreciate the benefits of registration, the gender gap in copyright registrations is in part reflective of more general social realities, including inequitable patterns of property ownership by women as well as persistent inequality within creative industries. Notably, women are underrepresented in ownership of copyrights, trademarks, and patents compared to their share of the U.S. workforce. In 2010, women made up 46.7 percent of the U.S. workforce but received only 33.31 percent of granted trademarks.Footnote 10 Likewise, in 2015, women represented 28 percent of the STEM (science, technology, engineering, and mathematics) workforce, but only 12 percent of the inventors listed on granted patents.Footnote 11 Some creative fields, such as the music industry, have been plagued by allegations of gender bias and accompanying low levels of women participation, underscoring the finding that women registered only 24.02 percent of music copyrights between 1978 and 2012.Footnote 12
One may think that the disparity in intellectual property rights ownership only affects a limited number of artists, entrepreneurs, and scientists. However, intellectual property–intensive industries – industries whose growth is fueled by effective protection of intellectual property rights – accounted for 27.9 million U.S. jobs in 2014 and 38.2 percent of U.S. GDP.Footnote 13 A great deal of economic value is added by effectively protecting intellectual property rights and by promoting creativity and innovation among as many people as possible.
The USCO does not ask registration applicants for their demographic information. While this does not necessarily mean that gender bias could not sometimes play a role when applications are reviewed, it is at least consistent with its mission to promote creativity “for the benefit of all.”Footnote 14 It should be uncontroversial to point out that the quality and breadth of works produced would be better with a diverse and more inclusive set of authors and when barriers to entry are removed.Footnote 15 However, it is clear that either women do not respond to the current copyright system’s set of incentives or, more likely, that the incentives operate in conjunction with social and psychological factorsFootnote 16 to motivate women to create and register certain types of work but not others, and at rates that generally fall below those at which men create and register works.Footnote 17 If the USCO is to properly carry out Congress’ constitutional charge to “promote the Progress of Science and useful Arts,”Footnote 18 then we must understand what is underlying lower rates of creative authorship and subsequent registration by women.
We will seek to address some of these factors by considering the extent to which the gender disparity is or is not merely reflective of gender dynamics in other types of intellectual property holdings. Through a further discussion of patterns of inequality in other forms of property ownership, it will be possible to contextualize gender inequality in intellectual property. This will be further supplemented by a discussion of gender dynamics across different types of creative professions in the hopes of understanding some of the reasons why women may be less likely to author and register creative works in certain industries.Footnote 19
The first section reviews recent data and demonstrates patterns of copyright authorship by men and women that vary over time by work type. The second section reviews recent studies on gendered trends in patent and trademark ownership. Available data suggest that women are underrepresented in every category of intellectual property rights ownership. The third section discusses similar gender-linked differences in other forms of property, such as home and corporate ownership. These data suggest that the gender-based trends in copyright ownership reflect some more general trends of property ownership. The fourth section considers the extent to which copyright registration gender differences by type-of-work category are reflective of gender inequality within creative professions. The fifth section identifies explanations and factors that may contribute to lower rates of authorship by women. We ultimately conclude that it is impossible to rule out, based on available data, the possibility that our copyright system, in conjunction with its related industries, may have a discriminatory effect on women’s incentives to create.
6.1 The Copyright Gender Gap
Drawing on data from the USCO Electronic Catalog (“Catalog”), a study coauthored by one of us (“Study”) was the first to identify demographic patterns of copyright authors.Footnote 20 It reveals a striking degree of imbalance between population demographics and rates of authorship, particularly concerning rates of authorship among men and women. In the surveyed data, men authored an estimated two-thirds of registered works. The degree and nature of the differences between men and women went beyond mere rates of authorship, and have varied over time and across work types, showing that what seems like a gender-neutral system may produce a disparate incentive effect on men and women.Footnote 21
6.1.1 The Data Set and Methodology
The Study analyzed the over 14 million copyrighted works registered with the USCO between 1978 and 2012.Footnote 22 Registration records contain information about the work, such as its title, date of application, publication status, and creative category.Footnote 23 Usefully, the Study converted all work types into six basic categories: text, music, art, movies, drama, and software.Footnote 24
In analyzing gender demographics, the Study focused on works by known, named individual authors.Footnote 25 Registrants are not asked to self-report demographic information in their copyright registration applications. Using gender-related data extracted from the 1990 Census, the Study could assign to authors a probabilistic gender based on their first names.Footnote 26 First names are highly indicative of gender: 82 percent of the authors had a 99 percent or higher likelihood of being either a man or a woman.Footnote 27 Works created by business associations and anonymous and pseudonymous works were excluded from the gender statistics because the author’s gender could not be determined probabilistically.Footnote 28
6.1.2 Key Findings
This study revealed a wide variation in gender parity across time, type of work, and publication rates, among other aspects. Strikingly, in 2012, 64 percent of authors were men.Footnote 29 While this was a decrease from 1978, when 70 percent of the authors were men, it was still well above their labor market share in 2012.Footnote 30 The percentage of women in the labor market increased from 41.7 percent in 1978 to 46.9 percent in 2012, while the share of women authors has only increased from 30 percent in 1978 to 36 percent in 2012.Footnote 31
6.1.2.1 Gender Variation across Work Types
The disparity between authorship rates among men and women has varied across type-of-work categories. Between 1978 and 2012, men registered 88.22 percent of software copyrights and 78.16 percent of movie copyrights.Footnote 32 Both categories have experienced a relative increase in authorship by women over time, but when combined, these categories represent only 2.5 percent of registrations by individuals.Footnote 33 The most significant gains toward gender parity have been made in the text category, which makes up over a third of the individual registrations.Footnote 34 While men were listed as authors for 57.45 percent of all text registrations, the share of women authors increased from 33.98 percent to 45.83 percent between 1978 and 2012. The drama and music categories, which account for 5 percent and 44 percent of individual registrations, respectively, did not experience a significant change in gender parity between 1978 and 2012. Overall, men authored 66.99 percent of all drama registrations and 75.98 percent of all music registrations.Footnote 35 The art category experienced the greatest fluidity between 1978 and 2012, with the percentage of authorship by men decreasing between 1978 and 1984 and rising again by 2012. Art represents 11 percent of individual registrations, with men authoring 54.34 percent of total art registrations and 59.1 percent of art registrations in 2012.Footnote 36
6.1.2.2 Gender Variation in Publication Status
The data suggest that women are more likely to create and register copyrights in categories of work where the work has typically already been published at the time of registration.Footnote 37 In the study, 39 percent of registrations authored by men were published at the time of registration, compared with 44 percent of works authored by women.Footnote 38 However, these statistics are affected partly by the different types of work men and women tend to register. For example, half of all registrations authored by women were in the text category, and within that category, 61 percent of women had published their work by the time it was registered. While men demonstrated a similar propensity to publish textual work before registering it for copyright, text registrations represented only 33 percent of registrations authored by men.Footnote 39 On the other hand, music registrations represented half of the registrations authored by men, and this category only had a 22 percent prior-publication rate for men. Women, in contrast, had a 15 percent prior-publication rate for music registrations, but music registrations only made up 29 percent of women-authored registrations.Footnote 40 In the software and art categories, women were more likely to publish their work before registration than men, but in the drama category, men and women had equal publication rates.Footnote 41
6.1.2.3 Gender Variation in Age and Coauthorship
The Study concluded by examining coauthorship patterns and author age differences by gender and work type. First, in comparing registrations with more than one author listed, the Study found that authors generally worked with coauthors of the same gender. Conditional on one of the authors being a man, there was about an 80 percent chance that the other author was also a man. Conditional on one of the authors being a woman, there was about a 50 percent chance that the other author was also a woman. If authors had picked their coauthors randomly and neutrally, we would expect these statistics to have been about 71 percent and 29 percent.Footnote 42 Men and women, therefore, show a clear tendency to collaborate with same-gendered coauthors.
While there was some variation in age demographics between men and women, the difference in size was dependent on the type of work registered.Footnote 43 For example, women authors of registered works were on average one year older than men in the movie category, two years older in the music category, and three years older in the software category. On the other hand, women were generally a year or less younger than men in the text, drama, and art categories.Footnote 44
6.2 Patent and Trademark Ownership
The gender disparity in copyright registration is mirrored in both patent and trademark ownership. The degree of disparity varies for patents and trademarks, but in both cases, women are underrepresented compared with men. Women submit fewer applications than men and have fewer patents granted.Footnote 45 Focusing strictly on metrics drawn from the intellectual property system obscures the factors and events that precede a patent or trademark application. Rather than indicating a lack of ability, creativity, or interest, lower numbers of applications and grants are likely indicative of barriers to full access to and participation in the system by women. The existence of such barriers, particularly among women applying for patents, has been confirmed by researchers seeking to understand the behavior of women prior to and after securing intellectual property rights. Considered in conjunction with copyright registration, there may be systemic barriers within the intellectual property system hindering women.
Similar to copyright registration data, studies have indicated that gender disparity in patent and trademark ownership varies widely by the subcategory, or class, into which the particular patent or trademark falls. Some of these distinctions can be justified by gendered patterns of educational attainment, but additional factors suggest something other than education is disincentivizing or preventing women from seeking intellectual property rights ownership within their fields. As with copyrights, some studies on patent ownership have also indicated that women have different collaboration patterns than men and are very unlikely to patent an invention as a sole inventor.
Like the USCO, the U.S. Patent and Trademark Office (USPTO) does not record demographic information for its applicants. Therefore, the data provided later in the chapter is based on studies that used a similar procedure of matching the first names of listed owners with their likely gender using U.S. Census data.
6.2.1 The Patent Gender Gap
In 1977, only 2.6 percent of granted U.S. patents listed at least one woman as an inventor.Footnote 46 More recently, in 2016, women were listed on 21 percent of granted patents.Footnote 47 However, this remains below women’s share of the STEM labor force.Footnote 48 Furthermore, the total inventor rate – that is, the percentage of all inventors listed on granted patents who are women – has only increased from 10 percent in 2000 to 12 percent in 2015.Footnote 49 If we disaggregate some of these patent statistics, we find that the degree of gender disparity varies widely over time and by scientific field. For example, while some fields, such as life sciences, have achieved near gender parity, other fields, such as engineering, have remained vastly disproportionate.Footnote 50 This trend is reflected in STEM educational data, labor force makeup, and patent statistics.
Unlike trademarks and copyrights, the expertise required to invent something patentable would often necessitate some formal education or expertise in STEM, a high level of education, or at least a background in STEM.Footnote 51 As a result, gender disparities in a degree program at both the undergraduate and graduate levels may explain part of the gender disparity in patent rates.Footnote 52 For example, one study has argued that individuals with mechanical and electrical engineering degrees produce more patents than most other STEM degrees, but women have historically received less than 10 percent of the mechanical and electrical engineering degrees awarded to men. Because individuals with these STEM degrees have a high likelihood of patenting compared to other degree programs, a lack of women in the degree program could affect the disparity in overall patent rates between men and women.Footnote 53 On the other hand, women have been more proportionally represented in biological and physical science degree programs, and in 2015, women represented 48 percent of biological and life scientists. These STEM degrees are much less likely than mechanical and electrical engineering to lead to patent activity, but while men and women are nearly equally employed as biological and life scientists, in 2015, only 25 percent of the inventors for biotechnology patents and 23 percent of inventors for pharmaceutical patents were women, suggesting educational attainment alone does not determine patent rates.Footnote 54
6.2.1.1 Level of Gender Equality Varies by Workplace Type
Granted patents are often assigned to an employer, and by looking at assignment data, it is possible to draw conclusions about the types of work environments that either attract more women or perhaps place greater emphasis on gender equality. Between 2007 and 2016, nearly 20 percent of the inventors listed on patents assigned to universities or hospitals were women. This was followed closely by public research organizations, where 15 percent of listed patent inventors were women. These two sectors have shown the largest and most continued improvement in the share of female inventors. Between 2007 and 2016, among individual-owned patents, just under 15 percent of inventors were women.Footnote 55 Only 12 percent of the inventors listed on patents assigned to private companies were women.Footnote 56
These data support a couple of propositions. First, these statistics suggest that women are much less likely than men to individually develop and patent a new invention.Footnote 57 Second, these data support studies that concluded that women might be more likely to patent while working for academic institutions or public companies than for private companies.Footnote 58 This could be tied to the organizational structure of most private companiesFootnote 59 or could be reflective of the private sector’s difficulties in retaining women in STEM roles.Footnote 60
6.2.1.2 Patterns of Coauthorship
Several studies have found that women are more likely to work with coinventors than to apply for patents by themselves. Most often, patent teams with women have two to five total inventors. While larger teams are becoming more common overall, teams with women on them are much more likely to include four or more inventors than teams of only men.Footnote 61
While women are more likely than men to collaborate with coinventors, they are unlikely to work as part of an all-women team. Between 2007 and 2016, only 4 percent of patents had only women listed as inventors.Footnote 62 Furthermore, patents with only women listed as inventors are cited less frequently than mixed-gender and men-only patent inventor teams.Footnote 63 However, mixed-gender teams are cited more frequently in later patent applications than men-only and women-only teams, which may be indicative of either the relative value of average patents produced by diverse, mixed-gender teams or the added value of large teams of inventors.Footnote 64
6.2.1.3 Gender-Linked Behavioral Differences in Patent Applications
There are several differences between men and women during and immediately after the patent application process. First, all-women teams may be subject to gender bias or discrimination by patent examiners. One study found that for all-women teams of inventors that submitted patent applications, inventors with “common” names for women were 8.2 percent less likely to have their patent applications approved than all-men teams.Footnote 65 The magnitude of this effect decreased when women inventors had “rare” names that might not be socially connected to either gender.Footnote 66 All-women teams are also less likely to appeal rejected patent applications and less likely to have their patents maintained by their assignee than mixed-gender or all-men teams.Footnote 67 Second, women are less likely to commercialize their patents, resulting in less monetary gain from their patenting activity.Footnote 68 This is a reflection of both having women as inventors and some of the fields they specialize in. For example, while women are well-represented in life sciences, only 39 percent of life sciences patents are commercialized.Footnote 69
6.2.1.4 Explanations
Ultimately, only part of the patent gap is likely linked to the absence of women in STEM.Footnote 70 The lack of gender equality in patent-intensive fields such as engineering may disproportionately affect the patent gender gap.Footnote 71 However, even in areas of STEM where women are well-represented, they still do not patent at the same rates as men. This is particularly clear in academia, where men and women have been shown to publish similar-quality papers at similar rates. Still, men remain much more likely to patent than women.Footnote 72
Another potential problem could be the cost and complexity of the patent application process. Applying for and maintaining a patent could cost upwards of tens of thousands of dollars, and due to historical exclusion from STEM, women may not have the connections to the patent industry that men have.Footnote 73 These connections both with the patent industry and within STEM fields may be important resources for individuals to gain valuable expertise and insight into whether or not they should apply for a patent and what that process entails.Footnote 74
There are also several ways in which women applying for a patent may face some degree of discrimination. While progress has been made in recent decades, some women still report encountering either implicit bias or sexist behavior in STEM workplaces. While it is unclear how widespread these kinds of experiences may be, they may lead women to leave their jobs in STEM more frequently than men and steer women away from patent activity.Footnote 75 Even in academia, researchers have found that some science faculty may be implicitly biased against women. In a study where researchers submitted identical resumés for a lab manager position, both men and women STEM faculty members rated the resumé with a common name for a man as more qualified and offered a higher starting salary than the resumé with a common name for a woman.Footnote 76 In addition, data suggest that examiners at the USPTO show gender bias in processing applications.Footnote 77
6.2.2 The Trademark Gender Gap
Unlike patents, there has been relatively little research done on women’s trademark ownership. Still, available data suggest a similar gap exists between the number of men and women who own trademarks, although there are signs of greater equality over time. In 1980, women received 16.7 percent of trademarks granted, and by 2010 they still received only 33.31 percent.Footnote 78 Unlike patents, no set of educational indicators is associated with people who will apply for a trademark. Trademarks have occasionally been connected to entrepreneurial activity, but a 2015 survey conducted by the U.S. Census Bureau found only a marginal difference in the share of women-owned businesses with a trademark compared with men-owned businesses.Footnote 79 That being said, women as a whole are less likely to become entrepreneurs, and in that study, only 20.8 percent of the surveyed businesses were women-owned.Footnote 80
Like copyright and patent rates, women appear to specialize in different areas than men. In 2010, women were granted the most trademarks in the following classes: advertising and business, clothing, education and entertainment, and paper goods and printed matter.Footnote 81 While these categories were among the most frequently used trademark classes between 2004 and 2013, notably missing are the electrical and scientific apparatus and computer and scientific classes, the first and fourth most-used classes in that period.Footnote 82
Interestingly, women’s trademark applications were accepted more frequently than applications by men between 1988 and 2000. However, the ratio of successful trademark applications made by women and men has been nearly equal since 2000.Footnote 83 Therefore, women are likely underrepresented as trademark owners due to a lack of applications compared with men. There has not been much research done on why women file fewer applications than men. But one study has suggested that women may be hesitant to apply for trademarks due to a lack of knowledge about how they work and uncertainty about the financial value of obtaining a trademark.Footnote 84
6.3 Gender Trends across Property Ownership
While some factors and explanations are specific to intellectual property rights ownership, the disparity between men and women in the intellectual property rights context is consistent with more general inequities in other forms of property ownership and corporate power. Therefore, to fully understand lower rates of intellectual property rights ownership by women, it is necessary to contextualize our findings within the broader scheme of property ownership and wealth accumulation. In their lifetimes, women are more likely to experience poverty,Footnote 85 receive social welfare benefits,Footnote 86 and retire with few if any retirement savings compared with men.Footnote 87 Women on average make less than men for the same job, even in industries where women predominate, perpetuating both a wage and a wealth gap between men and women.Footnote 88 Despite making up half of the U.S. labor force, women represent only 5.8 percent of its CEOs.Footnote 89 A thorough exploration of gender inequality is beyond the scope of this chapter, but understanding some of the forms of inequality that affect property ownership and wealth accumulation will allow us to contextualize and explain some of the gender differences in the copyright registration data.
6.3.1 Gender Disparity in Property Ownership and Wealth Accumulation
6.3.1.1 Wage Gap and Wealth Gap
Women across the country are compensated less than men for their labor, and this disparity ultimately contributes to a lifetime wealth gap. In 2019, women on average earned 81.5 cents for every dollar earned by a man with the same job.Footnote 90 This gap has been more pronounced in occupations commonly held by men. For example, several professions with men in the majority have paid women only 70–75 percent of what they pay men for the same job.Footnote 91 In addition to varying across professions, the wage gap has also varied by geography, with women in 2013 earning between 67.3 percent and 87.6 percent of what men made based on their state.Footnote 92 One estimate suggests that the gender wage gap will not be closed in some states until after 2100.Footnote 93
The perpetuation of this wage gap contributes to women experiencing higher levels of poverty than men and is one large contributor to the wealth gap between men and women. In addition to base wage differences, women are twice as likely to be part-time workers, constitute the majority of minimum-wage and low-wage workers, and typically have more caregiving responsibilities than men, all of which can limit their ability to save for the future and accumulate wealth at the same rate as men.Footnote 94 Some studies have also found that women are more risk-averse in terms of taking financial risks, which may contribute to lower rates of wealth accumulation.Footnote 95 As a result of all of these factors, women are disproportionately unprepared for retirement compared with men.Footnote 96
6.3.1.2 Welfare Benefits
Correlated with the wage and wealth gap, women are more likely to receive welfare benefits than men. In 2018, women were more likely to experience poverty than men in every age category after turning eighteen.Footnote 97 In 2012, 23.3 percent of women in the United States received some form of welfare benefits compared with 19.3 percent of men. The statistics were starker for single mothers. In 2012, 58 percent of “female-householder families” received welfare benefits compared with 37.2 percent of “male-householder families” and 19.9 percent of married couples.Footnote 98 These statistics have varied by education level and geography, but women in the South and parts of the Western United States with less than a college-level education as a whole have had a high likelihood of experiencing poverty.Footnote 99 A variety of factors contribute to these bleak statistics the wage gap, and increased likelihood for women to be in low-paying or part-time jobs compared with men are among the most prominent.Footnote 100
6.3.1.3 Home Ownership
Home equity is the largest source of wealth for U.S. households, followed by business ownership, and this is one of the few areas in which women outperform men by some measures.Footnote 101 Since the 1990s, single women have owned more homes than single men.Footnote 102 In 2017, single women owned 22 percent of available homes in the United States, while single men owned only 13 percent.Footnote 103 However, most homes are still owned by married couples, and as soon as additional family members are added to the household, home-ownership rates by single women rapidly decrease compared with men.Footnote 104 Furthermore, despite owning more homes as a group, a recent study has suggested that women can still end up worse off than men because, on average, they buy their home for 2 percent more and sell it for 2 percent less than similarly positioned men.Footnote 105 As the dominant form of savings for many households, the disparity in purchasing and selling prices over time likely contributes to the wealth gap between men and women.Footnote 106
6.3.2 Entrepreneurial Success and Corporate Power
6.3.2.1 Women’s Entrepreneurship
Entrepreneurial activity among women and various forms of corporate ownership are related, contributing factors to property ownership and wealth accumulation. In 2012, women-owned businesses accounted for only 36 percent of U.S. businesses and earned, on average, only 22.5 percent of what men-owned businesses made.Footnote 107 Revenue differences varied widely by sector. In some industries such as arts/entertainment and scientific services, women-owned businesses made under 40 percent of the revenue of men-owned businesses. Notably, 93.7 percent of women-owned businesses were in either a service or retail industry. But the combined revenue of women-owned businesses in retail made only 13.5 percent of the revenue earned by men-owned retail businesses.Footnote 108
Part of the financial disparity between entrepreneurship by men and women is tied to a lack of funding for women-owned businesses. Men are much more likely to receive venture capital than women, and even when women receive venture capital, they receive smaller investments than men.Footnote 109 Some studies have found that this may be caused at least in part by investors evaluating women-proposed projects differently than projects proposed by men. In a study of a top venture capital pitching competition, researchers found that women were more likely to be asked how they would avoid business failure while men were more likely to be asked how they expected to maximize profits.Footnote 110 While this may seem just a difference in semantics, this type of failure-avoidance questioning was associated with projects receiving less or no funding compared with comparably positioned companies that were asked about profit maximization.Footnote 111 Another part of the funding problem is a lack of women in top venture capital firms, as only 8 percent of global venture capital partners are women. Venture capital firms with women partners have been shown to be more likely to invest in women-owned companies than firms without women partners.Footnote 112 Still, to a lesser extent, the gap in venture capital funding may also be connected to women being less likely to own intellectual property rights than men, as some studies have found that new companies with a patent receive venture capital much more quickly than others.Footnote 113
Women, however, may be less inclined than men to start their own businesses. One study found that in 2013, 11 percent of working women were running or starting their own business compared with 16 percent of men, but it is difficult to say whether this is indicative of a preference among women or a consequence of other barriers to women’s entrepreneurship.Footnote 114 For example, in a survey of successful men and women entrepreneurs, women were much more likely to believe that having a robust professional network and prior experience as an entrepreneur is crucial for entrepreneurial success and securing outside funding.Footnote 115
6.3.2.2 Corporate Ownership and Positions of Power
In December 2019, out of the S&P 500 companies, only twenty-nine (5.8 percent) company CEOs were women.Footnote 116 In a study of equity ownership in companies and C-suite executives, women on average owned forty-nine cents in equity for every dollar owned by a man.Footnote 117 While these dynamics are often reflective of individuals at the very top percentiles of income and success, they reinforce the conclusion that gendered wealth disparity permeates every income bracket. At a high level, of the companies surveyed, women represented 34 percent of the employees but held only 20 percent of the companies’ combined equity value. Part of the problem is that there are not as many women involved in the early stages of start-ups when it is more likely for the company to grow immensely and for early employees to be awarded considerable equity.Footnote 118
Another problem is the lack of women in C-suite positions. As people are promoted, firms that start with relatively equal numbers of men and women shift to become majority men. By the time people are promoted to a C-suite position, men predominate.Footnote 119 These dynamics are also reflected in company board demographics. Among Fortune 500 companies, only 22.5 percent of board positions were filled by women in 2018,Footnote 120 representing an improvement from 2004 when it was only 15.7 percent.Footnote 121
6.4 Gender Disparity in Creative Professions
While professional participation in a creative industry is not a prerequisite for creating or registering copyrightable material, gender-based inequities and discrimination within creative industries may contribute to lower rates of creation and registration of works by women. As a general rule, creating a copyrighted work of authorship does not necessitate a formal, educational, technical, or professional skill or training at the level that creating a patented invention often does. With a lower barrier to entry than STEM fields, one may expect creative industries to be more equally representative of both men and women, and in some ways, they are. However, many creative industries still struggle with a lack of women in positions of leadership, as well as allegations of implicit gender bias or outright gender-based discrimination. If these conditions create additional professional and social barriers to entry for women, then that may explain some of the gender disparity in the rates of copyright registration.
Available studies are overly dependent on understanding gender by looking at finished work products, such as released movies, top-played songs, and plays selected for performance. Therefore, it is difficult to gauge gender disparities at levels below the tip of the success iceberg or at supporting roles – such as editors in the book publishing industry or artists who are not yet prominent enough to be featured in a museum. That being said, broadly discussing gender dynamics within creative professions provides useful perspectives for understanding why some women may be disinclined or unable to create in certain fields.
6.4.1 Book Industry
Women have traditionally been in the majority at every stage of book publishing.Footnote 122 In 2012, roughly 55.6 percent of self-reported writers or authors were women.Footnote 123 That same year, 52.3 percent of periodical, book, and directory publishers were women as well.Footnote 124 Nevertheless, despite authors being majority women, the majority of authors (54.17 percent) of registered textual works in 2012 were men.Footnote 125
While women for all purposes appear to be in the majority representation-wise, there are a set of gendered patterns that may discourage women authors or otherwise act to decrease the representation of women within the industry. First, although women are overrepresented in the publishing industry, some of the largest publishing houses do not publish books written by women at the same rate as they publish books written by men.Footnote 126 One study found that out of thirteen publishing houses, only two had more than 30 percent of their published books authored by women.Footnote 127 With over 50 percent of self-reported authors being women, it is difficult to argue that this unequal representation in publishing houses is due to women’s lack of interest or ability.
Even when women’s books are published, on average, they sell for less, and their publishers invest less in their promotion compared with books written by men.Footnote 128 As a result, women profit less from their textual creativity than men. Furthermore, books written by women are comparatively less likely to be reviewed in magazines.Footnote 129 Men also have historically had a greater likelihood of having their books appear on The New York Times’ bestseller list.Footnote 130 While these statistics could be tied to lower numbers of books written by women being published in the first place, book reviewers have also predominantly been men.Footnote 131 With this background, it is perhaps unsurprising that women may not be encouraged to write and register their work as much as men.
6.4.2 Music Industry
The music industry has long struggled with a lack of women both as performers and in music production. In 2018, 35 percent of self-reported musicians and singers and only 12.4 percent of broadcast and sound engineers were women.Footnote 132 This represented an improvement for the industry from 2010 when only 31.9 percent of musicians and singers and 9.9 percent of broadcast and sound engineers were women.Footnote 133 However, despite these improvements, women remain underrepresented as musical artists and in music production. In a study of representation on the Billboard Hot 100 Year-End Charts between 2012 and 2019, only 21.7 percent of artists, 12.5 percent of songwriters, and 2.6 percent of producers were women.Footnote 134 This disparity varies by genre, with women in pop representing 32.6 percent of artists but only 11 percent of artists in alternative music.Footnote 135 This lack of representation is reinforced in awards show nominations. Between 2013 and 2020, 88.3 percent of Grammy Award nominees were men, though the number of women nominees has been trending upward over time.Footnote 136
While it is unclear whether this is a cause or an effect, the music industry has been plagued by allegations of gender-based discrimination.Footnote 137 In one study that surveyed women in different parts of the music industry, 78 percent of respondents reported that they had been treated differently due to their gender.Footnote 138 In another study, women reported that their colleagues did not take them seriously and that their contributions both as producers and performers were not seen by their colleagues as important or valuable.Footnote 139 While these barriers would not necessarily prevent a self-recording artist from creating and registering new work, they may be part of why men authored 75.98 percent of copyright registrations in the music category.Footnote 140
6.4.3 Film Industry
Men hold the vast majority of roles in the film industry. In 2010, women represented only 7 percent of directors, 2 percent of cinematographers, and 15 percent of executive producers for the top 250 grossing films of the year.Footnote 141 By 2019, these numbers have improved, though there is still a way to go. Of the top 250 grossing films of 2019, women represented 13 percent of directors, 5 percent of cinematographers, and 23 percent of executive producers.Footnote 142 This inequality is mirrored among film actors and actresses as well. In 2010, only 30 of the top 100 movies for the year featured a woman as a lead or colead. By 2019, this had increased to 43 out of the top 100 movies.Footnote 143 However, for actresses, this inequality does not appear to be tied to a lack of interest. One of the most popular college majors for professional actors and actresses is visual and performing arts, and in 2017, women received 60.1 percent of visual and performing arts bachelor’s degrees.Footnote 144 The lack of gender representation goes all the way up to the top of movie studio leadership, with one study finding that 82 percent of chief executives for some of the country’s largest movie studios are men.Footnote 145
While it is unclear whether some women choose to steer clear of the film industry or whether the industry as a whole creates additional barriers to entry for women, the film industry has faced allegations of gender-based discrimination for years.Footnote 146 Actresses have often been paid less for their creative labor than their costars, underscoring the finding that in a list of the top ten highest-paid actors and actresses for 2019, only two out of the top ten were women.Footnote 147 In addition, stories about men refusing to work with women directors and women’s contributions behind the scenes being challenged by their coworkers suggest that there may be social barriers that could discourage women from entering or remaining in the film industry.Footnote 148
6.4.4 Theatre Industry
Like the film industry, men predominate in almost every role, both on stage and behind the scenes for theatrical works. In a study of theatrical productions on Broadway between 2018 and 2019, 13 percent of directors, 24 percent of choreographers, 13 percent of writers, and 32 percent of named characters were women.Footnote 149 However, women are in the majority or close to the majority as costume designers (52 percent), stage managers (47 percent), and company managers (57 percent).Footnote 150 These trends have been mirrored in Off-Broadway productions as well. In 2010, 25 percent of directors and 31 percent of playwrights were women.Footnote 151 Notably, some theaters have had years where they did not feature a single play written by a woman, and in the 2013–14 season, women wrote only 29 percent of the plays produced in Off-Broadway theaters.Footnote 152
Women playwrights may be particularly discouraged from writing because their lack of exposure and access to theaters is a nationwide problem.Footnote 153 Between 2011 and 2014, a study of 153 theaters across the United States found that women wrote only 22 percent of the plays produced despite making up around two-thirds of theater audiences.Footnote 154 While some of this disparity may be tied to theaters relying on a certain number of revived productions year to year, men also hold an estimated 80 percent of artistic director positions in regional theater companies, and these individuals often have the greatest influence on the plays that are selected.Footnote 155 The data may however suggest a relative female inclination toward originality: While men wrote 84 percent of the revivals produced in 2016–17, women wrote 35 percent of the “new” plays produced that year.Footnote 156
6.4.5 Other Copyright-Related Industries: Art, Dance, and Architecture
Despite making up roughly 46 percent of artists in the United States between 2012 and 2016, women in the arts are not given the same opportunities as men and are compensated less for their work.Footnote 157 While this statistic suggests that men and women have a roughly equal interest in the arts, works produced by men constituted 87 percent of U.S. museum collections in 2018.Footnote 158 While 51 percent of visual artists in recent years have been women, women have received only 27 percent of solo exhibitions between 2013 and 2020.Footnote 159 This lack of exposure in museums is effected partly by women being underrepresented in art markets and fairs around the world, as well as by potential bias within museum leadership.Footnote 160
Part of the earnings gap may be tied to differences in occupation selection. For example, between 2012 and 2016, women represented 81.4 percent of dancers and choreographers but only 25 percent of architects.Footnote 161 While architects in this period made, on average, US$76,680 per year, dancers and choreographers made only US$31,150.Footnote 162 Even within the same field, women are still paid less than men. One study found that women across art professions make around US$20,000 less per year than men in the same field.Footnote 163 In addition to their undercompensated labor, women’s art is not valued as highly as art produced by men. In the fine art industry, one study found that, on average, women’s artwork sells at auction for 47.6 percent less than artwork created by men.Footnote 164 To put this into perspective, between 2008 and the first half of 2019, US$196.6 billion was spent at international art auctions, and only 2 percent of this figure, US$4 billion, was spent on works created by women.Footnote 165 Works by just five women accounted for US$1.6 billion of the total US$4 billion spent on women artists.Footnote 166 Part of the problem with women’s art valuation is that rather than comparing works by women with art produced by both men and women, it may be common in the industry to compare art prices only to works created by other women artists, which may lead to lower price growth and valuation over time.Footnote 167
6.5 Taking Stock
Gender inequality is pervasive across different sectors and industries, but while some explanations for inequality are fact-, sector-, or industry-specific, there are several takeaways from inequality in intellectual property, property, and creative professions that may inform our understanding of why more men than women register copyrights. These explanations, in turn, can form the basis for a broader examination of the U.S. copyright system and ultimately support a conclusion that the copyright system and related industries might be associated with a discriminatory effect on women.
As a wealth of intellectual property scholarship demonstrates, women are underrepresented across patent, trademark, and copyright ownership. This disparity may be due partly to a lack of institutional support, and higher barriers to entry for women.Footnote 168 While trademark ownership remains under-researched, researchers have found that the concentration of women in STEM fields is correlated in part with the number of patents granted to women inventors.Footnote 169 This suggests that a lack of women in a given field impacts the percentage of intellectual property rights awarded to women. Furthermore, while patentable material may sometimes necessitate larger team sizes than copyrightable material, research has suggested that women are much more likely to work with coinventors than men and often work with one to four coinventors.Footnote 170 Finally, some studies have indicated that patent examiners may be biased against women applicants if the applicant has a name that is socially construed as a woman’s name.Footnote 171
On a broader level, women are less likely than men to engage in entrepreneurial activity, which may affect the likelihood of women investing the time and resources necessary to secure intellectual property rights.Footnote 172 This trend is partly driven by women generally having less access than men to venture capital funding.Footnote 173 It may also be partially explained by either risk aversion among women or higher perceived barriers to entry, such as lacking prior experience or robust professional networks.Footnote 174 In addition, with women on average experiencing higher poverty rates than menFootnote 175 and earning less for their labor, women are likely rewarded less for their creative labor than men if they are working as full-time artists or creatives.Footnote 176 Furthermore, as studies on the gender makeup of venture capital firms have indicated, when there are women in leadership positions, firms are more likely to support women-owned start-ups.Footnote 177 This may indicate that a lack of women in positions of power in creative industries could, in some cases, lead to fewer opportunities for women within those industries.
Finally, our exploration of gender dynamics within several creative industries revealed widespread inequality between men and women as well as potential gender-based discrimination. While copyright registrants may not all work professionally in a creative field, the extent to which their creativity is encouraged by the larger industry may affect how much a registrant can expect to profit from their work and whether they continue to create new works.
6.5.1 Inequality or Discrimination?
Given the undeniable disparity between authorship rates among men and women, the question remains whether this difference is tied to existing forms of inequality between men and women or whether women register works at lower rates than men due to gender-based discrimination.
6.5.1.1 Inequality
As suggested in the preceding sections, gender inequality is pervasive and touches almost every component of participation in creative industries. With a wealth gap between men and women and higher poverty rates among women, the gap in women’s ownership of copyright registrations is consistent with more general social patterns of inequality in property ownership by women. While registering a copyright is not as large of a financial burden as applying for a patent, some women may lack networks that promote knowledge or encourage or promote the value of obtaining copyrights, which studies have found to be important for trademarks and patents as well.Footnote 178 Part of the gap in registration rates is also likely a reflection of existing inequality within creative professions, which would be consistent with studies on patent frequency that have suggested that the number of women inventors increases as the proportion of women in STEM fields increases.Footnote 179 Even though several creative industries are achieving greater levels of gender parity, in some cases, women still have to overcome past inequality that may continue to discourage their creativity.Footnote 180
Women also may be disinclined to create and register their works because they continue to be compensated less for their work than men. This may even deter some women from pursuing a creative profession, knowing they have a smaller likelihood of success in some industries. And even if they become successful, they may not be compensated as much as similarly positioned men.Footnote 181
6.5.1.2 Discrimination
While an unknown portion of the disparity in registration rates between men and women is likely tied to existing forms of inequality, women face additional barriers to full participation in the copyright system both within their fields as well as within the copyright system itself. Some portion of the gender imbalance in creative professions may be tied to women self-selecting certain fields in greater numbers than men. However, when women do not have the same opportunities to be published authors,Footnote 182 have their plays produced,Footnote 183 or have their artwork shown in a gallery,Footnote 184 it is difficult to argue that creative professions are free from some degree of gender-based discrimination that may discourage some women from creative authorship.
Despite purporting to incentivize original works of authorship by all, regardless of gender, the current copyright system does not protect forms of creative expression that have traditionally been associated with women. For example, recipes, fashion designs, and sewing and knitting patterns have traditionally received little or no copyright protection.Footnote 185 Women traditionally dominated these industries, and many had a communal aspect whereby multiple women would collaborate and build off of each other’s creativity.Footnote 186 Their exclusion may suggest that women’s creative expression is not valued as highly as men’s in terms of being perceived as a form of creativity that needs, and is worth, incentivizing. At the same time, including these fields and forms of creativity may either change the communal aspect of these industries by enforcing individual claims of authorship or entail substantial changes to the law of copyright, such as a revision of the nature of the originality requirement.Footnote 187
The copyright system may have a discriminatory effect on women due to its requirement that to become a coauthor, one must make an independently copyrightable contribution to the joint work. This standard is reflected in case law,Footnote 188 as well as in the USCO’s definition of coauthorship.Footnote 189 This requirement for coauthorship may have a disparate impact on women who prefer to work collaboratively or operate in fields that involve communal creativity because multiple individuals may make important contributions that are nevertheless not independently copyrightable. Creative expression does “not occur in splendid isolation,” yet the creative contributions of individuals go unrewarded when their contributions do not qualify them as “authors.”Footnote 190 Between 1976 and 2012, only 14.2 percent of copyright registrations had multiple authors.Footnote 191 Yet, from research on patent behavior among womenFootnote 192 as well as an understanding of traditional forms of creativity among women, we know that some women may be inclined toward collaborative creative expression.Footnote 193 While the “independently copyrightable contribution” standard emerged from Professor Paul Goldstein and was subsequently adopted by case law, it is possible that Professor David Nimmer’s alternative standard for coauthorship – one that merely requires each coauthor’s contribution to be more than de-minimis – would better incentivize women’s creativity.Footnote 194 Finally, at least one study has indicated that officers within the patent system may be biased against applicants with names commonly associated with women; it might not be unfounded to surmise that there could be a similar effect within the copyright system.Footnote 195
Conclusion
When women make up roughly 50 percent of the U.S. population but only one-third of the authors of registered works, it is necessary to understand why women do not create and register works at the same rates as men. Unfortunately, this gender disparity is not unique to copyright registrants. Women are less likely to own trademarks and are less likely to apply for patents than men. This is consistent with larger and more general trends in property ownership. Women as a whole are much less likely to achieve the same level of financial success as men due in part to persistent wealth and wage gaps. This disparity in the financial payoff is just one aspect of existing forms of gender-based inequality in many creative industries.
It is likely not feasible for the copyright system to fully mitigate the impact of gender disparity within creative professions. However, understanding some of the factors that may discourage creativity, participation, and copyright registration among women is a crucial first step for determining how to encourage creativity moving forward. Despite encountering additional barriers inside and outside the copyright system, women have persisted as successful authors, playwrights, musicians, and artists. But if all or even some of the additional barriers were removed, the increased creative output among women could be even more remarkable and work to society’s benefit.
Introduction
“Without women, life is pure prose,” wrote Nicaraguan poet Rubén Darío. Not only have women inspired male poetic creativity, but they have also contributed to progress in the world, and evidence of female artistic and intellectual attributes has been left behind throughout history. During prehistoric times, women must have been anonymous inventors, creating a number of objects and activities needed for everyday survival while the men were off hunting. The creative potential of the “fairer sex” has been marginalized, limited, and unacknowledged due to unequal gender treatment at different periods in human history.
This chapter attempts to shed light on the efforts that women inventors from three emerging countries – Brazil, India, and Mexico – have undertaken to overcome the obstacles of inequality and how relevant these challenges can be for economic development and society. In particular, it seeks to (1) analyze gender differentiation in creativity, innovation, and science; (2) define the nature and dynamics of female inventive activity by using data provided by the U.S. Patent and Trademark Office (USPTO) on patents granted in Brazil, India, and Mexico; (3) determine which factors influencing the growing propensity of women to invent help reduce gender inequality in knowledge economies; and (4) contribute policy proposals that target greater female participation in inventive activities.
The key questions for this research are thus: What are the characteristics and dynamics of female inventive activity in emerging countries with different economic development paths? What factors influence women’s propensity to invent? Do female inventive skills complement those of men?
We consider that women possess potential abilities for invention-innovation and that their propensity to be inventors, by themselves or in co-participation with men, will depend on their scientific background and variables related to inventive activity.
The findings of this research suggest that factors influence, to varying degrees, the propensity of women to invent in Brazil, India, and Mexico. Each case offers different strands of analysis according to the innovation trajectories of each country and the incorporation of women into scientific and technological (S&T) research. For instance, the fact that the stock of prior knowledge is significant only in the size of inventor teams has a positive influence on women inventors in Brazil and Mexico. Concerning patents, patents by firms positively affect women inventors in Mexico and India, while patents by institutions and individuals only affect Mexico and Brazil, respectively. Regarding the technological field, mechanical is significant in Mexico, while pharmaceutical, medical, electrical and electronics, and “others” are important in Brazil. In contrast, in India, no particular field is influential on the propensity of women to invent. The presence of foreign researchers increases this propensity in Mexico. The outcomes suggest specific policies that will promote the incorporation of women and the development of their inventive potential in the different technological fields. To that extent, gender inequalities in inventive activity can be overcome, and this will be expressed through improved economic growth and social welfare.
The following section provides a short, specialized literature review on the factors influencing women’s ability to display their inventive capabilities. The second section deals with whether policies geared toward reducing gender inequalities in education, science, and technological knowledge have been implemented in Brazil, India, and Mexico. The third section focuses on analyzing the dynamics of female inventive activity in these emerging countries, specifying the empirical model used to test the hypotheses, analyze the results, and formulate policy proposals. The last section presents conclusions and advances some policy recommendations.
7.1 Review of Literature on Women Inventors
Despite women’s enormous potential to contribute to economic growth through scientific, technological, inventive, management, and business activities, they have historically been marginalized in education, particularly in S&T fields of study (Asgeirsdottir, 200Reference Asgeirsdottir6). The growing incorporation of women into S&T careers and their professional performance in these fields is seen as a potential source of economic growth and well-being in society (Hunt et al., Reference Hunt, Garant, Herman and Munroe2012; Huyer, Reference Huyer2015; Kahler, Reference Kahler2012; UKIPO, 2016). As more women develop new scientific knowledge and technological innovations, a positive impact on countries’ productivity, economic growth, and social well-being is expected (European Commission, 2008). Especially when women are involved in science, technology, engineering, and mathematics (STEM) fields, they acquire the skills to develop new S&T ideas that have innovative potential and foster entrepreneurship (Kuschel et al., Reference Kuschel, Ettl, Díaz-Garcia and Alsos2020).
Some authors maintain that women have participated in the development of science since the beginning. Yet, their involvement and contributions have been mainly ignored by historians or deliberately concealed behind male figures (van den Eynde, Reference van den Eynde1994). Today, the deficiencies in women’s participation in science and technology are more visible (UNESCO, 2018).Footnote 1
Historic gender discrimination notwithstanding, some women have succeeded in standing out for their scientific work. For example, Marie Curie received two Nobel Prizes: in 1903 for physics, shared with her husband Pierre and Henri Becquerel, and in 1911 for chemistry, all by herself. Rosalind Franklin’s X-ray diffraction photographs were crucial for the double helix model of DNA, for which James Watson and Francis Crick were awarded the Nobel Prize in Physiology or Medicine in 1962.
In the realm of technology, women have also developed inventions that have significantly impacted industrially and successful businesses at different times in history. Women’s inventions have moved from household utensils, clothing, and other fields to inventions of greater technological complexity (Table 7A.1). Women inventors in developed countries stand out. As developing nations have made efforts in science and technology, women involved in these fields – albeit in a much smaller proportion than men – have been publishing scientific findings in journals, patenting inventions, and receiving awards – including “Women in Science” Awards from UNESCO–L’Oréal–ABC (Agência Brasil, 2018). Concerning the emerging countries selected in this study, India reports significant scientific achievements from women in various fields (Ramesh, Reference Ramesh2020). Brazilian women scientists have been critical players in life sciences and health, and women in Mexico have made essential contributions in the same area (Table 7A.1).
The interest in studying the contributions of women inventors is recent. Several studies offer a historical focus, giving an account of the social impact of inventions made by women in different periods and industrialized countries (Blashfield, Reference Blashfield1996; Braun, Reference Braun2007; Currie, Reference Currie2001; Karnes and Bean, Reference Karnes and Bean1995; Whittington and Smith-Doerr, Reference Whittington and Smith-Doerr2008, among others). Others have made remarkable efforts to identify women inventors across countries, regions, technological fields, and sectors, using data on Patent Cooperation Treaty (PCT) applications from the World Intellectual Property Organization between 1995 and 2015 (Martínez et al., Reference Lax-Martínez, Raffo and Saito2016). Another effort to identify women inventors was made by the UK Intellectual Property Office (2016), which analyzed ninety million documents compiled from the European Patent Office (EPO) and its Worldwide Patent Statistical Database (PATSTAT). Additionally, the USPTO (2020) has analyzed patent data from 1976 to 2019 to identify women inventors compared to men. The findings of these studies coincided, identifying that a vital gender gap still exists, but there is a growing trend in the incorporation of women in inventor teams. There are also differences between countries in the technological fields in which women are involved (Martínez et al., Reference Lax-Martínez, Raffo and Saito2016; UKIPO, 2016; USPTO, 2020).
Some studies centered on analyzing patented inventions with female inventors’ participation in information technology (Ashcraft and Breitzman, Reference Ashcraft and Breitzman2012; Kahler, Reference Kahler2012). Still, other studies have spotlighted the problem of the significant gap in female participation as inventors, as patent owners, and in the commercialization of inventions (Frietsch et al., Reference Frietsch, Haller, Funken-Vrohlings and Grupp2009; Giuri et al., Reference Giuri, Grimaldi, Kochenkova, Munari and Toschi2020; Hunt et al., Reference Hunt, Garant, Herman and Munroe2012; Jung and Ejermo, Reference Jung and Ejermo2014; Kahler, Reference Kahler2012; Milli et al., Reference Milli, Gault, Williams-Baron, Xia and Berlan2016; Whittington and Smith-Doerr, Reference Whittington and Smith-Doerr2008) (Table 7A.2).Considering that women have gradually increased their participation in academia over the past sixty years, some studies have focused on women’s working conditions, seeking to identify reasons that inhibit greater female involvement in S&T research projects. Some authors point out that family/career tradeoffs disadvantage women’s academic positions and, therefore, women in science may value authorship of scientific articles more than inventorship reflected by patents (Lissoni et al., Reference Lissoni, Montobbio and Zirulia2013). In the view of these authors, women are less likely to patent than men (Whittington and Smith-Doerr, Reference Whittington and Smith-Doerr2008), even if they have a similar history of publications (Azoulay et al., Reference Azoulay, Ding and Stuart2007; Breschi et al., Reference Breschi, Lissoni and Montobbio2005; Stephan et al., Reference Stephan, Gurmu, Sumell and Black2007, cited by Lissoni et al., Reference Lissoni, Montobbio and Zirulia2013).
Either way, gender-differentiated academic performance is seen across scientific fields and countries in terms of the number of women and men authors and their productivity, citations, recognition, and salary. This seems related to diverse publishing, career longevity, and dropout rates, particularly in academic careers across STEM fields (Huang et al., Reference Huang, Gates, Sinatra and Barabási2020). The fact that women graduate with STEM degrees in a lower proportion than men means that they have fewer opportunities to operate in business and commercialization circuits, even if they are inventors (Giuri et al., Reference Giuri, Grimaldi, Kochenkova, Munari and Toschi2020; Kuschel et al., Reference Kuschel, Ettl, Díaz-Garcia and Alsos2020; Lissoni et al., Reference Lissoni, Montobbio and Zirulia2013). However, in some fields, such as biotechnology, women scientists are more likely to become inventors in patents by firms, especially when those firms are more flexible and less hierarchical in their organizational management and favor collaboration with academia and other companies.
Other reasons explaining the persistent academic gender productivity gap include “differences in family responsibilities, … career absences, resource allocation, the role of peer review, collaboration, role stereotypes, academic rank, specialization, and work climate.” Insofar as the case studies are limited, the analysis of this phenomenon needs to be deepened, covering the whole longitudinal, disciplinary, and geographical landscape (Huang et al., Reference Huang, Gates, Sinatra and Barabási2020: 4609).
As for emerging and developing countries, studies of Mexico (Guzmán, 2012) and comparative studies of Latin American countries (Sifontes Fernandez and Morales Valera, Reference Sifontes Fernandez and Morales Valera2014) have been conducted. These studies show the huge gap in female participation in inventive activities, identify the technological sectors in which women participate, and explain the rate of female involvement in an innovative activity associated with external collaboration and the patenting of universities and institutions (Sifontes and Morales, Reference Sifontes and Morales2020).
The literature on women inventorsFootnote 2 and, in particular, on factors affecting women’s propensity to invent remains limited. However, once the barriers faced by women in accessing patenting and commercializing innovations have been identified, the authors put forward interesting suggestions to overcome these barriers (Hunt et al., Reference Hunt, Garant, Herman and Munroe2012; Meng, Reference Meng2018; Milli et al., Reference Milli, Gault, Williams-Baron, Xia and Berlan2016). The relevance of this research resides in the fact that it identifies factors influencing the propensity of women to be inventors, in addition to characterizing the activity and dynamics of inventive activity involving at least one woman in three emerging countries. This analysis allows us to corroborate the extent to which the U.N. Sustainable Development Goals are met, which will contribute positively to their economic and social development (Table 7A.2).
7.2 Have There Been Policies in Brazil, India, or Mexico for Reducing Gender Inequalities in Education, Science, and Technological Knowledge?
A crucial aspect of sizing gender inequalities in the knowledge economy is highlighting the stylized facts,Footnote 3 of the gaps in the Gender Development Index (GDI)Footnote 4 and in human capital specialization by gender. This paves the way for the empirical analysis of women inventors in the emerging countries selected. Therefore, the next section deals with whether policies geared toward reducing gender inequalities in education, science, and technological knowledge have been implemented.
7.2.1 Gender Inequality Index: Brazil, India, and Mexico in the Global Context
According to the Gender Inequality Index (GII),Footnote 5 Brazil and Mexico stand out for nearly converging in the 2014 GDI (with index scores of 0.997 and 0.943, respectively), whereas India has a lower index score of 0.795 (Figure 7A.1). India, however, rose in the GDI in 2018; Mexico and Brazil had marginal improvements. The Latin American countries’ GII scores rank between very high human development (VHHD) and high human development (HHD), while India ranks in the low human development category.
In terms of average years of schooling, gender advances were observed between 2014 and 2018 in the three emerging countries studied (Figure 7.1). Compared with VHHD and HHD countries, the average years of schooling in Brazil, India, and Mexico were lower for both sexes, especially in India. In Mexico, there was a marginal increase in average years of schooling from 8.2 to 8.4, while the corresponding figure remained 8.8 years for men. In Brazil, women exceeded the average years of schooling for men: 8.1 versus 7.6 average years, respectively, in 2018. Finally, there were more significant differentials in India, with only 4.7 average years of schooling for women and 8.2 for men.
7.2.2 Human Capital Specialization by Gender: Toward Which Scientific Disciplines Are Women in Higher Education Oriented?
The graduate gender gap in the scientific field has different dimensions across countries. Having gender gaps in engineering, manufacturing, and construction, as well as in STEM, is a fact for all three countries (Figure 7.2). There has been very little improvement from 2014 to 2017 – with none, in fact, in Mexico in the STEM field. More men than women in Brazil and Mexico graduate in information and communication technologies, and the same is true for India’s agriculture, forestry, fisheries, and veterinary sciences. These gaps have even increased from 2014 to 2017. However, across all three emerging countries, graduation percentages for women are higher in natural sciences, mathematics, and statistics and are robust in health and welfare. Only minor changes have occurred (UNESCO, 2016, 2018).
Participation of female graduates in STEM careers in 2017 registered significant and differentiated progress across countries. In India, female graduates reached parity in information and communication technologies. In health and welfare, women surpassed men in all three countries, especially in Brazil (75 percent women). Women reached parity in natural sciences, mathematics, and statistics, especially in Brazil (59.5 percent). However, women still lagged behind men in traditional fields (Figure 7.2).
7.2.3 Inclusion of Women in S&T Research
The participation of women within the total group of researchers in Brazil and MexicoFootnote 6 improved between 2011 and 2015, when compared with the period between 1996 and 2000 (Figure 7.3). In general, the number of researchers in Mexico increased more for men (an increase of 39,000) than for women, from 8,100 to 34,400 researchers (an increase of 26,300). As for Brazil, the increase was noteworthy and even higher for women (136,000 women researchers compared with 129,000 men researchers).Footnote 7 The differential between Mexico and Brazil (89,500 compared with 312,800 researchers) is most likely associated with the fact that Mexico has had little GDP expenditure on research and development (R&D) (an average of 0.4 percent). In contrast, Brazil intensified its efforts in this area (1 percent) (Table 7A.3).Footnote 8
When identifying researchers by scientific areas in the two Latin American countries between 2011 and 2015, diversification and greater integration of women in the various scientific fields are observed. Although Brazil and Mexico, respectively, have 25 percent and 22 percent of women in medicine, the differential between the two countries in the number of women researchers in this field was substantial (see Figure 7.3). The count for Brazil was 80,600 during 2011–2015, an increase of 9.4 times from 1996 to 2000, and the corresponding figure for Mexico was 17,300 researchers during 2011–2015, an increase of 4.6 times. Other areas of importance are agriculture and biological sciences, biochemistry, genetics, and molecular biology (an average of 10 percent each) and, to a lesser degree, immunology, and microbiology (5 percent), with only marginal percentages in other fields.
7.2.4 Launch of Knowledge Empowerment Policies
We find STEM and Gender Advancement (SAGA) among the international projects. Efforts have focused on pushing for reforms to close gender gaps in STEM at the education and research levels – and also drawing lessons from evidence and the policy mix to improve national science, technology, and innovation (STI) policies. These efforts encourage the incorporation of women into the knowledge economy. In addition, they develop a better understanding of women and girls in science. Finally, they provide estimates and help build sex-disaggregated data, and design and implement the STI policy instruments that affect gender equality in STEM (UNESCO, 2016).
As noted in the UNESCO study, there are several important facts about women researchers: (1) Women are slightly less likely than men to collaborate across academic and corporate sectors on research papers; (2) there is a relatively slight variation between comparator countries and regions in the percentage of cross-sector collaboration between academia and industry; (3) the proportion of scholarly output resulting from the academic–corporate collaboration is slightly lower for women researchers than for men researchers; (4) women tend to have a slightly higher share of the top 10 percent of interdisciplinary scholarly output relative to their total scholarly output than men; (5) among researchers, women are generally less internationally mobile than men; and (6) the highest citation impact is associated with transitory researchers (those who move internationally for periods of less than two years) (Elsevier Research Intelligence, 2017: 7).
7.3 Empirical Study: Factors Affecting the Propensity of Women to Invent
This section analyzes the nature and dynamics of female inventive activity in Mexico, Brazil, and India and then tests a hypothesis. First, we characterize the inventive activity of USPTO patents granted to those emerging countries where at least one woman participates. Second, we state the hypothesis and specify the econometric model seeking to identify the factors that contribute to increasing the propensity of women to invent. Third, we verify the validity of the hypothesis and analyze the results.
7.3.1 Nature and Dynamics of Female Inventive Activity: Data
Our analysis of emerging female inventors focuses on three countries in the study: India, Brazil, and Mexico. We have used the USPTO database of patents granted to the holders in three countries. The period for each country is different: Mexico, 1980–2015; Brazil, 1997–2013; and India, 1997–2010. We identified those patents with at least one woman inventor and then organized the list of women inventors, associating with them the information on the patent(s).
We observe different growth dynamic paths for USPTO patents granted to the three countries. On the one hand, India was favored by a ten-year transition period following the adoption of the Agreement on Trade-Related Aspects of Intellectual Property Rights (TRIPS Agreement), showing an increasing dynamic in the case of pharmaceuticals. From 1997 to 2010, 2,685 patents were granted to Indian holders, of which 1,219 involved at least one woman inventor and 1,416 involved only men inventors (see Figure 7.4). India registered an annual average growth rate (AAGR) of 20.9 percent, which was higher for those patents with at least one woman inventor (24.7 percent). Two subperiods stand out in the evolution of patents granted to Indian holders. The first, 1997–2003, showed an AAGR of 40 percent on total patents, and patents with female collaboration were notably higher (54.2 percent). The second subperiod, 2004–2010, had a lower AAGR of 8.34 percent, particularly for patents with women inventors (6.7 percent) (Figure 7.4). Perhaps in the following years, patent expansion grew and was equaled by that of at least one woman.
On the other hand, we have Mexico with lower growth. Indeed, 1,193 USPTO patents were granted to Mexican assignees from 1986 to 2015, with an AAGR of 8.4 percent. Although female participation in total patents is characterized by a large gap, the 108 patents identified with at least one woman inventor were slightly higher (AAGR of 8.7 percent). Women’s collaboration increased in 2007, with seven patents, and reached seventeen in 2014 (Figure 7.5). Innovative activity in Mexico remains low because of a lack of entrepreneurial and institutional investment in R&D activities that target innovation and patenting.
Concerning Brazil, of the 1,434 patents granted to Brazilians between 1997 and 2013, 388 (27 percent) had at least one woman inventor on the team of researchers. The growth path was very similar to that for all patents. The country has a small and volatile trajectory, but this trajectory is growing as the R&D/GDP percentage increases (Figure 7.6). Although the most significant proportion of patents with female involvement in Brazil is individual, teams with two or more inventors have become the practice since the end of the 1990s.
In short, the evolution of granted patents analyzed shows that even if the participation of women inventors in each country is still marginal, it has been increasing, especially in India. It is worth pointing out that men are also on those inventor teams with at least one woman inventor. The differentiated abilities across genders seem to strengthen the scope of innovation.Footnote 9 We assume that the increase of women in inventor teams is associated with the increasing incorporation of female inventors in STEM careers and related research activities. This phenomenon is more evident in India and Brazil. There is growth in Mexico but at a lower level.
7.3.2 Nature of Innovation
We proceed to identify the features of patents involving women inventors. It is interesting to compare the patent number by team size in the three emerging countries in this study. In general, the teams are mixed, except in patents with only one inventor. India leads with 45 percent of patents with groups including women, followed by Brazil with 24 percent and Mexico with just 21 percent. During the total period analyzed, the whole patents with teams of two to five inventors predominate in all three countries: two-thirds in India and just over 70 percent in Mexico and Brazil.
Regarding teams with more than six researchers, India stands out, with almost one-third of the patents, and the two Latin American countries have around 10 percent. Individual women’s participation in patenting is relatively marginal. This is especially the case for India, where 3.4 percent of patents are characterized as individual patents. Mexico and Brazil slightly exceed 15 percent. In contrast, for patents in which only men participate, individual participation is significant in Brazil and Mexico, but the figure is lower in India (see Table 7.1).
Country | Team size | Total number of patents | Number of patents with at least one female inventor by team size | Number of patents with only male inventors by team size |
---|---|---|---|---|
Mexico | One inventor | 227 | 20 | 207 |
Two to five | 324 | 87 | 237 | |
Six or more inventors | 36 | 16 | 20 | |
Brazil | One inventor | 631 | 62 | 569 |
Two to five | 688 | 256 | 432 | |
Six or more inventors | 115 | 31 | 84 | |
India | One inventor | 348 | 41 | 307 |
Two to five | 1,801 | 796 | 1,005 | |
Six or more inventors | 537 | 371 | 166 |
Regarding patent assignees, institution holders are prominent in India (65 percent) and Mexico (54 percent). In contrast, firms have greater weight in Brazil (73 percent), although there has been less participation in patents with women inventors in Mexico (44 percent) and India (34 percent) (Figure 7.7).
During 1997–2013 in Brazil, 401 female inventors were identified, representing 18.5 percent of all inventors. In 2003, the Natura companies and the Johnson & Johnson subsidiary in Brazil had the greatest participation, in many cases with inventor teams composed of several researchers. In 2006, a similar situation was seen with the Foundation for Research Support in the State of São Paulo. There is a clear growing trend, which has been most noteworthy in the past few years and seems to be associated with a higher incidence of larger inventor teams.
During 1980–2015 in Mexico, sixty-one female inventors were identified, representing 5.3 percent of the total number of inventors. Outstanding for their participation are Sabritas (six of the sixty-one), Mabe (three), El Instituto Mexicano del Petróleo (nine), and the Universidad Nacional Autónoma de México (seven). As in Brazil, the trend is for working in relatively large teams. The average number of researchers per patent is three, but as many as five in the chemical, pharmaceutical, and medical sectors. Individual patents are registered only in the electrical and electronic sectors.
From 1997 to 2010 in India, 219 female and 659 male inventors were identified in the 1,208 patents with at least one woman. Over half (53 percent) of the patents had the Council of Scientific and Industrial Research as the patent assignee. Companies that had more than seven patents were Aurobind–Pharma (seven), Dr. Reddy’s Laboratories (nineteen), Hetero Drugs (twelve), Indian Oil Corporation (twelve), Ittiam Systems (fourteen), and Reliance Life Sciences (forty-one). A trend toward working in increasingly larger teams of inventors has been recorded in India, as it is the country with the most effective teams – in fact, with ten inventors in the “others” category and nine inventors in chemical. In Brazil, the largest teams of inventors are in pharmaceutical and medical (nine inventors), chemical (seven inventors), and “others” (seven inventors).
For the field of technology, where patents are classified, we underscore the following evidence. In all three countries, women’s participation stands out in pharmaceutical, medical, and chemical patents. Specifically, nearly two-fifths of India’s women inventors are in the pharmaceutical and medical sector, and 42 percent are in the chemical sector, according to the higher percentage of women graduates in these sectors and their integration as researchers (Table 7A.3). Studies have found a positive correlation between the increasing number of women graduates in STEM careers and research activities and a higher number of female inventors (Giuri et al., Reference Giuri, Grimaldi, Kochenkova, Munari and Toschi2020; Kuschel et al., Reference Kuschel, Ettl, Díaz-Garcia and Alsos2020; Lissoni et al., Reference Lissoni, Montobbio and Zirulia2013). However, this study did not explore such correlations due to a lack of information on each woman.
The distribution of women inventors in Brazil and Mexico is similar in the pharmaceutical and medical sectors – 37 percent and 29 percent, respectively. In the chemical sector, the distribution is 31 percent and 26 percent, respectively. Few women inventors, however, are found in mechanical, electrical, and electronic sectors, with percentages ranging between 2 percent and 4 percent. In the “others” category, differentials are observed among the three countries, with Mexico – where women inventors collaborate on a third of the patents – standing out.
In every patent document, previously consulted patents are recorded as Backward Patent Citations (BwPatCit) to show that the work done by the researchers is state of the art in their technological field. We consider this variable the stock of previous technological knowledge. We estimate this indicator based on the average of BwPatCit per patent where a woman is present. Mexico has the highest average (forty-seven citations per patent), whereas India and Brazil have averages of fifteen and sixteen citations, respectively.
Regarding patent value, we use the number of forward patent citations (FwPatCit) per patent as a proxy variable. We observe that, in all three countries, the importance is still relatively low, especially in India.
India has a notably higher percentage of claims in the pharmaceutical and medical sector and the chemical sector (a combined 83 percent). Both sectors are essential for the other two countries, but with a lower proportion: 66 percent for Mexico and 68 percent for Brazil. The percentages for the “others” category are 29 percent and 19 percent, respectively. There is marginal diversification in the other technology categories.
Table 7.2 shows the distribution of patents with at least one woman inventor by variable, which we consider the nature of innovation, and by technological field. It summarizes what was previously said.
Mexico | Brazil | India | ||
---|---|---|---|---|
TechField | % | % | % | |
Chemical | 26 | 29 | 42 | |
Computer and communication | 3 | 4 | 8 | |
Drugs and medicals | 31 | 37 | 40 | |
Electrical and electronic | 3 | 2 | 2 | |
Mechanical | 2 | 4 | 3 | |
Others | 34 | 24 | 6 | |
Total | 100 | 100 | 100 | |
% | % | % | ||
Chemical | 51 | 28 | 4 | |
Computer and communication | 1 | 2 | 9 | |
Drugs and medicals | 8 | 46 | 75 | |
Electrical and electronic | 2 | 2 | 2 | |
Mechanical | 0 | 5 | 2 | |
Others | 38 | 17 | 8 | |
100 | 100 | 100 | ||
ValuePat | % | % | % | |
Chemical | 34 | 29 | 28 | |
Computer and communication | 0 | 5 | 3 | |
Drugs and medicals | 18 | 45 | 57 | |
Electrical and electronic | 1 | 0 | 2 | |
Mechanical | 0 | 2 | 3 | |
Others | 47 | 18 | 7 | |
100 | 100 | 100 | ||
TechInnScope | % | % | % | |
Chemical | 38 | 29 | 42 | |
Computer and communication | 3 | 4 | 7 | |
Drugs and medicals | 28 | 39 | 41 | |
Electrical and electronic | 2 | 3 | 1 | |
Mechanical | 0 | 6 | 3 | |
Others | 29 | 19 | 5 | |
Total | 100 | 100 | 100 | |
AssigPat | % | % | % | |
Individual | 2 | 1 | 1 | |
Institution | 54 | 26 | 65 | |
Firm | 44 | 73 | 34 | |
Total | 100 | 100 | 100 | |
MobInv | % | % | % | |
1 | 93 | 90 | 99 | |
More than 1 | 7 | 10 | 1 | |
Total | 100 | 100 | 100 | |
SizeRT | Average | Average | Average | |
Chemical | 5 | 7 | 9 | |
Computer and communication | 2 | 6 | 5 | |
Drugs and medicals | 5 | 9 | 9 | |
Electrical and electronic | 1 | 4 | 1 | |
Mechanical | 3 | 6 | 6 | |
Others | 4 | 7 | 10 | |
Total average | 3 | 7 | 7 | |
Women by team participation | % | % | % | |
Chemical | 50 | 45 | 35 | |
Computer and communication | 75 | 43 | 47 | |
Drugs and medicals | 67 | 50 | 40 | |
Electrical and electronic | 100 | 59 | 56 | |
Mechanical | 66 | 49 | 37 | |
Others | 60 | 64 | 36 | |
Total average | 70 | 52 | 42 |
7.3.3 Hypothesis Research and Model Specification
Considering the historical marginalization of women in S&T activities, we expect that women possess potential abilities for invention-innovation and that their inclusion in the sphere, in co-participation with men, will positively affect the creation of new processes and technological products. The factors associated with innovation that especially affect this propensity are (1) the stock of previous knowledge, (2) the type of patent assignee, (3) the technological field of the patent, (4) the invention scope of each patent, (5) international inventor mobility, and (6) patent value. Therefore, we propose a regression model, which is estimated for each woman inventor in Mexico, Brazil, and India and is specified in the following equation:
Where the dependent variable:
According to this estimate, a reduced WmjPropInvij is shown in the three countries (Table 7.3). Compared with Mexico, India and Brazil are relatively higher. They are similar in all technological fields – except that India is higher in the electrical and electronics sector while Brazil is higher in the pharmaceutical and medical sectors. Mexico is notably lower in almost all sectors, although less so in the pharmaceutical, medical, and chemical sectors.
Mexico | Brazil | India | ||
---|---|---|---|---|
WmjPropInvij | Average | Average | Average | |
Chemical | 0.19 | 0.26 | 0.21 | |
Computer and communication | 0.08 | 0.22 | 0.23 | |
Drugs and medicals | 0.22 | 0.4 | 0.26 | |
Electrical and electronic | 0.08 | 0.23 | 0.12 | |
Mechanical | 0.16 | 0.24 | 0.21 | |
Others | 0.14 | 0.24 | 0.21 | |
Total average | 0.15 | 0.27 | 0.21 |
The independent variables are taken from USPTO patent information. They characterize the inventions. Based on the literature reviewed, these variables allow us to assume how each invention influences WmjPropInvij (Table 7.4).
Variable | Variable proxy | It is expected that |
---|---|---|
Stock of previous knowledge. Number of BwPatCit as a proxy variable | … the higher the BwPatCit, which reflects increased R&D expenditure, the higher is the propensity of women to become inventors (Aldieri et al., Reference Aldieri, Carlucci, Paolo Vinci and Yigitcanlar2019; Duguet and MacGarvie, Reference Duguet and MacGarvie2005; Guzmán et al., Reference Guzmán, Brown and Acatitla2020; Hall, Reference Hall, Fagerberg and Mowery2005; Jaffe et al., Reference Jaffe, Trajtenberg and Henderson1993) | |
SizeRT | Size of research teams. Number of inventors involved in the generation of the patent | … a larger research team, by incorporating women, increases the diversity of new technological ideas and therefore the propensity of women to become inventors (Bianco and Venezia, Reference Bianco and Venezia2019; Breitzman and Thomas, Reference Breitzman and Thomas2015) |
AssigPat | Patent assignee. 1 = Firm; 2 = Institution; 3 = Individual; 4 = Co-patent firms; 5 = Co-patent firm-institution | … the higher number of firms patents a greater probability to scale at the industrial level, to eventually commercialize, and for government and university innovation efforts to crystallize in patents, and therefore contributed to a higher propensity of women to become inventors (Chatterjee and Ramu, Reference Chatterjee and Ramu2017; Giuri et al., Reference Giuri, Grimaldi, Kochenkova, Munari and Toschi2020; Meng, Reference Meng2018; Murray, Reference Murray2004; Whittington and Smith-Doerr, Reference Whittington and Smith-Doerr2008; Woolley, Reference Woolley2019) |
TechField | Technological field of the patent. 1 = Chemical; 2 = Computer and communication; 3 = Drugs and medical; 4 = Electrical and electronic; 5 = Mechanical and 6 = Others | … the higher distribution of women inventors by technological fields will be differentiated among countries according to the importance of those fields and the advances in science and technology in each case (Cook and Kongcharoen, Reference Cook and Kongcharoen2010; Hunt et al., Reference Hunt, Garant, Herman and Munroe2012; Kahler, Reference Kahler2012; Maldonado Carbajal et al., Reference Maldonado Carbajal, Chávez and de Jesús Peredo2015; Martínez et al., Reference Lax-Martínez, Raffo and Saito2016) |
TechInnScope | Invention scope of each patent. Number of claims as the proxy variable | … the higher the number of claims, the higher is the propensity of women to become inventors (Jensen et al., Reference Jensen, Kovács and Sorenson2018) |
MobIn | International inventor mobility. Dummy variable, where 0 = inventors of the same nationality; 1 = foreign inventors | … the higher mobility favors the spillover of codified and tacit knowledge, and therefore contributes to as higher propensity of women to become inventors (Bianco and Venezia, Reference Bianco and Venezia2019) |
ValuePat | Value of the patent. This variable specifies the number of patent citations made in successive patents. A proxy variable is the number of FwPatCit obtained | … the larger the FwPatCit, which suggests a wider diffusion of new patents and increased importance of new knowledge, the higher is the propensity of women to become inventors (Bransteter, Reference Branstetter2003; Branstetter and Ogura, Reference Branstetter and Ogura2005; Breschi et al., Reference Breschi, Lissoni and Montobbio2005) |
7.3.4 Analysis of Outcomes
According to the results of each model, we have partially verified our hypothesis, with a different pattern in each of the three countries. The independent variables – the stock of prior knowledge, the size of inventor teams, the type of patent holder, technological field, and presence of foreign influence – impact positively on women’s propensity to invent (WmjPropInvij) in a differentiated manner in each country. In some cases, they did not. These results are detailed subsequently and shown in Table 7.5.
Variable | Mexico | Brazil | India |
---|---|---|---|
0.0004** | 0 | ||
SizeRT | 0.020*** | 0.051*** | 0 |
AssigPat | |||
Institution | 0.020*** | ||
Firm | 0.081*** | 0.006 | 0.0442*** |
Individual | 0.104** | ||
TechField | |||
Computer and communication; | -0.004 | -0.023 | 0.03 |
Drugs and medicals | -0.007 | 0.055** | 0.024 |
Electrical and electronic | -0.035 | 0.157*** | 0.008 |
Mechanical | 0.039** | 0.017 | -0.023 |
Others | -0.031 | 0.130*** | 0.019 |
TechInnScope | 0 | 0.0002*** | |
MobInv | 0.140*** | -0.083 | 0.017 |
ValuePat | 0 | 0 | 0.045 |
_cons | 0.046 | -0.073 | -0.05 |
0.236 | 0.163 | 0.477 | |
N | 61 | 299 | 728 |
R2 | 0.67 | 0.76 | 0.68 |
F | 6.89 | 9.14 | 3.06 |
Note: p < 0.01*** p < 0.05** p < 0.010*
Concerning the stock of previous knowledge, has been statistically significant only in Mexico. According to our elasticity estimation (0.012), if the number of BwPatCit increases by 10 percent, the propensity for women to invent grows by 0.12 percent. In the tradition of Griliches (Reference Griliches1990), several authors have used BwPatCit to study knowledge flows and FwPatCit to analyze the invention value (Gay et al., Reference Gay, Latham and Le Bas2008; Lerner and Seru, Reference Lerner and Seru2017, among others). An essential aspect to consider, however, is when it is used as a proxy value for knowledge links among inventors to explore the nature of knowledge flows and the factors affecting these flows (Jaffe and Rassenfosse, Reference Jaffe and de Rassenfosse2017). In this research, we consider BwPatCit as the stock of previous knowledge upon which inventors develop their new ideas. As references to prior technology that has been used or on which current patents build (Hall, Reference Hall, Fagerberg and Mowery2005), BwPatCit involves an R&D effort, which, when increased, makes it possible to include women in inventive activities. The fact that it has positively impacted WmjPropInvij is a reminder of the need to disclose patents, just as they are meant to be.
Relative to SizeRT, there is a positive influence in Mexico and Brazil. When the research team is 10 percent bigger, WmjPropInvij increases 4.9 percent (Mexico) and 10.9 percent (Brazil). Bianco and Venezia (Reference Bianco and Venezia2019: 14) state that “the presence of more members on a team certainly brings more diverse and variegated knowledge and can therefore produce better results.”
Contrary to the importance of institution holders in Mexico and India, firms have a positive influence on WmjPropInvij in both countries (0.08 and 0.04, respectively). Institutions have been positively significant for Mexico as well, but only individual assignees are positively significant in Brazil. The reason for a positive effect is understandable considering the importance of public R&D expenditure in Mexico and India, even though such expenditure remains marginal in Mexico. Women academic inventors are key to understanding their involvement in scientific research – and eventually the discovery of new products and processes that could make it to the productive sphere, depending on the degree of links between firms and institutions. According to Murray (Reference Murray2004: 643), “The first element that the firm may leverage is the academic’s local laboratory network – a network to current and former students and advisors established by the inventor through his laboratory life.”
Although Martínez et al. (Reference Lax-Martínez, Raffo and Saito2016), in their study of women inventors from 182 countries with PCT patents, do not analyze the causal effects of ownership on WmjPropInvij, they have identified that an average of 48 percent of women participate in the academic sector, while only 28 percent are in the business sector. Their findings coincide with previous studies (Whittington and Smith-Doerr, Reference Whittington and Smith-Doerr2008). It is pointed out that China, Brazil, and Spain have higher percentages of PCT patent applications with women inventors in the academic sector (around two-thirds). In particular, Mexico has 69 percent participation in the academic sector and 26 percent in firms (Martínez et al., Reference Lax-Martínez, Raffo and Saito2016). Unlike India, Mexico has few entrepreneurial businesspeople, and technological dependence dominates every sector. Women in India have increased their presence in business activities, and they discuss the challenges that they have to face to reduce inequalities (Chatterjee and Ramu, Reference Chatterjee and Ramu2017). In Brazil, however, the increase in R&D efforts surpasses the inventive activity of institutions toward companies (Maldonado Carbajal et al., Reference Maldonado Carbajal, Chávez and de Jesús Peredo2015).
Regarding the technological field, the mechanical sector is statistically significant for Mexico, while the fields of pharmaceutical and medical, electrical and electronic, and others are statistically significant for Brazil. In India, however, not a single field has an impact on WmjPropInvij. We have confirmed the results of previous research on the positive influence of the pharmaceutical and medical sector in Mexico and Brazil, but we are now modeling each woman inventor and not each patent (Guzmán and Orozco, Reference Guzmán, Orozco and Perrotini-Hernández2011; Maldonado Carbajal et al., Reference Maldonado Carbajal, Chávez and de Jesús Peredo2015). The current study is also connected to the importance achieved by female graduates and researchers in medicine and related disciplines. Our findings coincide with the study by Cook and Kongcharoen (Reference Cook and Kongcharoen2010), where advancement by women in life sciences places them in the realms of innovation and marketing. The involvement of women inventors in different technological fields is one of the topics that have been addressed more in studies, especially with a focus on identification. Some of these studies find that technological fields differ across countries (Martínez et al., Reference Lax-Martínez, Raffo and Saito2016) and are probably associated with the country’s technological specialization, as in certain Latin American countries where chemistry and metallurgy are the main sectors (Sifontes Fernandez and Morales Valera, Reference Sifontes Fernandez and Morales Valera2014). Few studies have thus far analyzed the impact of factors relating to the nature of innovation on the propensity of women to invent, let alone provide analysis based on a micro-level model that considers each woman inventor. Hunt et al. (Reference Hunt, Garant, Herman and Munroe2012) find that to close the gender gaps in patenting, it is essential for the participation of women in physics and engineering to grow. That could increase the GDP by 2.7 percent if we keep in mind GDP growth among countries in the long run and that patents are found among explanatory variables of the country.
In economic literature, mobility has been detected as a factor favorably affecting innovation. In Mexico, we find that the presence of foreign inventors has a positive influence on research teams; when there is a 10 percent increase in foreign inventors, WmjPropInvij grows by 0.5 percent. The results reinforce the finding of Bianco and Venezia (Reference Bianco and Venezia2019: 14) that “the presence of external inventors broadens the scope of the patent, [and] longer working experience of inventors affects technological and market value, whereas inventors who have already patented in the past develop new product architectures, with broader scope and higher scientific value.” The results also confirm consistency with contributions by previous authors, underscoring that openness and experience positively influence the innovative capabilities of teams. In India, female researcher mobility tends to occur outwardly, and knowledge spillovers take place in research centers with other colleagues. The need for such mobility finally finds channels of communication in India.
We cannot, however, confirm the influence of patent value for any country. The fact that the countries studied are emerging may mean their innovations are essentially incremental as they follow leading countries, so they are not as well recognized as industrialized countries yet. Patent value is still low, but it might be interesting to study Indian, Brazilian, and Mexican inventors collaborating on patents in developed countries and identify the contributions of women therein. New technology patented by mixed teams is often cited in the following patents. This suggests that diversity of ideas could lead to the development of patents that are more useful and consequently more successful (Hunt et al., Reference Hunt, Garant, Herman and Munroe2012).
Conclusion and Recommended Policies
Some countries have achieved gender parity in scientific training or are close to doing so. For others, the gap remains wide. Among emerging countries, Brazil, India, and Mexico have made progress in overcoming gender disparities in education, with differences in specializations. Brazil and India stood out for striving to increase R&D spending, thereby helping to incorporate more researchers – among them women – while expanding innovative domestic capacities. Such development is especially notable in India, whose patents are in high technology (Mani, Reference Mani2015).
Analyzing each country separately, we observed different patterns for women inventors in the three countries. We also found that some policies could be furthered through our model’s estimations.
The evidence of factors in Mexico that positively affect WmjPropInvij indicates that policies must be oriented toward fostering diffusion of the technological knowledge codified in patent documents. As team inventors increase the number of BwPatCit, the stock of previous knowledge ( and the propensity of women to join as inventors could go up.Footnote 10 Another recommendation is to increase inventor team size and include more women inventors. Indeed, an increase in innovation in firms and institutions favors WmjPropInvij. As Mexico has specialized in the mechanical sector, one recommendation is to support development and innovation in this area, incorporating more women inventors and thus diminishing gender inequalities. That, nevertheless, does not eliminate the importance of other fields, especially those with greater knowledge intensity. Finally, the presence of foreign researchers in the inventor teams could be suggested as a way of having positive effects on increasing WmjPropInvij.
In Brazil, the results suggest a focus on the following policies: (1) increasing the number of researchers on teams, encouraging women to join; (2) further stimulating individual innovation (surprisingly for this Latin American country); and (3) coinciding with Brazil’s specialization, strengthening patented innovation in the pharmaceutical and medical, electrical and electronic, and sectors in the “others” category.
Finally, in India, the right policies could be directed to improve innovative firms, and therefore patents, and incorporate more women in R&D activities – especially in the pharmaceutical and medical sector, the electrical and electronic sector, and sectors in the “others” category. Encouraging an increase in claims per patent (TechInnScope), which is apparently associated with seeking a broader range of claims, requires not only the talents of men but also women. This requirement differs from the idea that each sex has different creative abilities neurologically. While India is the most backward country in terms of the various aspects of the GII, the country has registered steps forward that make greater inventive activity possible for women and are thus reflected in the dynamism of patent growth, especially those that are more technologically intense. The potential growth and well-being of nations in the world will have to be supported by the merging of cognitive skills and innovation of women and men.
This empirical study focused on a model where independent variables correspond to patent data that characterize innovation in each USPTO patent. However, the results could be strengthened by incorporating individual information from women inventors on their level of education and age, among other characteristics. In future research, we can go deeper with new model proposals.
Introduction
Women are currently underrepresented among patent holders. Studies show that female inventors, in both industry and academia, hold fewer patents, file fewer patent applications, and have their applications more often rejected by the patent office than men do.Footnote 1 As a result, female inventors are less likely to receive patent protection for their innovative efforts or to attract the investment necessary to commercialize their inventions, hindering their success in highly technological fields.Footnote 2
Although a variety of measures are needed fully to resolve the patent gender gap, one possible measure that could help women access protections for their innovations is allowing unregistered patent rights in addition to the existing regime of registered patent rights.Footnote 3 The proposed unregistered rights would extend only to inventions that meet the standard substantive requirements for patentability but would do so without requiring inventors to go through the expensive, complicated, and time-consuming patent examination process. Such unregistered patents would grant exclusive rights to inventions for a limited period of time and only against direct and knowing copying. They nonetheless would provide much-needed protections for female innovators, who face many obstacles in obtaining registered patent rights for their innovative efforts.
8.1 Inequality in Patent Protection Worldwide
Although the numbers vary substantially by country, technology, and sector, the overall percentage of women among patentees and patent applicants remains low worldwide.Footnote 4 The comprehensive study of Patent Cooperation Treaty applications from 151 countries conducted by the World Intellectual Property Organization (WIPO) highlights the significant gender gap in patent protection.Footnote 5 The study found that less than 30 percent of all patent applications listed female inventors, with less than 5 percent listing women as sole inventors.Footnote 6 This gender gap persisted even in fields that otherwise exhibited near-gender parity.Footnote 7 For example, biotechnology and academia generally offer women better opportunitiesFootnote 8 than electrical and mechanical engineering and industry,Footnote 9 but even in bioscience, women are still underrepresented among patent holders.Footnote 10
Similarly, a study the UK Intellectual Property Office conducted using the Worldwide Patent Statistical Database (PATSTAT) and PatBase found that women have constituted less than 2 percent of inventors for most of the twentieth century, rising only to just over 10 percent by 2015.Footnote 11 Importantly, although patents listing female inventors are increasing, this trend has been slow.Footnote 12 Variation between countries in the percentage of female inventors did not correlate with socio-economic indicators such as GDP or the number of women in the labor market.Footnote 13
Organizational context matters as well. Women in hierarchical firms are less likely to patent, for example.Footnote 14 Women are also less likely to work as sole inventorsFootnote 15 and more likely to work in large research groups,Footnote 16 where they often cede their patent rights to colleagues.Footnote 17 Patenting patterns among academics reveal similar trends, with women holding fewer patents than men.Footnote 18 Women in academia instead seem to focus their efforts more on teaching and publishingFootnote 19 and are less likely to pursue commercial opportunities.Footnote 20 When female academics do patent their inventions, on the other hand, it is their male coauthors who often drive the patenting process.Footnote 21
The much lower rate at which women file for patents stems mainly from the cost, complexity, and frequently discriminatory nature of the patent registration and examination process. The overall cost for a twenty-year patent term of protection averages tens of thousands of dollars.Footnote 22 Investing in a patent is also risky, as the sizable costs of application, examination, and maintenance may never be recouped. The value of a patent depends on its successful commercialization, which in turn depends on highly uncertain economic and technological factors. The resulting financial barriers to patenting are especially daunting for women.Footnote 23 Although venture capitalists often fund patent filings, men are much more likely to secure such outside investment.Footnote 24 This perhaps is due partly to biases among venture capitalistsFootnote 25 and partly to the fact that men are more likely to apply for patents and, therefore, to attract investors.Footnote 26
Moreover, patenting requires access to expertise on how best to negotiate the complexity of the application and prosecution process.Footnote 27 Connections with experts and experienced inventors can prove instrumental in both navigating the process and evaluating its risk and potential profitability.Footnote 28 Women typically have fewer of these kinds of social and professional network connections and support.Footnote 29
Furthermore, women are less likely not only to apply for patent protection but also to obtain a patent once they do apply.Footnote 30 Some studies have found that patent applications by women are up to 21 percent less likely to be granted than those by men.Footnote 31 This stems partly from the fact that women tend to file applications in fields in which patents are generally harder to obtain.Footnote 32 Even when controlling for scientific field, however, patent applications by women are still 7 percent less likely to be granted.Footnote 33 In the life sciences, for example, all-female inventive teams are 11 percent less likely to have their applications granted than are all-male teams, despite the prominence of women in the field.Footnote 34 Even when women are granted patents, they typically have more independent claims disallowed and are more likely to have their remaining claims narrowed.Footnote 35 Patent examiners also cite patents granted to women less often.Footnote 36
The lower patent issuance rates among women arise to some extent from the often male-oriented interpretation of patentability doctrines such as the notoriously nebulous PHOSITA (person having ordinary skill in the art) standard, used to measure the equally ambiguous utility and nonobviousness requirements for patentability, among other things.Footnote 37 These disparities likewise stem from biases among patent examiners, who have been shown to grant patents at lower rates when applicants had easily recognizable feminine names.Footnote 38
The costs of the gender gap in patenting are significant. Patent protection can be essential in commercialization, and investors are typically reluctant to invest in inventions that are not patent protected.Footnote 39 Thus, as a consequence of their lesser patent protections, women are less likely to see their inventions developed and commercialized and to recoup their investments in inventing. This patent gender gap can have implications for economic growth and social equality.
8.2 Unregistered Patents
As the previous discussion suggests, truly leveling the playing field for women in technology would necessitate many changes, including changes to the patent system. More consciously, nongendered patentability doctrines and an anonymous application system could help women achieve greater parity and better outcomes. One possible measure that has been overlooked, however, is expanding opportunities for patent protection.
Patent protection is currently unavailable absent registration and examination with a national patent office.Footnote 40 In this way, patents differ from most other intellectual property rights, many of which offer protection to both registered and unregistered creations. Trademarks and design rights, for example, often feature a two-tier structure that offers some minimal protection absent registration but also offers stronger protections for right holders who register their creations.Footnote 41 Similarly, copyright protections often employ a two-tier structure to protect both registered and unregistered works, although many countries do not have a registration system for copyrighted works.Footnote 42
In the case of copyright, protection typically is available from the moment a copyrightable work is created, whether or not it has been registered.Footnote 43 Registration is available in some countries such as the United States, where it creates a presumption of “constructive notice” that a work is copyrighted, thereby assisting in proving infringement.Footnote 44 Trademarks likewise can be protected without registration, albeit only in the geographic area where the mark actually is used in commerce.Footnote 45 To gain nationwide protection and additional remedies, however, owners have to register their marks.Footnote 46 Likewise, both EU and UK law protect unregistered designs against direct copying for a limited duration but are subject to the defense of independent creation;Footnote 47 only registered designs are protected against independent creation.Footnote 48 Registration also gives designs a longer term of protection.Footnote 49
Our proposal for the patent system follows this general structure of a two-tier intellectual property right, offering narrow protections of limited duration for unregistered inventions while retaining the option of the standard twenty-year term of protection for those who submit their inventions for registration and examination. This proposal also can be applied globally through an existing international agreement such as the Agreement on Trade-Related Aspects of Intellectual Property Rights and used to address the global gender gap in patenting.
8.2.1 The Proposed Model
The proposed model would offer inventors a novel form of protection with no need for registration. Inventors who wish to secure full patent protection would still have to register their inventions and undergo an examination process, just as they do today. The central difference between the existing form of registered rights and the proposed form of unregistered rights is the scope and duration of protection afforded under each. The proposed unregistered patents would protect subject inventions for only three years and against only knowing and direct copying. Thus, unlike registered patent rights, these unregistered rights would provide relatively short protections and no protection against independent creation.
Note that the distinction in rights between unregistered and registered patents follows naturally from the rationale behind the registration and examination of traditional patents. Registration has long been seen as providing the public with notice of in rem rights.Footnote 50 Because the proposed unregistered patent system by definition would not make registration and description of patent rights public, it would be inefficient and arguably unfair for potential infringers to be held unknowingly liable for infringement. Those who directly copy an invention, by contrast, obviously would know that it is another’s creation and, therefore, would notice that another person could hold unregistered rights in the invention, despite the lack of registration of those rights.
Moreover, inventions eligible for our proposed unregistered rights still would need to meet the existing patentability requirements of subject matter eligibility,Footnote 51 novelty,Footnote 52 utility,Footnote 53 and nonobviousness.Footnote 54 Only for inventions meeting these traditional substantive standards would unregistered protections become available. Those protections would then automatically arise as soon as the invention becomes available to the public. Public availability would be measured under the same standards used for novelty under current U.S. patent law, including public availability of a description of the invention, public use of the invention, or the invention becoming otherwise available to the public.Footnote 55
Unlike the twenty-year term for a registered patent, however, the duration of an unregistered patent under our proposal would run for only three years from the date the subject invention first became publicly available. Inventors who wish to extend their rights for more than three years would have the option to do so but would have to undergo the usual registration and examination with the applicable patent office, even if their unregistered patent rights had already been successfully enforced in court. Inventors would have to file for such registered rights no more than a year after their unregistered rights attach; inventors who do not file applications for registered rights within a year of acquiring unregistered rights would forfeit registered patent protection altogether, leaving them with only the remaining two years of their unregistered patent rights.
In this way, the proposed unregistered rights regime would comport with what many patent systems already do under their novelty (or statutory bar) provisions. Almost all countries allow inventors to disclose their inventions publicly up to a year before filing their patent applications without anticipating themselves or otherwise being barred from patent eligibility.Footnote 56 The law in the United States, for example, establishes a one-year grace period that allows inventors to disclose their invention publicly before filing, in effect measuring novelty and nonobviousness as of the disclosure date rather than the filing dates.Footnote 57 Our proposal applies this “first to file or to publicly disclose” approach to both registered and unregistered rights holders.Footnote 58 Granted, even under U.S. patent law, patentees cannot sue others for infringement occurring in that first prefiling year the way they would be able to under our proposal. Nonetheless, the effect is that under both systems, an inventor who applies for registered patent rights within a year of publicly disclosing her invention can exclude others until the twenty-first year after that initial prefiling disclosure.
Finally, our proposal would allow inventors only a limited presumption of validity of their unregistered patent rights. In bringing an enforcement action, inventors initially would not need to prove that their inventions meet the standard patentability requirements; instead, the inventors would have to establish only the date their invention became public. They would, however, at all times bear the burden of proving direct copying by the defendant. Once the inventors establish these basic elements of their claim, the defendant would have the right to challenge the validity of the inventors’ unregistered rights by showing that their invention fails to meet one or more of the patentability requirements. Importantly, the defendant would need to rebut the presumed validity of an unregistered patent by mere preponderance of the evidence, unlike the clear and convincing evidence required under U.S. law to invalidate a registered patent.Footnote 59 The lower preponderance of the evidence standard would reflect the fact that no patent office had yet vetted the invention’s patentability and that a court would thus have no need to defer to the patent office’s expertise.Footnote 60 If the proposed unregistered patent rights were found to be valid as well as infringed, the remedies for infringement would include both injunctions and damages.
However, it may seem odd to grant unregistered patents any presumption of validity, given that neither unregistered trademarks nor copyrights enjoy such a presumption. In both trademark and copyright law, owners of unregistered rights bear the burden of proving the validity of their rights.Footnote 61 Shifting the burden to alleged infringers may be more efficient in the patent context, however. The exceedingly rigorous standards for patentability make it relatively easy for defendants to identify prior art references that prove unpatentability, even with regard to registered patents previously examined by a patent office.Footnote 62 Allowing a defendant to proceed immediately to its invalidity argument may thus lead to faster and less costly disposition of infringement proceedings.
8.2.2 The Costs and Benefits of Unregistered Patents for Gender Equality
Two critical questions our proposal presents are whether unregistered patent rights would in fact help female inventors and, if so, whether the benefits would outweigh the costs of creating such a system. As noted earlier, simply decreasing the barriers women face in obtaining patent protections would go far in helping them to capitalize on their innovations and to participate in technological industries generally. While our proposal would increase the number of patent rights overall, the proposed unregistered rights would be carefully cabined to avoid creating excessive drag on future innovation. Our proposal is thus tailored to ease many of the disadvantages women face in protecting their inventions while avoiding undue burdens on technological progress overall.
First, an unregistered patent regime would enable inventors to obtain patent protection without the oft-prohibitive costs of registration, examination, and maintenance. Women would thus have easier access to the patent system despite frequent difficulty in securing funding. Similarly, unregistered patent rights under the proposed regime would be automatic and therefore would not favor those who have access to a network and other support for guidance on the patenting process. This also will help women and others who lack such connections.
Of course, inventors would have to bear the costs of enforcing their patents, including any litigation costs. The policing costs for infringement of unregistered patents would be lower than those for registered patents, however, as monitoring for only purposeful copying is presumably cheaper than monitoring for both knowing and “innocent” infringement, such as independent design. More importantly, enforcement costs would have to be born only ex post, after direct copying has been detected, and the value of the invention thereby demonstrated. That value – along with the protection the invention would automatically enjoy under unregistered patent rights – could in turn help attract investors. As with any other invention, venture capital and other investment funds can be used for defending rights in the invention through litigation or other means, filing for registered rights and paying for subsequent maintenance fees, and commercialization and licensing generally.
All the same, investors may be hesitant to invest even in innovations valuable enough to have been copied if they lack registered patent rights. The proposed unregistered rights would not enjoy the cachet of vetting by a patent office or the presumption of validity rebuttable only by clear and convincing evidence that comes with such vetting. The proposed rights also would last for only three years. As a result, unregistered patents might not have the same signaling effect in attracting investment.
Investing in unregistered patents may not be significantly riskier than investing in registered patents, however. Investing in technological innovation is always risky, as even registered patents have only speculative economic value and probabilistic legal validity.Footnote 63 Under our proposal, outside investors also would know that even unregistered inventions would have at least some protection, compared to their current lack of protection. Such protection could be converted to registered protection if still within the one-year grace period. Moreover, many technologies do not need the full twenty years of registered protection. The three years of protection under our proposed unregistered rights could be more than enough to recoup investments in industries such as computer software and electronics.Footnote 64
A second and equally important benefit is that automatic, unregistered patent rights would allow women to bypass many of the biases inherent in the patent system. The most obvious are patent examiner biases against patent applicants with recognizably feminine names. Less obvious are workplace biases leading to less support for women in filing for patent rights. Automatic rights would make these biases less important in barring access to patent protection.
That being said, unregistered rights holders seeking to enforce their rights may need to rely on the court system, which itself is subject to bias. Allowing courts to recognize unregistered intellectual property rights nonetheless could be more equitable than forcing inventors to go through the patent registration and examination process or forgo their rights altogether. Like investors, courts may be more apt to recognize the value of an invention once others have affirmatively copied it and therefore be more inclined to protect the invention against appropriation. Courts also may be more inclined to look to broader economic and social values to evaluate patent rights with more focus on equity than a patent office would.Footnote 65 Administrative agencies such as patent offices, by contrast, lack many of the procedural justice and due process constraints to which courts are subject.Footnote 66 Members of the judiciary may be less subject to the biases affecting the science, technology, engineering, and mathematics (STEM) fields from which patent offices typically draw their examiners.Footnote 67 While administrative agency decisions are subject to judicial review, this review often tends to be somewhat deferential.Footnote 68 Thus, using courts to recognize unregistered intellectual property rights would at least provide an alternative venue for women and other inventors to protect their interests.Footnote 69
What are the costs and pitfalls of the proposed new regime of unregistered patent rights, however? The fact that no jurisdiction has ever provided unregistered, automatic patent rights reflects a discomfort with the idea. Many have argued that excessive patent rights would impose much greater burdens on future innovation and creation than would similarly excessive grants of copyright, trademark, design, and trade secret rights. The breadth and robustness of patent rights mean that granting patents too lavishly or easily could lead to hold-outs, patent thickets,Footnote 70 patent “trolling,”Footnote 71 and other phenomena that wastefully deter other inventors from valuable research. Technologies in which development and commercialization are inherently cumulative and complementary are particularly prone to these issues.Footnote 72
In contrast to other forms of intellectual property right, patent law also has very few safety valves to protect inventors from opportunistic claims of infringement that might over-deter them from building on existing technologies.Footnote 73 Unlike copyright and trade secrecy,Footnote 74 patent law has no independent creation defense to infringement liability,Footnote 75 nor does patent law have the fair use defense seen in copyright and trademark law.Footnote 76 Even the experimental use exception available in the patent systems in many countries applies only in limited circumstances, such as regulatory approval of pharmaceuticals or use of medical treatment methods.Footnote 77 Although prior user rights also are common in many countries, they are limited to only those using an invention commercially before the patentee filed its patent application.Footnote 78
Instead, the patent system relies on its comparatively stringent limitations to reduce both the number of patents and breadth of patent rights.Footnote 79 Patent law has far more limited terms than copyright, trademark, design, or trade secret law,Footnote 80 as well as novelty and statutory bar provisions that force inventors to file their patent applications or lose their eligibility to patent.Footnote 81 These limitations serve to release inventions into the public domain as soon as possible. Unconditional patent rights granted without examination or even registration appear at first glance to completely dismantle patent law’s carefully calculated system for cabining patent law’s otherwise robust rights of exclusivity.Footnote 82
The unregistered rights proposed here would be very closely limited to avoid unduly burdening overall innovation, however. Unlike registered patent rights, the proposed unregistered rights would be subject to a number of safety valves to protect downstream innovation. In addition to applying all of the standard patentability requirements, the proposed unregistered patent regime would protect only against copying, not independent creation, and for only three years from the date the subject invention first became publicly available. These constraints establish significant safeguards against placing undue burdens on others.
Some might argue that unregistered patent rights would exacerbate the innovation bottlenecks created by “bad” or “weak” patents – that is, patents of suspect validity.Footnote 83 As with registered patents, however, the proposed unregistered rights would be subject to judicial review for validity. Our proposal in this way invokes the same efficiencies of various proposed “soft-look” registration approaches. Under these latter proposals, patent applications would undergo only minimal administrative examination prior to issuance, and only those that were important enough to give rise later to litigation would then face more substantive judicial examination.Footnote 84 Such judicial review ex post, only when needed, is more resource-efficient than the current system of administratively examining all patent applications ex ante. In addition, judicial review ex post would have the benefit of not only the defendants’ field-related expertise and motivation to invalidate patents but also a presumption of validity rebuttable by a mere preponderance of the evidence.Footnote 85 Registration-only patents rest on the idea that the high costs of eliminating bad patents administratively ex ante outweigh the social costs of waiting to eliminate those patents judicially ex post.Footnote 86 Similarly, the unregistered patent regime proposed here rests on the idea that the cost of patent registration and examination and how it sidelines women and other inventors outweighs the cost of potentially bad unregistered patents.Footnote 87
Regardless of whether patents are “good” or “bad,” simply adding to the overall volume of patent rights still could impose a drag on innovation. Technology may be more incremental, cumulative, or complementary than expressive works, trademarks, or trade secrets,Footnote 88 and inventive concepts are often more difficult to design around.Footnote 89 The fear of litigation and the uncertainty of proving invalidity therefore often causes competitors to fear innovating in heavily patented technologies.Footnote 90 This in terrorem effect can over-deter competitors from innovating near or around others’ patents, particularly given the patent system’s lack of independent creation, fair use, and other defenses available in other forms of intellectual property right.Footnote 91 In this way excessive patent rights may be more likely than other intellectual property rights to over-deter future innovation.
The proposed unregistered patent regime would provide a number of safe harbors to address this problem, the most obvious of which would be for independent creation. Cumulative or complementary innovation might still be unduly deterred from copying needed components, however. So unlike the current patent regime in the United States, the proposed regime would therefore not impose treble damages for knowing infringement, especially if only for experimental use. Perhaps most importantly, the proposed unregistered rights would be very limited in duration; other innovators could thus just wait three years to copy an invention with impunity. The limited duration and scope of these unregistered rights would greatly lower the risk of patent trolling, nuisance suits, patent thickets, and holdouts. The proposed unregistered rights would thus broaden access to patent protection without either increasing or prolonging them.
As an unregistered regime, our proposed patent rights could undermine the public-notice function of patent registration, however, thereby increasing the informational costs of establishing freedom to operate within a particular technological space. The breadth of patent rights and the relatively limited defenses to patent infringement call for clear public notice of what constitutes such infringement. Indeed, this is one of the foremost values of registering patent rights and perhaps the primary reason that, in contrast to copyright, trademark, and trade secret law, unregistered rights in patent law never emerged. The patent registration system already falls short of this public-notice ideal, as the clearance costs of identifying and interpreting all the patents potentially relevant to one’s project are often astronomical.Footnote 92 Injecting unregistered, unrecorded rights into the existing system could exacerbate these costs exponentially. Under the proposed unregistered rights system, by contrast, infringers would have demonstrated actual notice of the protected invention by virtue of copying it. Public notice, therefore, would not be an issue. Downstream inventors would have to determine the date the invention became publicly available, of course, which could be costly, but this cost is already part of the existing registered rights system.Footnote 93
One final objection could be that the proposed unregistered regime would undermine the peripheral-claiming system.Footnote 94 In the United States, peripheral-claiming mandates that registered patents include claims “particularly pointing out and distinctly claiming” the subject invention.Footnote 95 Peripheral claiming is designed to delineate a patent’s boundaries as precisely as possible to give the public detailed notice. An unregistered patent system, by contrast, would give the public only the inventions themselves as indicators of their patent boundaries in a way resembling the now-obsolete central-claiming system. Under the central-claiming system in the United States, courts could only compare an allegedly infringing device with the patented invention, without the benefit of claims or other express boundaries, often leading to surprise and uncertainty.Footnote 96 Reversion to a central-claiming-like system may thus seem inefficient,Footnote 97 but in practice the modern-day peripheral-claiming system introduces its own inefficiencies.Footnote 98 Peripheral claiming has led to the notoriously difficult problems of construing patent claims and widespread complaints about the uncertainty to which they lead.Footnote 99 Indeed, some commentators have even called for a return to the central-claiming system as a more equitable and flexible approach to patenting.Footnote 100
Lastly, none of what is proposed here should be taken as urging the abolition of existing registered patent systems. Without a doubt, registration and examination of patents yield many benefits, including greater public notice and independently vetted patentability. Registration and examination come at a high cost for inventors, but for many inventors – and their employers or investors – this cost will not pose an obstacle to patenting inventions perceived to be worthwhile.Footnote 101
For all its benefits, however, the high cost of the patent application and examination process falls disparately on women and other disadvantaged inventors. Predicting the commercial value of an invention is immensely difficult, and deciding whether to invest in the process of applying for patent protection, even if only provisionally, is a gamble.Footnote 102 To assume that investors and employers evaluate inventions from a purely rational, rent-maximizing perspective is undoubtedly inaccurate, especially for inventions by female inventors. As a result, a disproportionately large number of female inventors are disenfranchised by the costs and complexities of patent registration and examination and their inherent biases.Footnote 103 Adding an unregistered regime such as the one proposed here would help ameliorate the gender gap in patent rights without creating undue burdens on innovation.Footnote 104 The benefits of unregistered patent protection, even if for a relatively brief period, could be quite significant and thus outweigh the potential risks of such a regime.
Conclusion
The stark gender gap in patenting is unlikely to disappear in the near future due partly to the ex ante registration currently required for patent protection. The patent registration and examination process is risky, expensive, time-consuming, and complex and poses significant barriers for many inventors, particularly women. Excluding women and other similarly disadvantaged inventors from patent protections is detrimental to both equality and economic growth and stifles overall innovation.
A novel regime offering inventors automatic, unregistered patent rights for even a limited period of time could help make the patent system more inclusive and egalitarian by avoiding the cost and risk of the patent registration and examination process. The version of unregistered patent rights proposed here would be carefully narrowed to allow protection only against knowing and direct copying to maintain the appropriate balance between inventors and the public and between the need to protect existing inventions and the need to allow future innovation. Naturally, this proposal cannot achieve perfect gender equality on its own but would be a meaningful step in the right direction.
Introduction
In principle, the patent system is equally accessible to all inventors.Footnote 1 Big corporations, small start-ups, and individuals all have their patent applications scrutinized by the same patent office. If granted, their patents receive the same protection, duration, and remedies.Footnote 2 This equality principle serves an important purpose. It guarantees a neutral position of patent law and pledges equal opportunity to all inventions to win in the marketplace.Footnote 3 Theoretically, equality serves another vital objective: to ensure diversity of inventions.Footnote 4 It does so by giving new and small inventors the same treatment as experienced and well-known inventors and not granting an advantage to inventors who may be perceived as having a higher chance of success.
However, the patent system is not equally accessible to all. Some actors are more likely than others to file for patents and have their patents granted.Footnote 5 Thus, patents are more handily granted to men over women, whites over minorities, and big companies over start-up firms.Footnote 6 Granted, this reality is largely a product of the broader phenomenon of inequality in other spaces, such as academia and entrepreneurship, rather than a feature of the patent system per se.Footnote 7 Yet, in this chapter, I propose that a decentralized design of the patent system, particularly the patent record, can mitigate this inequality. Although this chapter focuses on the patent system in the United States, much of the analysis can apply to patent systems worldwide.
The extant patent system in the United States is centralized almost from end to end. The U.S. Patent and Trademark Office (PTO) is responsible for examining patent applications, publishing the granted patents, and increasingly managing postexamination proceedings.Footnote 8 For a number of reasons, the centralization of all of these functions within the PTO has adverse effects on equality. First, the current system involves high entry costs and requires particular know-how that benefits repeat players and highly capitalized inventors. Second, centralization requires a single agency to examine the entire pool of patent applications. The immense quantity of patent applications compels examiners to use decision shortcuts and proxies. It should come as no surprise that these shortcuts work in favor of big and repeat players and to the disadvantage of traditionally underrepresented groups in the patent system. Third, the current system grants many unmerited patents, mainly to big corporations.Footnote 9 These patents create barriers to entry for newcomers. Finally, the current system features a limited patent record – a static registry that holds only basic information about inventions. Acquiring updated and relevant information regarding the technological, legal, or commercial status of inventions is costly. The cost barrier places underfunded inventors at a disadvantage and at risk of falling victim to patent trolls.Footnote 10
In a recent work, I considered an idea to decentralize the patent system.Footnote 11 In particular, I proposed to open the public record to input by market and state actors during the examination process and throughout the lifetime of the patent, using blockchain or other technology. During the examination period, third parties could submit prior art and weigh in on obviousness. Following the patent issuance, patentees would be able to register updates to the patent, the underlying invention, or products that rely on it. They will also be able to offer licenses via smart contracts or otherwise. The court system would add to the record cases that pertain to the patent. That article argued that decentralization could improve the productivity and effectiveness of the patent system and accelerate the introduction of inventions to the market.Footnote 12
In this chapter, I explore the possibility that decentralization could boost equality in the system by removing access barriers and turning the patent record into an effective platform to learn about inventions and commercialize them affordably. The first part of this chapter discusses the principle of equality in patent law in theory and practice. The second part explores the distributive problems that the current system entails and the future improvements for equality with the shift to a decentralized architecture. A short conclusion ensues.
9.1 Equal Access to the Patent System
In theory, equal access is a key feature of the patent system.Footnote 13 With few exceptions, patent law abides by a strict nondiscrimination principle.Footnote 14 Neither the examination criteria nor the rights attached to patents grant favorable treatment to inventors based on their experience, size, financial status, or the likelihood that the invention would be valid as a patent, manufactured or sold.Footnote 15
Nondiscrimination is a crucial principle. It ensures that all inventors, including small entities and members of marginalized communities, have an equal chance to protect their inventions. Consequently, under the assumption that patents incentivize invention, the equality principle augments everyone’s incentives to invent.Footnote 16 Beyond its distributive value, the equality promise is designed to increase innovation gains by diversifying the inventive base.Footnote 17 A broad pool of inventors can yield a diversity of products, markets, and processes because different founders see different innovation needs.Footnote 18 In particular, inventors from underrepresented groups can tackle issues that sit in the blind spots of others or address well-known problems with more inclusive solutions.Footnote 19 Access of small technology companies to the patent system bears particular importance.Footnote 20 Small entities are both disproportionately innovative and crucially dependent on patents to secure funding and market entry.Footnote 21 Yet small entities are less likely to make use of the patent system.Footnote 22 Guaranteeing the access of small entities to the patent system thus best furthers the objective of the patent system to promote innovation.Footnote 23
Despite the significance of the equality principle, equal access to the patent system remains largely theoretical. As Peter Lee put it, on the ground, “the U.S. patent system has become highly corporatized and concentrated.”Footnote 24 Indeed, most patents are issued to large corporations,Footnote 25 with some industries featuring extreme concentration.Footnote 26 Inequality overwhelmingly persists among individual inventors as well. Women are issued around 20 percent of patents, and only 8 percent of patents feature women as the primary inventor.Footnote 27 The rate of minority inventorship is somewhat under-researched,Footnote 28 but indications are that this rate is very low, particularly among Blacks.Footnote 29 Generally, as Dan Burk and Mark Lemley observe, “even those [patents] granted to individuals and small corporations are often incubated in large research universities.”Footnote 30
Several reasons for the unequal distribution of patents have nothing to do with the patent system per se. Social, economic, and other pressures force some groups out of the innovation economy and other inventive spaces.Footnote 31 Yet part of the problem, and perhaps partial solutions, may lie in issues pertaining to the patent system. The next part discusses such issues and explores the possibility that decentralizing the patent system can improve equality.
9.2 A Decentralized Patent System
Currently, the patent system features a rigorously centralized structure. The PTO examines patent applications, publishes the granted patents to the public, and increasingly manages postexamination proceedings.Footnote 32 While surely unintended, the centralized structure of the patent system jeopardizes equality in three main ways. First, a central examination entity involves high entry costs and requires particular know-how, including institutional knowledge. High entry costs work to the detriment of new and under-resourced inventors.Footnote 33 Second, centralization congests the system and induces patent examiners to use decision shortcuts and proxies that favor strong and repeat players. Third, the current system over-grants patents, mainly to big corporations, and these patents form barriers to entry for newcomers. Finally, the current system features an inadequate patent record that lacks vital information about inventions and frustrates the use of that record as a source for consultation in the invention ecosystem. Acquiring such information elsewhere is cost-prohibitive for small inventors, but operating without it exposes them to market and legal risks. The thesis advanced in this chapter is that decentralizing some of the PTO’s functions can effectively address these concerns and boost equality.
9.2.1 The Problems in a Centralized Patent Regime
The most apparent distributive concern in the patent system involves high entry costs.Footnote 34 Patent prosecution has become increasingly expensive, partially due to the prolonged processes at the PTO, which compound legal and other expenses, and partly because the complexity of these processes requires expensive professionals to navigate them.Footnote 35 Patent prosecution may be even costlier for small inventors, who, among other things, do not have in-house patent attorneys.Footnote 36
The financial barrier to the patent system prompted Congress to lower the filing fees for small firms and micro-entities through the Leahy-Smith America Invents Act.Footnote 37 This statute also entitles small entities and independent and unrepresented inventors to technical, pro bono, and pro se assistance.Footnote 38 Despite such measures, inequality seems to worsen with time.Footnote 39 The reduced fees have not moved the needle, most likely because these fees are negligible in the overall expenses of patent prosecution. Also, the rate of abandoned applications is more than twofold for pro se applicants than for represented applicants.Footnote 40
High entry costs confine small companies and individuals more than well-resourced corporations. The most obvious result of costly patent prosecution is that small inventors give up on patents. While avoiding patenting may be rational for small entities,Footnote 41 it exposes their inventions to copying and may yield an inferior position in the marketplace.Footnote 42 Indeed, the rise of trade secrets protection provides alternative, cheaper protection that often suits better the financial capabilities, focus, and business of small entities and individual inventors.Footnote 43 Yet, if patents exist as a tool to generate an incentive to create, then the exclusion of certain groups from patenting adversely affects their incentives to invent.Footnote 44 But high costs can be even more devastating; small inventors depend on investments, but investors are reluctant to fund patent prosecution and often delay investments until patents are secured.Footnote 45 Consequently, inventors may be forced to relinquish their ventures altogether or settle for lower valuations than their invention is worth.Footnote 46
Consider now the backlog of the patent system. Currently, the PTO examines all patent applications alone, generating severe delays.Footnote 47 A high pendency rate has a differential effect on the market. For small players, pendency shrinks the duration and thus the value of patent protection.Footnote 48 Big players, in contrast, can make lemonade out of the long application process lemon. Such players can file numerous broad patents, including for embryonic ideas that did not go through full development or feasibility testing. They can then strategically use the “patent pending” status of their applications to persuade others to back away from their asserted territory during the long examination period, even if the application would eventually be denied or reduced in scope.Footnote 49
The backlog at the PTO potentially affects the incentives of examiners as well.Footnote 50 While probably unintended, proxies for validity – such as inventors’ names, former acquaintance with the representing agent, and institutional affiliation – are almost inevitable considering the severe examination backlog at the PTO and the time constraints imposed on examiners.Footnote 51 These biases are compounded by the notorious public choice problems at the PTO that further the interests of large corporate patent filers and other repeat players at the expense of smaller inventors.Footnote 52 Institutional capture easily penetrates into the individual level of examiners, who may be contemplating their next career step as patent prosecutors or major patent holders.Footnote 53
The third challenge that the extant regime poses to equality concerns the prevalence of low-quality patents. The issue of patent quality has long troubled patent scholars.Footnote 54 From the equality prism, the concern is that the PTO is biased toward granting patents, de facto disadvantaging small inventors who file fewer patents and must penetrate a dense screen of patents to function. Remarkably, Alberto Galasso and Mark Schankerman find that innovation by small firms is often triggered by invalidating large firms’ patents, suggesting that those patents thwart innovative efforts.Footnote 55
A key reason for the over-grant bias is that the PTO has limited access to the information and proficiency required to disqualify patents and insufficient time to acquire such information and proficiency.Footnote 56 Indeed, patent applications must be granted absent reasons to deny them.Footnote 57 But assessing applications’ novelty and nonobviousness typically requires highly contextual, fact-intensive, industry-specific information (to disqualify patents based on a lack of novelty) and very specific expertise (to deny patents based on their obviousness).Footnote 58 Such knowledge is naturally dispersed in society rather than concentrated in one agency.Footnote 59
What is more, the incentives of the PTO are set up to make it an ineffective gatekeeper for patent quality. The PTO is largely self-funded by patentees’ fees, generating an institutional disincentive to reject patents.Footnote 60 Studies even indicate that the PTO grants more patents in areas where fees are higher.Footnote 61 To avoid time-consuming disputes, a swamped PTO is also better off granting borderline patents, particularly to applicants who will likely challenge rejections.Footnote 62
Finally, another way that a centralized patent system contributes to inequality concerns information problems in the patent record. Naturally, a PTO-operated patent record can only include information that the PTO possesses at the time of publication.Footnote 63 But such a record is gravely deficient. The current record lacks information about the background science of the invention and any developments since it was filed. Neither does it include information relating to litigations or transactions, such as available licenses and prices.Footnote 64 However, its immense value, including robust information in the patent record, is unrealistic under a centralized model. The PTO has no access to the information that is most relevant to make the record useful for the inventive community. Much of this information is also dynamic and is changing over time. A central agency cannot realistically be responsible for collecting and registering updates to the record.
An inhibited record has distributive effects. Highly capitalized inventors can overcome information deficiencies by investing in other methods to acquire information, which is cost-prohibitive for small players.Footnote 65 But running an underinformed business involves market and legal risks. The main risk concerns exposure to “patent trolls” – nonpracticing entities who accumulate vast portfolios of dubious patents and use them for strike suits against innocent infringers.Footnote 66
These problems did not go unnoticed, and Congress, courts, and the PTO have attempted to tackle some of them.Footnote 67 Yet, high costs, congestion, information problems, and capture are inherent to a centralized PTO and will render any solution that maintains the current structure partial at best. Next, I explore whether decentralizing some PTO functions can provide a better way forward.
9.2.2 Can Decentralization Provide a Solution?
Imagine that the power to write information into the record was not exclusive to the PTO but distributed among state and market actors. The patent record would be built on a blockchain or another platform that enables the autonomous sharing of information by authorized parties.Footnote 68 Such parties would be able, and in some cases obliged, to update the record with relevant information during the examination process and throughout the duration of the patent. Under a decentralized model, third parties and scientists could submit prior art and weigh in on obviousness for the use of examiners during the examination period. After patents are issued, patentees could include in the record commercial information, such as licensing and pricing information, and even plug-in smart contracts. Courts would list decisions and outstanding cases that pertain to the patents. These updates would inform the patent community whether patent claims are in question, whether the patent holder is prone to litigation, and other useful information that is costly to obtain under the extant regime. The PTO would be responsible for reviewing the patent record and fixing errors.
In my previous work, I tackled the practical aspects of this proposal and the related concerns.Footnote 69 The main concern revolves around whether there are adequate incentives for market players to contribute to a decentralized record. This is a critical point. After all, a functioning patent record is a public good. Without private incentives to participate in it, the record would be unable to achieve its goals.
The first answer to that concern is that some contributions to the decentralized record would be automatic or mandatory and would be independent of the participants’ goodwill. For example, patent applications would be fully published, with automatic references to similar materials on the record;Footnote 70 information about litigations would be added by courts as created, and patentees would be obliged to maintain the accuracy of the information on available licenses. This information would already be a substantial improvement over the current regime.
Consider now the incentives for market players to participate in the system voluntarily. It is relatively easy to see the incentives for patentees to add licensing information to the record. Adding such information would enable patentees to commercialize their inventions without much effort. Some patentees, such as big pharmaceutical companies, may prefer to continue licensing their patents individually.Footnote 71 Yet, this functionality can be extremely valuable for small companies or individual patentees that do not have resources to negotiate each license individually, as well as for owners of vast patent portfolios who can build a cost-effective licensing model.
How about the interests of third parties to contribute information to the record? During the examination process, firms would be incentivized to question the validity of patents that would curb their free operations. From their point of view, this mechanism would be a cheaper, easier way to battle a patent than postreview examination, let alone litigation.Footnote 72 The concern may be that such parties would be too eager to provide invalidating information in a way that would jeopardize the efficiency of the system. My previous work addressed this concern.Footnote 73
Other contributors, such as academics or scientists, may be motivated to participate by other considerations, such as reputation or exposure to new information in their field. Volunteer reviewers are the regular case in many academic frameworks, such as reviews of submissions to scientific journals and grants. It would thus not be surprising to see scientists weigh in on an invention in their field.Footnote 74 At the postexamination stage, technology firms and scientists would be incentivized to update and consult the record as an affordable mechanism to avoid infringements, as well as to learn of new inventions and form collaborations.
Decentralizing the patent record could transform the record from a static database that includes basic filing information that is barely used in the industry into an up-to-date platform that forms a central tool in the innovation economy. This strategy can potentially improve equality in the patent system in three main ways. First, it would tackle distributive concerns in the patent examination process. Second, it would protect small inventors from information problems. Third, it would boost the commercialization of patents, particularly for small inventors.
Consider first how decentralization can cure distributive harms in the examination process. As discussed, the patent prosecution process is done ex parte under the current regime. However, market actors hold superior information, such as knowledge of instances where the invention was offered for sale or disclosed publicly.Footnote 75 The PTO alone is entrusted with raising arguments to reject the patent or narrow down its claims.Footnote 76 It performs this task in a suboptimal manner, under time and knowledge constraints.Footnote 77 Decentralization would make invalidating information handily available to examiners and reduce the rate of low-quality patents, which form entry barriers for small players. A broader information basis would also save examiners search time and attenuate their need to rely on proxies, which have discriminatory effects.
Even greater equality can be found in the postexamination period. An updated patent record would provide a cost-effective means to gain useful technological, transactional, and legal information throughout the duration of the patents. Making robust information available to small players levels the playing field between them and big players, rendering it less likely that entrenched firms could learn about patents and new players in their field more than start-up ventures.Footnote 78 Tackling information problems would also enable innovators to avoid infringements, thus battling patent strike suits, which can devastate small entities.
Finally, decentralization of the record would introduce a platform to commercialize inventions globally. Patentees could list licensing options, potential use cases, and prices on the patent record. Once the record contains such robust transactional information, cooperation with commercial bodies to bring the invention to the market is much more likely.Footnote 79 A distributed registry could also enable functionality not existing today, such as plugging in smart contracts and allowing third parties to act on available licenses automatically.Footnote 80 This functionality can be extremely valuable for small companies or individual patentees that do not have resources to negotiate each license individually.
The benefit of this policy is twofold. First and foremost, the dynamic record can further the goal of the patent system – to accelerate the path of innovation to the market.Footnote 81 Second, improved commercialization would have a dynamic effect. It could spur innovation and patenting because patents would become an effective reward for inventors.Footnote 82
Conclusion
The technological ability to decentralize the power to write into the patent record presents intriguing opportunities to generate a patent system that is more inclusive and diverse and to address the pressing issues of equality in the patent system.
An intriguing question can arise in this context: Considering the pledged efficiency of a blockchain-based database for inventions, why has the market not stepped in to create such a registration itself? The answer to this question is that some trading platforms between inventors and licensees exist worldwide.Footnote 83 Yet, without regulation, these platforms are underdeveloped. The first reason is that the market does not internalize the distributive concerns discussed in this chapter, and therefore market-based registries may not develop as efficiently as they should. In this vein, a second issue with market initiatives concerns information and collective action problems. Too many actors from various industries and jurisdictions need to join together to generate an effective patent record on the free market.
Yet the most fundamental reason is that it is simply more efficient to decentralize the state-run patent registry than to create a new registry, especially when distributive concerns are considered. The patent registry is a legal creature. It is set by the law and operates under the controlling statutes in each country. Thus, market initiatives cannot replace the existing record, but they can rather duplicate the platform and add to it. This reality harms efficiency and generates distributive harm by adding another registry and multiplying registration costs. At the end of the day, while a market-based scheme has its advantages, it would be more efficient to channel the resources and efforts that are already being made for patent registration to a registry that is valuable to the market.
Introduction
As the “highest normative act of the state,”Footnote 1 a constitution is a unique national product that defines a set of commitments relating to preserving a country’s “shared collective existence.”Footnote 2 Constitutions serve as the basic scripts that enable countries and their citizens to be bound by values and principles that define their social and political construction. The recent “rise of world constitutionalism”Footnote 3 resulted in fundamental changes to the unique constitutional culture of many countries, irrespective of their ability to enforce these changes. The inclusion of intellectual property as a socio-economic right in the formal constitutions of many countries of the world provides a striking example of these changes and questions the role of constitutions as “uniquely national products.”Footnote 4 Similar to other “legal norms that are exported and imported across borders,”Footnote 5 intellectual property laws have been transplanted into the systems of many countries without making necessary changes to align them with the local culture and legal environment. This includes constitutionalizing intellectual property as a basic socio-economic right as early as 1801, as well as ordinary intellectual property legislation.
The process of constitutionalizing intellectual property rights highlights absurdities associated with unequal and asymmetrical power relations within the politics of intellectual property. The findings in this chapter expose the inherent conflicts between international legal harmonization and unbalanced trade powers in intellectual property constitutionalism and how these conflicts affect the most defining document of a nation – the constitution. These findings confirm the “naïve assumption that ideological adherence in constitutions has automatic and immediate effects,”Footnote 6 and introduce a new layer to contemporary discourses on the design processes of effective intellectual property regimes. Various ideological motivations explain the reasons behind constitutionalizing intellectual property as a fundamental socio-economic right. These motivations impact conceptions of constitutional autonomy and the preservation of global cultural diversity and question the intuitive assumption that the constitutional protection of a particular right will secure protection on the ground. Recent empirical research has dealt with this proposition and finds that “the poorer a country’s human rights record, the greater the number of rights that its constitution tends to contain.”Footnote 7 This research also finds that there is a negative correlation between constitutionally recognized rights and the level of actual rights protection.Footnote 8
The first section demonstrates the gap between the mere existence of a constitutional equality provision and its application on the ground and presents the three core objectives of the chapter. The second section focuses on intellectual property and examines how inequality is a defining concept in intellectual property that can be articulated in many forms. The third section takes intellectual property and inequality one step further, discussing intellectual property constitutionalism and highlighting the lack of scholarly attention to intellectual property in formal constitutions and the implications. The fourth section demonstrates the incorrect assumption that adding intellectual property rights to a constitution will provide better protection for these rights and highlights how this assumption is predominantly a result of global political inequality and asymmetrical power relations. This section first evaluates the ideological motivations of countries to adopt intellectual property as a socio-economic right in their formal constitutions. It then introduces and empirically analyzes the results of the data collected. This chapter concludes by discussing the inequality-related consequences of unbalanced intellectual property constitutional commitments.
10.1 Three Objectives
Catharine MacKinnon applied the claim that a country’s inclusion of a particular fundamental right in its formal constitution does not project its enforceability. Her article examined the inclusion of the concept of gender equality in formal constitutions and compared measures of “sex equality” in constitutions.Footnote 9 Of the two countries with the highest international ranking for equality of the sexes, Norway has no equality provision in its constitution, while Australia has no formal written bill of rights. In contrast, many countries with the lowest equality rankings in the world have strongly worded provisions guaranteeing equality in general and gender equality in particular. Malawi has one of the most detailed constitutional provisions for equality of the sexes in the world, guaranteeing equal protection for women, invalidating laws that discriminate based on gender, and requiring legislation to be passed to eliminate discriminatory customs and practices, including “sexual abuse, harassment, and violence”Footnote 10 as well as “discrimination at work and in property.”Footnote 11 Malawi sits at 153rd in sex equality among the 169 nations ranked.Footnote 12 Indeed, many states have anchored the term “equality” in their formal constitutions. In 2020, Jody Heymann, Aleta Sprague, and Amy Ruab mapped equality clauses in world constitutions.Footnote 13 The study examined 193 U.N. member states and found that 20 percent of the constitutions generally protect equality without explicitly mentioning inequality concerning a particular category.Footnote 14 Irrespective of the frequent appearance of “equality” in constitutions, the authors reminded us how far we still have to go in order to practically and adequately protect equality.
Another example demonstrating the gap between the mere existence of a constitutional equality provision and its application on the ground is the constitution of South Africa. That constitution begins with a commitment that “[t]he Republic of South Africa is one, sovereign, democratic state founded on the following values: … Human dignity, the achievement of equality and the advancement of human rights and freedoms.”Footnote 15 Despite the explicit and detailed defense of equality in the South African Constitution, it appears that, in practice, there exist significant wage gaps based on both raceFootnote 16 and gender.Footnote 17 South Africa is ranked 149 out of 150 in the Gini World IndexFootnote 18 and is rated 92 out of 153 in economic participation and opportunity in the Global Gender Gap Report 2020.Footnote 19
The same conflict was recently examined in relation to the freedoms of expression, movement, association and assembly, religion,Footnote 20 private property,Footnote 21 torture,Footnote 22 and health.Footnote 23 An example of the right to health is the constitution of Afghanistan, which commits the State to “provide free preventive health care and treatment of diseases as well as medical facilities to all citizens in accordance with the law.”Footnote 24 And yet, despite this commitment, Afghanistan has one of the lowest life expectancies in the world.Footnote 25 These examples raise complex questions that are critical in the constitutional context, such as the following: Why would countries adopt constitutional commitments that cannot be enforced? What are the ideological motivations for countries to adopt socio-economic rights that conflict with and are unsuitable to their political and social realities? This chapter addresses these questions.
Intellectual property displays a similarly misleading assumption and raises the same questions. This chapter examines this assumption and provides theoretical and empirical support to this claim. It has three main objectives. First, the chapter shows how asymmetrical power relations dictate which countries will include intellectual property as a constitutional guarantee. Second, it discusses how these unequal power relations nurture a wrongful assumption according to which intellectual property as a constitutional guarantee secures better protection in practice. For example, Venezuela, which has one of the most detailed intellectual property provisions in its constitution, was ranked last among 128 nations in the 2016 International Property Rights Index.Footnote 26 The text from the Constitution of Venezuela reads as follows:
Cultural creation is free. This freedom includes the right to invest in, produce and disseminate the creative, scientific, technical and humanistic work, as well as legal protection of the author’s rights in his works. The State recognizes and protects intellectual property rights in scientific, literary and artistic works, inventions, innovations, trade names, patents, trademarks and slogans, in accordance with the conditions and exceptions established by law and the international treaties executed and ratified by the Republic in this field.Footnote 27
Haiti has the oldest provision situating intellectual property as a fundamental human right in the world, which dates back to 1801.Footnote 28 Despite redrafting its working constitution in 2012,Footnote 29 Haiti is ranked three places before last.Footnote 30 To quote MacKinnon, “often the reasons for the gap between guarantee and reality lie elsewhere than in constitutions.”Footnote 31
Third, this chapter invites the constitutional aspect into scholarship that heavily criticizes the lack of balance between countries in global intellectual property affairs, where weaker countries are coerced into accepting the standards of dominant countries. One of the main expressions of this criticism revolves around the unilateral acts that certain countries inflict upon other countries and the suitability of international intellectual property standards and their enforcement in certain parts of the world. As this chapter shows, coercing countries to constitutionalizing intellectual property rights drives many adopting countries into severe violation of these rights and to consequently appear on lists of countries that do not adequately protect intellectual property. This chapter aims to add a layer to this discourse by examining how asymmetrical power relations do not leave constitutions unaffected.
10.2 Intellectual Property and Inequality
Intellectual property systems increase the benefits and reward the owners or investors of an idea, product, or process gained from their activity.Footnote 32 Inequality is a concept embedded within contemporary intellectual property discourses and explains many of the system’s deficiencies. The following three examples highlight this claim. First, inequality in intellectual property explains limits on access to knowledge and their effect on income equality and local stability.Footnote 33 Because these systems have been transformed into a “hegemonic battleground,”Footnote 34 rather than preserving their role as “an indispensable tool of modern economic management,”Footnote 35 they feed power asymmetries that dictate who owns and controls products of knowledge. In this regard, Rebecca Eisenberg and Richard Nelson claim:
Patent rights motivate private firms to invest in research, but they also introduce significant inefficiencies that may inhibit future research. Patents permit innovators to restrict access to, and thus raise prices for, their inventions. Although sometimes necessary to allow firms to recover R&D [research and development] costs and thus profit from innovation, such pricing is inefficient, because it excludes users who would be willing to pay enough to cover marginal production costs but not the additional patent premium.Footnote 36
Another empirical study found that increasing patent breadth leads to economic growth by increasing R&D but also simultaneously increases income inequality by increasing the rate of return on assets. The researchers also examined the macroeconomic effects of international intellectual property rights. They found that strengthening patent protection in any given country increases global economic growth but also worsens income inequality in both developed and developing countries.Footnote 37 Similarly, the World Social Report 2020, which addresses complex issues of inequality,Footnote 38 states that technological changes are driving wage and income inequality upward and most highly skilled workers away. The report further refers to intellectual property, saying that it must become one of the main focal points of the international community, alongside transnational crimes and international trade, to reduce inequalities in an interconnected world.Footnote 39 States must agree on “a more flexible approach to intellectual property rights that can provide adequate patent protection, while enabling and facilitating access to technological enhancements within and among countries.”Footnote 40
Second, inequality in intellectual property results in social exclusion and explains the rapid growth in counterfeit goods. This is another way to demonstrate unequal power relations between weak and strong private members of society. Intellectual property laws act as laws of social exclusion, building cultural fences around goods of high social symbolism. Consumers react to this exclusion by massively using counterfeit goods, thereby creating and financially feeding a market where violations of intellectual property rights flourish. The consumption of these goods is a “strategic response to the general cultural struggle of acceptance and recognition in the context of class divided property relations.”Footnote 41 In other words, using these counterfeit goods is a “social reaction to inequality and marginalization … the counterfeit trade thrives in the context of organized, historically rooted, structural inequality.”Footnote 42
Third, on the international level, inequality persists and defines differences between weak and strong countries – for example, in access to medicine.Footnote 43 In this area, inequalities are magnified by intellectual property regulations.Footnote 44 The third example is best explained using the explanatory narratives Peter Yu provides for the developing countries’ accession to the Agreement on Trade-Related Aspects of Intellectual Property Rights (TRIPS Agreement). The bargain narrative provides that this agreement is a product of a compromise between developing and developed countries. While developed countries received stronger protection for intellectual property rights and a reduction in restrictions against foreign direct investment, developing countries obtained lower tariffs on textiles and agriculture as well as protection against unilateral sanctions imposed by the United States and other developed countries via the mandatory dispute settlement process.Footnote 45 This narrative, however, does not give enough weight to the fact that power relations between developed and developing countries at the time of the negotiations were far from equal. The coercion narrative declares that “the TRIPs Agreement is considered an unfair trade document that developed countries imposed on their less developed counterparts. The Agreement is ‘coercive,’ ‘imperialistic,’ and does not take into consideration the goals and interests of less developed countries.”Footnote 46 An additional narrative suggests that developing countries did not fully understand the importance and implications of intellectual property protection, which has led to an agreement that does not reflect their interests.Footnote 47
These narratives highlight how unequal power relations impact the development of international and national intellectual property laws in developing and politically weaker countries.Footnote 48 In times of health crisis, highlighted since the COVID-19 pandemic began to control the life of people in every corner of the world, inequality in access to medicine will have a devastating effect on these countries. According to the U.N. Development Programme, the crisis threatens to devastate developing country economies and ramp up inequality disproportionately.Footnote 49 Interestingly, the constitution of only one country in the world explicitly mentions access to medicine as part of its clause protecting intellectual property as a fundamental socio-economic right.Footnote 50 Article 41 of the Bolivian Constitution of 2009 provides:
I. The State shall guarantee the access of the population to medicines.
II. The State shall prioritize generic medicines through the promotion of their domestic production and, if need be, shall decide to import them.
III. The right to access medicine shall not be restricted by intellectual property rights and commercial rights, and it contemplates quality standards and first generation medicines.
Access to medicine is not the only area of conflict between developed and developing countries. Yu notes that both domestic and international digital copyright enforcement measures pose threats to human rights such as free speech and free press.Footnote 51 He explains how favoring rights holders over the public in copyright feeds inequality:
[I]n an age where digital literacy is highly important, users who cannot exercise their right to freedom of opinion and expression are unlikely to be able to function effectively in the digital environment. It is therefore no surprise that UN bodies and developing country governments have expressed grave concern that the growing global digital divide could cause many individuals and developing countries to lose out on the unprecedented opportunities generated by the information revolution. Such impeded access would make it difficult for individuals to fully realize themselves and to develop … human capabilities.Footnote 52
What needs to be done, in the words of Laurence Helfer, is to “reorient a legal discourse that privileged the private (and often corporate) ownership of IP [intellectual property] over human rights and other societal values.”Footnote 53 Inequality and power asymmetries, as defining defects of global intellectual property developments, have brought many scholars, such as Graeme Dinwoodie and Rochelle Dreyfuss, to declare that “the North had the South over a barrel.”Footnote 54 Daniel Benoliel, in his recent inquiry into patents and economic growth, further explains the North–South dichotomy. His approach raises concerns relating to asymmetrical power relations within global intellectual property clubs of states:
Growing evidence reveals differences between developing countries in their ability to make use of [intellectual property rights] as a tool for fostering domestic innovation. All these pieces of evidence are startling when placed against the backdrop of a traditional World Bank-led and rather inflexible North/South country-group dichotomy, or some variant thereof. Such an innovation policy setting continually highlights the asymmetries between Northern countries, which are deemed to generate innovative products and technologies, and Southern countries, which are generally thought to consume them.Footnote 55
In sum, inequality in intellectual property can be demonstrated in many forms. It can be demonstrated through the restriction on access to knowledge, through social exclusion that fosters gaps between weak and strong private members of society – and, of course, through fostering such gaps between the countries of the world at the international level. As mentioned at the beginning, this chapter takes the discussion further and shows how inequality permeates formal constitutions through intellectual property protection clauses. The next section, therefore, lays down the fundamental discussion on intellectual property and constitution and highlights the absence of scholarly debate on intellectual property in formal constitutions.
10.3 Intellectual Property Constitutionalism
Contemporary scholarship on the relationship between intellectual property and constitutionalism has focused on the way scholars have addressed intellectual property–related constitutional clauses, such as the U.S. constitutional clause that empowers Congress “[t]o promote the Progress of Science and useful Arts, by securing for limited Times to Authors and Inventors the exclusive Right to their respective Writings and Discoveries.”Footnote 56 This focus has left outside the discourse a two-century phenomenon, in which countries protect intellectual property as a socio-economic constitutional right alongside the rights to health, work, education, housing, and private property.Footnote 57 The presence of intellectual property in bills of rights has much to tell about the nature of the right, its constitutional status in different countries and geographical regions, and the constitutional and cultural ideologies underlying the decision to adopt the right.Footnote 58 Such presence further highlights the benefits of learning from other systems and allows a better viewpoint on the image of intellectual property as a system of rules that protects cultural diversity and the universality of human rights.
The first time a constitution included intellectual property as a basic right, as opposed to an empowerment clause, was the 1801 Constitution of Haiti declaring the right to benefit from inventions in rural machinery.Footnote 59 According to Article 70 of that constitution, “The law provides for awards to inventors of rural machines, or for the preservation of the exclusive ownership of their discoveries.” Two of the youngest countries in the world, South Sudan and Kosovo, have made intellectual property part of their constitutions. The 2011 constitution of the former includes “intellectual property rights” in the list of “national powers.”Footnote 60 Article 46 deals with the right to own property and its limits while stating that “intellectual property is protected by law.”Footnote 61 Only a handful of scholars in the field of intellectual property or comparative constitutionalism referred to this phenomenon – intellectual property as part of a list of fundamental socio-economic rights in a formal constitution. These inquiries only briefly mentioned intellectual property.Footnote 62
The wisdom behind adopting intellectual property rights in formal constitutional documents is embedded in the presumptions that constitutional laws “send a message about the priority of particular policies”Footnote 63 and that “constitutional commitments are potentially credible ones and send a strong signal to potential buyers and investors.”Footnote 64 Although the idea of written constitutions has spread to virtually every corner of the world, scholars are divided over the strength of constitutional text as a source for learning about constitutional practice. On the one hand, “constitutions are gaining recognition as enforceable legal documents, rather than mere declarations.”Footnote 65 On the other hand, the gap between constitutional text and its applicability raises questions about the role and impact of the text. Horowitz defines this gap as one between “law in books” and “law in action,” explaining as follows: “[T]he gap between a formal constitution and the practice under its aegis is perhaps greater than with ordinary law. Because constitutions often perform symbolic or aspirational functions that have little relationship to the ways in which constitutional law actually operates.”Footnote 66 Moreover, some constitutions are just “sham.”Footnote 67 For example, they could bear “no relationship to reality.”Footnote 68
David Law and Mila Versteeg explain this tension by drawing a distinction between de jure, written, codified, or formal constitutions (“large-C” Constitutions) on the one hand and de facto, unwritten, uncodified, or informal constitutions (“small-c” constitutions) on the other.Footnote 69 The latter attracted much scholarly debate, while the former has much less debate even though it represents an “act of making reasoned, explicit, commitments in written form.”Footnote 70 A focus on formal constitutions has its limits. Certainly, “not all that is constitutional is written, and not all that is written is constitutional.”Footnote 71 However, “the text pays extraordinary dividends both in terms of analytic leverage and in understanding change in the broader constitutional order.”Footnote 72 For certain countries, the choice to constitutionally codify intellectual property as a basic right projects their commitment toward certain goals in pursuing the common good and highlights their will to become members of the international community. As this chapter will show, this choice sometimes violates norms of equality and enforces cultural hegemony.
10.4 Inequality and Intellectual Property Constitutionalism
After discussing and illustrating inequality in intellectual property and how it is articulated in formal constitutions, this chapter shows the asymmetrical motivations of countries in adopting intellectual property rights in their constitutions. This section shows that, in reality, adding intellectual property rights to a constitution does not necessarily provide better protection to these rights, in contrast to the intuitive assumption that the constitutional protection of a particular right will secure protection on the ground. This section further highlights how this assumption is predominantly a result of global political inequality and asymmetrical power relations. It also shows that this assumption often stimulates constitutional templates unsuitable for the local culture or the countries’ ability to apply these templates locally. This section is divided into two subsections. The first subsection evaluates the ideological motivations of countries to adopt intellectual property as a socio-economic right in their formal constitutions, and the second subsection introduces and empirically analyzes the results of the data collected that support the main claim of this chapter. The findings undoubtedly show that when countries adopt intellectual property rights in their constitutions, sometimes due to asymmetrical power relations, it does not assure protection on the ground.
10.4.1 Asymmetrical Motivations
Constitutional ideas diffuse across borders, systems, and contexts.Footnote 73 David Strang defines diffusion as “the process by which the prior adoption of a trait or practice in a population alters the probability of adoption for the remaining non-adopters.”Footnote 74 In their study of the diffusion of 108 rights across 188 countries in sixty-one years, Benedikt Goderis and Mila Versteeg found evidence of diffusion to particular groups of countries. For example, countries with a common aid donor or a common colonizer suggest that constitutions are affected by coercive pressures from aid donors and former colonizers.Footnote 75 Diffusion can also be found among countries that compete for foreign capitalFootnote 76 or aim to be acculturated into the constitutional norms of world culture.Footnote 77 In these situations, unequal power relations dictate the content and structure of many norms that found their way into constitutions, regardless of ideological preferences that aim to protect cultural diversity and local legal history. When intellectual property is at stake, these diffusion channels exhibit how unequal power relations result in countries adding to their formal constitutions rights and duties that they cannot protect.
Various pathways define foreign influences and mechanisms of rights diffusion in constitutional design. The common mechanisms employed are coercion, learning, competition, and acculturation.Footnote 78 The logic behind competition suggests that states strategically imitate foreign constitutions in order to attract foreign capital. Competition is the rivalry between two or more states for material benefits.Footnote 79 Thus, countries act strategically in order to attract foreign capital, design a set of rules, and establish institutions that signal to investors and buyers that the local market can accommodate their interests, limit economic risks, and provide stability. Constitutional documents and lists of fundamental rights provide one of the ultimate sources of good signals to alleviate foreign investors’ concerns. Contemporaneous observers have found that a high level of protection of basic human rights renders countries more attractive to foreign investment.Footnote 80 Investors believe that “regimes with strong human rights records are typically stable ones”Footnote 81 and that public reception will be better if their company gains a reputation that promotes fair trade, does not engage child labor, or builds where basic income is unavailable. Thus, when governments offer a strong and detailed list of rights in a constitution, they believe it “may attract economic benefits.”Footnote 82 Property and intellectual property as constitutional human rights are important to foreign investors. In other words, when a state constitutionalizes intellectual property rights in its highest formal legal script, it invites investors to view its commitment to their rights.
Another example of how constitutional ideas diffuse across the border is the “learning” process. Learning means that “countries borrow each other’s constitutional provisions because the constitutional choices of others have altered their preexisting beliefs: they adopt certain arrangements only when they are convinced that these will be beneficial.”Footnote 83 Learning raises interesting issues with regard to intellectual property laws. Countries are open to learning from foreign sources, mainly because “the new global obligations from the treatment of intellectual property are transmitted from the international to the national level.”Footnote 84 Intellectual property rights
have gained increased prominence on the international economic agenda, rich and poor countries alike have responded by reforming their copyright, patent and trademark regimes, introducing new legislation, and creating new administrative and judicial institutions to facilitate the enforcement of these rights. In so doing, most countries have brought their [intellectual property right] systems into conformity with – and at times exceeded – the standards required by TRIPs.Footnote 85
Ruth Okediji further reminded us how these processes affect weaker countries:
Progressive harmonization of international IP law has continued in various fora, exacerbating historical and continuing burdens on the economic prospects of developing and least-developed countries. In particular, multilateral, regional, and bilateral trade agreements have assumed a crucial role in the creation of new international IP norms, with even stronger requirements and fewer safeguards for public welfare interests.Footnote 86
The above reflects how “states respond to cultural forces”Footnote 87 and how, in doing so, they often emulate foreign constitutional templates irrespective of their content, unsuitable dialectics to the local culture, or even their ability to apply them locally. This diffusion mechanism is defined as acculturation – denoting, as Ryan Goodman and Derek Jinks explain, “the general process of adopting the beliefs and behavioral patterns of the surrounding culture.”Footnote 88 Acculturation is different from coercion or competition because it explains how states act in order to reap social benefits. The logic behind acculturation is premised on organizational sociology, implying that organizations adopt models “not because of their functional utility but because of their legitimacy and the social relationships they represent.”Footnote 89 Acculturation brings states to sign international human rights agreements and adopt environmental policies and other trade treaties without intending to comply with their requirements.Footnote 90 For example, as discussed earlier, the number of constitutions that include provisions on gender equality is increasing. However, as MacKinnon has found, the existence of such a provision is disconnected from its practical applicability.Footnote 91 What states achieve through acculturation is an option to signal to domestic and international audiences that they value integration in world society and comply with cultural norms. Acculturation has been a defining component in contemporary discourse on intellectual property protection for indigenous cultures and native communitiesFootnote 92 and on the tension between preserving ancient languages and cultural assimilation.Footnote 93 Acculturation in these ways has impacted biodiversity, cultural diversity,Footnote 94 as well as individual acceptance of the effects of acculturation.Footnote 95
Many countries, rather than engaging in deliberate processes of adopting foreign constitutional norms and textual choices, are coerced into applying values alien to their national identity. Coercion sets aside the constitutional autonomy of a country and its cultural and legal histories.Footnote 96 Under this logic, “weaker states will converge upon the models provided by stronger states.”Footnote 97 Powerful countries often pursue coercion unilaterally to overcome resistance to international treaties,Footnote 98 respect international norms, and join multilateral institutions. However, coercion can also be used as a mechanism to assist countries in nation-building.Footnote 99
Coercion is not an alien concept in contemporary intellectual property discourse. From a multilateral perspective, the TRIPS Agreement has been at the forefront of critiques. The primary complaint is that “there were elements of coercion and questionable trade-offs may have been made between market access for commodities and intellectual property protection.”Footnote 100 The aggressive imposition of intellectual property norms on developing countries has become associated with concepts such as “recolonization”Footnote 101 and economic imperialism.Footnote 102 From a unilateral perspective, coercion has become a matter of trade policy in intellectual property. Lack of intellectual property protection risks economic isolation and unilateral acts such as economic sanctions and placement on lists of counterfeiting countries. The U.S. Trade Representative’s Special 301 ReportFootnote 103 is an example where a government empowers trade representatives to unilaterally test the level of intellectual property protection in other countries. Another example is the European Union’s annual Report on the Protection and Enforcement of Intellectual Property Rights in Third Countries. In its 2020 Report, the European Commission has remarked that one of the main objectives of the report is to “inform right holders, in particular small and medium-sized enterprises, about potential risks to their [intellectual property rights] when engaging in business activities in certain third countries and thus to allow them to design business strategies and operations to protect the value of their intangibles.”Footnote 104
The motivations of countries to include intellectual property in their constitutional bills of rights affect the structure of intellectual property constitutional clauses. Such clauses are sometimes shaped as a result of external interests or the influence of strong elites, as these clauses may “bear the imprint of the powerful.”Footnote 105 These imprints, as discussed earlier, disturb constitutional cultures that countries aim to preserve. These imprints project a desired and unequal cultural hegemony that conflicts with the legal history and political autonomy of constitutional regimes and affects the actual protection these constitutions can afford to adopt on the ground.
10.4.2 Empirical Results
A comprehensive and original dataset was created to provide modest empirical support to the main claim of this chapter. The findings show how asymmetrical power relations may bring countries to constitutionalize intellectual property protection. In reality, however, constitutionalization cannot guarantee protection on the ground – and, in the case of developing countries, this guarantees the opposite. The dataset covers all constitutional provisions since 1801 that protect intellectual property as a fundamental right. Compiling the dataset involved a range of methodological choices. A choice has been made to focus on formal, written constitutions.Footnote 106 A search has been conducted in numerous databases using keywords pertaining to intellectual property rights.Footnote 107 The findings were cross-referenced with the WIPO Lex database constructed by the World Intellectual Property Organization (WIPO),Footnote 108 the Comparative Constitutions Project,Footnote 109 Constitution Finder,Footnote 110 Oxford Constitutions of the World,Footnote 111 HeinOnline, and Constitutions of Nations.Footnote 112 The data includes information gathered from sources such as the U.S. Trade Representative, which publishes an annual report on intellectual property protection in designated countries.Footnote 113 Two indices were used for the purpose of evaluating the level of de facto intellectual property protection given by the relevant country: the Intellectual Property Rights Index constructed by the Property Rights Alliance (IPR)Footnote 114 and the U.S. Chamber International Intellectual Property Index (GIPC).Footnote 115 It is important to mention again that the data collected for this chapter deals with intellectual property as a fundamental right in constitutional provisions; it does not thoroughly evaluate provisions referring to intellectual property as a legislative empowerment clause. The dataset is updated to January 2017.
As Figure 10.1 shows, the number of countries adopting intellectual property as a fundamental constitutional right has risen. Rapid growth can be seen since 1974 when Sweden adopted intellectual property rights in its formal constitution. Since then, fifty-one countries have followed suit. Haiti was the first country to adopt intellectual property as a fundamental constitutional right in 1801,Footnote 116 and Nepal is the most recent country to have adopted such a provision in 2015. Between 1895 and 1973, only nine countries adopted an intellectual property clause. Colonial histories determined the structure of the constitutional design, and states in Central and South America were the first to adopt an intellectual property clause as a fundamental right in the nineteenth century after Portugal’s adoption of such a clause in 1826. Since the early twentieth century, including intellectual property in bills of rights has become more common among countries. As presented later, the major growth occurred during the last two decades of the twentieth century, shortly after Sweden adopted such a provision in its formal constitution in 1974. Another interesting insight is that many countries that adopted intellectual property as a fundamental constitutional right during that period were developing countries. There are currently seventy-eight countries with a clause protecting intellectual property as a fundamental constitutional right.
Countries refer to intellectual property in their constitution in two ways. First, they adopt an authoritative/empowerment clause – namely, a commitment vested in the state to legislate and regulate in the field. An example of such a clause is the U.S. Constitution, which empowers Congress “[t]o promote the Progress of Science and useful Arts,” as discussed at the beginning of the third section. Second, and more substantively, countries treat the right to own and protect intellectual property as a fundamental socio-economic right and make it part of a given bill of rights.
Some countries refer to intellectual property in both ways. As illustrated in Figure 10.2, twenty-two countries (thirteen of which are developing countries) adopted only an authoritative/empowerment clause;Footnote 117 sixty-five countries (fifty-one of which are developing countries) adopted a substantive clause;Footnote 118 and fourteen (all of which are developing countries) adopted an authoritative as well as a substantive clause.Footnote 119 It can be assumed that the status of a country as developed or developing will impact the way the country adopts such a clause.
Including intellectual property protection in constitutional bills of rights does not guarantee enforcement of these rights on the ground. That is, the mere existence of the right in a constitution can sometimes amount to a false signal: “False can be detected by a conspicuous absence of real enforcement mechanisms.”Footnote 120 Applied to the present argument, the adoption of intellectual property clauses sends a false signal if it lacks the possibility of enforcement. This section offers a modest empirical answer to this assumption. It explores the relations between the scope of protection given in a constitution (as measured by the textual ranking index created for this chapter)Footnote 121 and the level of protection given de facto to intellectual property in the applicable country (as measured by two available comparative data indices commonly used in the literature).Footnote 122 Table 10.1 provides the score of intellectual property clauses received, which were then applied to the data gathered from the indices:
Where the constitutional clause | Score |
---|---|
Explicitly provides “IP shall be protected” and specifically mentions all three main IP branches/elements (author/copyright, inventor/patent/invention, trademark) as well as additional principles such as moral rights | 9 |
Explicitly provides “IP shall be protected” and specifically mentions all three main IP branches/elements (author/copyright, inventor/patent/invention, trademark) (including when the clause’s text provides “and other rights”) | 8 |
Explicitly provides “IP shall be protected” and specifically mentions two of the three main IP branches/elements (author/copyright, inventor/patent/invention, trademark) | 7 |
Explicitly provides “IP shall be protected” and specifically mentions one of the three main IP branches/elements (author/copyright, inventor/patent/invention, trademark) | 6 |
Explicitly provides “IP shall be protected” | 5 |
Does not explicitly mention IP but refers to three additional branches/elements (author/copyright, inventor/patent/invention, trademark) | 4 |
Does not explicitly mention IP but refers to two of the three additional branches/elements (author/copyright, inventor/patent/invention, trademark) | 3 |
Does not explicitly mention IP but refers to one of the three additional branches/elements (author/copyright, inventor/patent/invention, trademark) | 2 |
Provides weak reference to intellectual property | 1 |
Analysis of the textual ranking, alongside the ranking of the state in the two indices examined, reveals a paradoxical reality: The more a constitution expands the scope of the protection by explicitly specifying the main branches of intellectual property rights (e.g., copyright, patents, and trademarks) in the text of the constitution and makes efforts to encompass different intellectual property doctrines and principles (e.g., moral rights) and rights holders (e.g., indigenous people), the less intellectual property protection is given de facto (in the manner the indices capture the latter). For example, Venezuela, a country with a broad constitutional language for de jure protection of intellectual property rights,Footnote 123 was given a maximum textual ranking of 9. Venezuela is also the country with the minimal overall GIPC score, at 6.88 out of 35. Similarly, Azerbaijan, which specifically includes in its constitutional language protection for “copyright, patent rights and other rights for intellectual property” as well as safeguarding “the right for intellectual property,”Footnote 124 achieved almost the maximum textual ranking score (8), but minimal de facto overall IPR score at 2.8 out of 10. Egypt, a country that provides constitutional protection to “all types of intellectual property rights in all fields,”Footnote 125 scored a similar textual ranking of 8 and low de facto intellectual property indices scores (overall IPR score of 4.4 and overall GIPC score of 9.4 out of 35). In contrast, the textual ranking score of Sweden, a leading nation in intellectual property de facto protection, is only 2 even though it has a GIPC overall score of 30.99 and overall IPR score of 8.2.
These findings uncover the apparent paradox concerning the constitutional protection of intellectual property rights, where countries with strong de facto protection of intellectual property rights do not offer broad explicit protection of those rights in their formal constitutions. The majority of the IPR and GIPC scores – Singapore, Switzerland, France, Belgium, Denmark, the Netherlands, Finland, Japan, Germany, the United Kingdom, and the United States (except Sweden) – do not refer to intellectual property as a fundamental socio-economic right in their constitutions. The geographical spread of textual ranking worldwide, illustrated in Figure 10.3, explains the almost inevitable pattern: Many countries with the highest score in the Textual Ranking Index are developing countries.
As Figure 10.4 illustrates, the textual ranking of developing countries (4.431) is, on average, higher than those of developed countries (2.929). This is, of course, not surprising, given that most countries that adopted a substantive clause in their constitutions are developing countries, as Figure 10.2 shows. Figure 10.4, therefore, emphasizes this through a more detailed explanation. These findings lend credence to the conflicting motivations of countries to adopt intellectual property as a fundamental constitutional right. Figure 10.4 confirms that regimes pay lip service or send false signals to appease the international community, certain powerful states, and potential foreign investors without an ability to honor these rights or the ability to enforce them due to various reasons such as political unrest and economic instability.
Conclusion
Constitutions have protected intellectual property as a socio-economic right for over two centuries. To date, this phenomenon has been absent from the scholarly discourse. This chapter provided theoretical and empirical support to the conflicting motivations of countries to adopt such a right and challenges the claim that protecting intellectual property in a constitution guarantees better protection on the ground. The case of intellectual property rights constitutionalism provides evidence for the argument that the “poorest nations by definition lack the resources to honor the kinds of positive socio-economic rights that have grown increasingly popular in recent years.”Footnote 126 This chapter highlights how global political inequality dictates what rights appear in the constitutions of certain countries and demonstrates the neglected value of constitutional intellectual property rights as an exemplar of the paradoxical consequences introduced by processes of global constitutionalism. Imposing a duty on countries to protect intellectual property rights in their constitution ignores, in many cases, the cultural history and social needs of these countries, leaving them unable to meet their constitutional commitments. One of the main consequences of this process is widening the distance between de jure and de facto protection of constitutional rights.Footnote 127