Hostname: page-component-586b7cd67f-dlnhk Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-11-24T20:37:28.344Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

The impact of market integration on arranged marriages in Matlab, Bangladesh

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  12 December 2022

S.B. Schaffnit*
Affiliation:
Pennsylvania State University, State College, PA, USA
A. E. Page
Affiliation:
London School of Hygiene and Tropical Medicine, London, UK
R. Lynch
Affiliation:
Pennsylvania State University, State College, PA, USA
L. Spake
Affiliation:
University of Otago, Dunedin, New Zealand Binghamton University, Binghamton, NY, USA
R. Sear
Affiliation:
London School of Hygiene and Tropical Medicine, London, UK
R. Sosis
Affiliation:
University of Connecticut, Storrs, CT, USA
J. Shaver
Affiliation:
University of Otago, Dunedin, New Zealand
N. Alam
Affiliation:
International Centre for Diarrheal Disease Research, Dhaka, Bangladesh
M.C. Towner
Affiliation:
Pennsylvania State University, State College, PA, USA Oklahoma State University, Stillwater, OK, USA
M. K. Shenk*
Affiliation:
Pennsylvania State University, State College, PA, USA
*
*Corresponding authors. Emails: [email protected], [email protected]
*Corresponding authors. Emails: [email protected], [email protected]

Abstract

Success in marriage markets has lasting impacts on women's wellbeing. By arranging marriages, parents exert financial and social powers to influence spouse characteristics and ensure optimal marriages. While arranging marriages is a major focus of parental investment, marriage decisions are also a source of conflict between parents and daughters in which parents often have more power. The process of market integration may alter parental investment strategies, however, increasing children's bargaining power and reducing parents’ influence over children's marriage decisions. We use data from a market integrating region of Bangladesh to (a) describe temporal changes in marriage types, (b) identify which women enter arranged marriages and (c) determine how market integration affects patterns of arranged marriage. Most women's marriages were arranged, with love marriages more recent. We found few predictors of who entered arranged vs. love marriages, and family-level market integration did not predict marriage type at the individual level. However, based on descriptive findings, and findings relating women's and fathers’ education to groom characteristics, we argue that at the society-level market integration has opened a novel path in which daughters use their own status, gained via parental investments, to facilitate good marriages under conditions of reduced parental assistance or control.

Type
Research Article
Creative Commons
Creative Common License - CCCreative Common License - BY
This is an Open Access article, distributed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution licence (http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/), which permits unrestricted re-use, distribution and reproduction, provided the original article is properly cited.
Copyright
Copyright © The Author(s), 2022. Published by Cambridge University Press

Social media summary: Market integration leads to a rise in love marriages in Bangladesh. Daughters rely less on parents’ involvement, use own status to facilitate marriages.

Introduction

A successful marriage is one that is both optimally timed and joins suitable partners. Success on the marriage market has long-lasting implications for the fitness of women and their future children as played out through their health and socioeconomic status (Shenk, Reference Shenk2004, Reference Shenk2005, Reference Shenk2007; Shenk & Scelza, Reference Shenk and Scelza2012; Boone, Reference Boone1986; Kaplan, Reference Kaplan1996; Kramer & Lancaster, Reference Kramer and Lancaster2010; Santhya, Reference Santhya2011; Schaffnit, Hassan et al., Reference Schaffnit, Urassa and Lawson2019; Shenk, Towner et al., Reference Shenk, Kaplan and Hooper2016; Apostolou, Reference Apostolou2010). Parents therefore invest heavily in facilitating advantageous unions for their children by using their resources or social connections to secure spouses who will provide desirable outcomes for their child, other children and the wider family. Parents also directly invest in their children to increase their desirability on the marriage market by, for example, saving for or negotiating financial transfers at the time of marriage (e.g. bride wealth or dowry) and/or investing in their children's education. Given the importance of marriage market outcomes for children and the unique position parents have to arrange advantageous matches, it is perhaps unsurprising that arranged marriages, i.e. marriages of children negotiated by parents and/or extended kin networks, are common across a majority of human societies (e.g. Shenk, Reference Shenk, Shackelford and Weekes-Shackelford2017; Apostolou, Reference Apostolou2007, Reference Apostolou2010; Shenk, Towner et al., Reference Shenk, Kaplan and Hooper2016; Walker et al., Reference Walker, Hill, Flinn and Ellsworth2011; Murdock, Reference Murdock1949; Berghe, Reference Berghe1979).

The behavioural ecology of arranged marriage

Although arranged marriage is common, parents' desire and ability to arrange children's marriages varies by socioecology (Apostolou, Reference Apostolou2010, Reference Apostolou2011; Shenk, Towner et al., Reference Shenk, Kaplan and Hooper2016) and children's characteristics. For example, arranged marriages are most common in societies where wealth is heritable and/or transferred at marriage, and where family alliances play key roles in a family's economic or political importance (Shenk, Reference Shenk, Shackelford and Weekes-Shackelford2017; Coontz, Reference Coontz2006; Lévi-Strauss, Reference Lévi-Strauss1949). As such, while present in foraging and horticultural populations, arranged marriage practices are much more common in agropastoralist societies (Apostolou, Reference Apostolou2010), where parents have a monopoly on heritable resources (e.g. land or animals) and are able to use their accumulated wealth and status through marriage negotiations or marriage payments to secure spouses for their children.

Patterns of arranged marriage are also gendered – daughters are more likely to experience arranged marriages than sons – owing to power imbalances between sexes, both in the parent–child and husband–wife dyads, and practical considerations. Women generally marry at younger ages compared with men, who often marry later, which is likely both a reflection and cause of their relative lack of power in arranging their own marriages. On the other hand, men are more likely to earn their own income, inherit from their parents (or inherit a larger share than their sisters), and otherwise control their own resources, and are thus more likely to arrange marriages for themselves through discussion with a potential bride's parents and/or family (Broude & Greene, Reference Broude and Greene1983; Agey et al., Reference Agey, Morris, Chandry and Gaulin2021; Apostolou, Reference Apostolou2007, Reference Apostolou2010; Shenk, Reference Shenk, Shackelford and Weekes-Shackelford2017). On a practical level within patrilocal societies, parents are generally more meticulous and involved in choosing a spouse for their daughters than sons because women leave home at marriage and the choice of spouse has a profound effect on the future life of the daughter and her children (e.g. Apostolou, Reference Apostolou2010; Shenk, Reference Shenk2007); in contrast, a woman who marries a son will have a less consequential effect on the socioeconomic situation of the family she joins. For these reasons, as our paper focuses on a patrilocal context, we specifically focus on arranged marriages for women.

While parents’ participation in facilitating their daughters’ marriages is an important form of parental investment, it can also be a source of conflict. Just as daughters can benefit from advantageous marriages, parents and extended kin can benefit from financial transfers at the time of marriage, and strengthened social networks through endogamy and/or widened social networks through exogamy (Shenk, Towner et al., Reference Shenk, Kaplan and Hooper2016; Chapais, Reference Chapais2008; Coontz, Reference Coontz2006; Lévi-Strauss, Reference Lévi-Strauss1949). Certain features of women's marriages, including timing and spousal characteristics, also impact children's reproductive fitness and thus affect their parents’ fitness as well (Raj & Boehmer, Reference Raj and Boehmer2013). Parents' and children's interests often align, but parents are expected to prefer marriages that advantage their whole family unit even when there is a potential cost to an individual child (Trivers, Reference Trivers1974; Schaffnit, Hassan et al., Reference Schaffnit, Hassan, Urassa and Lawson2019). For example, parents may prefer their daughters to marry at younger ages or in times of familial economic need in order to optimise the timing and size of bridewealth or dowry payments (Corno & Voena, Reference Corno and Voena2016; Schaffnit, Hassan et al., Reference Schaffnit, Hassan, Urassa and Lawson2019). Parents may also prioritise marriages which build advantageous family alliances (Chagnon et al., Reference Chagnon, Lynch, Shenk, Hames and Flinn2017; Coontz, Reference Coontz2006; Lévi-Strauss, Reference Lévi-Strauss1949), including, for example, prefering spouses from well-off or high-status backgrounds. In contrast, daughters may prefer to marry at older ages to benefit from prolonged investments in embodied capital and reduced risks associated with early reproduction (Apostolou, Reference Apostolou2015). Evidence of disagreement between parents and their children over marriages abounds, especially regarding ideal partners and timing of marriage (Weissner, Reference Weissner and Shennan2009; Agey et al., Reference Agey, Morris, Chandry and Gaulin2021). Yet not all parent–child disagreements are indicative of a true evolutionary conflict. For example, daughters often prioritise love and attraction to a husband more highly than their parents, potentially leading parents to select a partner who is less attractive to their daughter. While such a situation may result in disagreement between parents and daughter, if parents in fact select a spouse for their daughter based on more fitness-impacting traits, then parents may be acting in the fitness interests of their daughter, making the conflict superficial.

Whether arranged marriage systems are viewed as a source of conflict or as a form of parental investment – or most likely both – parents have historically had the upper hand over their children when it comes to marriage decisions (Voland, Reference Voland1998; Boone, Reference Boone1986). Parents are usually physically larger (when their children are young and/or female; Apostolou, Reference Apostolou2007), and generally control more resources and hold greater social sway than their children. As such, when conflicts do arise, parents are often in a better bargaining position – especially in contexts where parents control many economic and social resources and/or children marry at young ages (Alexander, Reference Alexander1974; Shenk, Reference Shenk, Shackelford and Weekes-Shackelford2017; Weissner, Reference Weissner and Shennan2009). In fact, even in the absence of outward disagreement between parents and children over marriage, the presence of arranged marriage systems and effective parental control over mate choice are indicative of parents having ‘won’ such conflicts, i.e. parents having systematically greater bargaining power than their children.

Impact of market integration on arranged marriage systems

Market integration may, however, fundamentally alter parent–child dynamics in marriage markets. Market integration is a process that entails a shift away from agriculture to occupations less directly related to subsistence, e.g. market work, or education-based employment, but it also encompasses wider economic and societal changes that occur alongside this process (Mattison et al., Reference Mattison, Hare, MacLaren, Reynolds, Sum, Liu and Wander2022; Lu, Reference Lu2007). Evolutionary anthropologists have argued that market integration results in increased parental investment, particularly in embodied capital via education (Kaplan, Reference Kaplan1996; Lawson & Mace, Reference Lawson and Mace2011), a phenomenon that results in a levelling of embodied capital differences between parents and children. Shifts from subsistence to market-based economies (i.e. market integration) thus increase children's bargaining power within the parent–child dyad. This is because as children become educated and more involved in generating wealth for themselves and their families, they gain influence within the family, thereby reducing relative parental influence and increasing their ability to make their own marriage choices even in the face of parental opposition. This has been shown in semi-rural Tanzania, where parents often attempt to control their children's, particularly daughters’, sexual and marital behaviours in order to secure advantageous bride wealth payments and social benefits (Wamoyi et al., Reference Wamoyi, Fenwick, Urassa, Zaba and Stones2011a). However, recent increases in children's education and economic contributions to their family unit have resulted in reductions in parental control and increased decision-making power among children (Wamoyi et al., Reference Wamoyi, Fenwick, Urassa, Zaba and Stones2011b). Among Ju/’hoansi foragers of South Africa, parents are highly motivated to control each step in the marriage process of their children, frequently desiring their children to marry at young ages to politically advantageous spouses (Weissner, Reference Weissner and Shennan2009). Through physical coercion of children (e.g. beating) or threats of suicide, parents were historically successful in enforcing their desires despite resistance from their children (e.g. running away). However, through government schemes in the 1960s and 1970s the Ju/’hoansi were settled, and wage labour amongst young men and education for girls increased. These changes altered parent–child relationships and the dynamics of marriage. Young people now control their own marriages and these marriages tend to occur at older ages than they did in previous decades (Weissner, Reference Weissner and Shennan2009). Furthermore, the fertility declines that often accompany market integration may also alter bargaining dynamics in marriage negotiations as extended kin networks disperse to different cities or regions and shrink in size and influence (Colleran, Reference Colleran2020).

In addition to changes in parent–child bargaining dynamics, market integration and accompanying fertility decline also alter parental investment strategies such that parents often invest more heavily in fewer children (Lawson & Borgerhoff Mulder, Reference Lawson and Borgerhoff Mulder2016; Shenk, Towner, et al., Reference Shenk, Towner, Kress and Alam2013; Kaplan et al., Reference Kaplan, Lancaster, Tucker and Anderson2002; Lawson & Mace, Reference Lawson and Mace2011). Market integration can also prompt increasing inequalities within communities and parents must increase their investments in their children – through education, health, marriage etc. – to ensure their future success (Shenk, Kaplan, & Hooper, Reference Shenk, Kaplan and Hooper2016; Boone, Reference Boone1986). Under such circumstances, parents' motivation to control children's marriages may remain high even as their ability to enforce their choice grows more limited in the face of the increasing participation of children in formal schooling, children's rising economic autonomy and the decoupling of the economic cooperation between parents and children (e.g. as children move away from family farms and trades and into the labour market). Thus, increasing parental investments owing to market integration reinforce children's already strengthened bargaining power. Further, such increases in parental investments and investments in embodied capital typically result in delays to marriage which again strengthen children's bargaining power in marriage decisions owing to their more advanced age and the economic productivity which accompanies it (Apostolou, Reference Apostolou2011). Spousal choice in such contexts often moves from norms of parental choice towards norms of joint decision-making or even child choice (Shenk, Reference Shenk, Shackelford and Weekes-Shackelford2017; Coontz, Reference Coontz2006), and direct parental investments in children (e.g. in their education, occupation, or income) often become the primary way that parents work to attract a desirable spouse (Shenk, Reference Shenk2004; Coontz, Reference Coontz2006).

Study setting

In this study, we consider patterns of arranged marriage for women in Matlab, Bangladesh, a rural area experiencing rapid market integration. Currently, many residents of Matlab still participate in agriculture but do not own the land that they farm and most households engage in wage labour to supplement agriculture (Alam et al., Reference Alam, Ali, Razzaque, Rahman, Haq, Saha and Streatfield2017; Shenk, Towner et al., Reference Shenk, Kaplan and Hooper2016). Recent decades have seen an expansion of both wage labour within Matlab and labour migration out of Matlab, whereby emigrants send remittances back to their families (ICDDR,B, 2018). Based on these ongoing changes in economy of households in Matlab, in this paper we operationalise family-level market integration using proxies derived from data on women's fathers’ occupation (Shenk, Towner, et al., Reference Shenk, Towner, Kress and Alam2013).

Arranged marriage is an ancient custom in South Asia, including Bangladesh, and has been normative regardless of the religion of the family or the type of marriage payment, e.g. dowry or bridewealth. While arranged marriages still account for the vast majority of marriages in Matlab, recent decades have seen increases in love and love–arranged marriages. Love matches are those in which a person selects and marries a spouse of their own choosing, sometimes without the approval of their family, while in a love–arranged marriage a person selects their spouse but their parents/relatives arrange the marriage – either because they approve of the spouse or for the sake of the family's reputation and prestige. Owing to sample size limitations, marriages that are not fully arranged will be collectively referred to as love marriages from here on, although they include both love matches and love–arranged marriages. In the cases where we distinguish between them, we will specify ‘purely love’ marriages to exclude love–arranged marriages.

Parents in Matlab use their own status to negotiate advantageous marriages for their daughters yet simultaneously invest heavily in daughters to secure a good match. Parents commonly invest in their daughters through education – with balances made between being educated to a high enough level and not postponing marriage too long (Shenk, Reference Shenk2004; Shahidul, Reference Shahidul2014) – and through savings for dowry, that is payments flowing from a woman's family to her groom's family at the time of marriage. In Bangladesh and other areas of South Asia, dowry is a major form of parental investment, critical to the success of daughters on the marriage market (Shenk, Reference Shenk2004; Shahidul, Reference Shahidul2014). The custom of dowry is ancient in the region, and while in the past it was typically practised mainly by wealthy land-owning or merchant families, in recent decades dowry has become normative in Bangladesh as in much of the rest of South Asia (Srinivas, Reference Srinivas1984; Lankes et al., Reference Lankes, Shenk, Towner and Alam2022). Many have argued that this spread of dowry is linked to economic development/market integration (Shenk, Reference Shenk2004; Srinivas, Reference Srinivas1984) through education and savings for dowry. In this region dowry payments are common across most marriages, but are less likely to occur in love marriages, particularly those lacking parental approval.

Research questions and predictions

Using data from, 2010 collected in Matlab Bangladesh, we address three research questions, the latter two with associated predictions:

  1. (1) What are the temporal changes in arranged vs. love marriages for women?

  2. (2) Which characteristics of women are associated with arranged vs. love marriages?

    [P1] Women who had arranged marriages will have higher status mates than those who had love marriages. This is because we expect that parents will be able to use their relatively greater wealth and/or status to attract a higher status husband for their daughters than a daughter would on her own. We thus further expect that, independent of marriage type, parental ability to attract a desirable spouse for their daughter will be an important predictor of the husband's status. This prediction is consistent with the hypothesis that arranged marriage is a means of parental investment, and that parental resources are positively correlated with spouse quality for children (Voland, Reference Voland1998).

    [P2] Love marriages will take place at later ages because early marriages, especially when closely followed by first births, can be costly for girls and their children (Kramer & Lancaster, Reference Kramer and Lancaster2010). While parents generally seek to avoid harm to their children, they may experience conflicting interests with an individual child; parents sometimes benefit from earlier marriages through lower dowry costs (in areas where younger women are seen as more biddable or chaste), or through positive effects of the marriage of a child on the family's economic status or social connections, and thus may be less risk averse than their daughters, who may prefer to marry later (Schaffnit & Lawson, Reference Schaffnit and Lawson2021). Such a pattern, however, could arise owing to delays in marriage related to either (a) the opportunities to meet prospective spouses afforded by extended education or (b) the fact that more educated daughters have greater bargaining power when the marriage finally occurs. Moreover, this relationship may be moderated by whether the marriage is to a relative or not. If love marriages are more frequently to cousins (e.g. Ghimire et al., Reference Ghimire, Axinn, Yabiku and Thornton2006; Shenk, Towner et al., Reference Shenk, Kaplan and Hooper2016), especially for women with low levels of education, then these marriages may take place at younger ages both because delays will not be made for education and because women are acquainted with their cousins from a young age.

  3. (3) How do aspects of market integration relate to patterns of arranged and love marriages?

    [P3] Women from families that are less market integrated will be more likely to have had an arranged marriage than women from more market integrated families. Specifically, we expect that love marriages will be more common in market-integrated families because daughters are likely to be better educated, marry at later ages, and have more opportunities to meet prospective husbands (e.g. Shenk, Starkweather et al., Reference Shenk, Starkweather, Kress and Alam2013; Shenk, Towner et al., Reference Shenk, Towner, Voss and Alam2016).

    [P4] Women with higher education who enter love marriages will be less likely to marry a relative, while women with lower education who enter a love marriage will be more likely to marry a relative. Within Matlab and other parts of South Asia, love marriages are also likely to be to relatives because socialising between unrelated, unmarried men and women is restricted and women are more likely to interact and thus fall in love with male relatives than with unrelated men (Ghimire et al., Reference Ghimire, Axinn, Yabiku and Thornton2006; Shenk, Towner et al., Reference Shenk, Kaplan and Hooper2016). Further, both women and their parents may prefer marrying relatives when entering a love marriage because there are fewer unknowns about their future in-laws (Maqsood, Reference Maqsood2021). Whether love marriages are more likely to be with a relative or not could therefore depend on both exposure to non-relatives (such as through secondary or post-secondary education) and the motivation to expand one's family network by marriage to a non-relative, which has become a prominent motivation in contemporary Matlab (Shenk, Towner et al., Reference Shenk, Kaplan and Hooper2016). Compared with women with fewer years of education, women with more education may have greater bargaining power to pick a spouse, and more opportunities to meet unrelated men than those with lower education, and may therefore favour marrying out of their family in order to expand their socioeconomic network.

Methods

Data

This study uses data collected within the Matlab Health and Demographic Surveillance System which has been run by the International Centre for Diarrheal Disease Research, Bangladesh (ICDDR,B) since 1962 (Alam et al., Reference Alam, Ali, Razzaque, Rahman, Haq, Saha and Streatfield2017). Data used in this study were collected in 2010 from 944 women aged 20–65 years. The Health and Demographic Surveillance System includes a full population survey of over 200,000 people. For our subsample, equal numbers of women were drawn at random from three 15-year age categories (20–34, 35–49 and 50–64), allowing for better representation of older women in this growing population. Refusal rates were very low (under 5%) and were generally related to travel, personal illness or other immediate commitments (e.g. a daughter's wedding). During surveys, female, Bangla-speaking ICDDR,B data collectors – trained by Shenk and Alam – interviewed women at their homes. Women answered questions about each of their children including their children's marriages and questions regarding their natal families (e.g. family composition and parents’ education). Surveys also covered topics such as residence patterns, land ownership and inheritance, migration and fertility. For the purposes of this study, we included all female respondents who had ever married and any of their married daughters. The inclusion of women's married daughters had the benefit of expanding our sample size and increasing the number of relatively rare events for our outcome of interest (love marriages). This resulted in a working sample of 1598 women (886 focal women and 712 of their ever-married daughters).

This study received ethical approval from the Ethical Review Committee at ICDDR,B in Bangladesh (no. PR-09030) and the Campus Institutional Review Board at the University of Missouri in the USA (no. 1139478). According to these approvals, all participants gave written consent prior to taking part in the study.

Variables

The primary variable of interest is marriage type, measured as arranged or love (including love and love–arranged). Other marriage variables captured women's age at marriage, and whether her spouse is a relative or not (0 = no, 1 = yes).

Women's status, or the individual characteristics likely to improve position on the marriage market, was measured in two ways: her education and information about her dowry. Education was measured in number of years of school completed. The dowry variable represents the total amount spent on dowry by women's parents and is reported in increments of 10,000 taka (~144 USD at the 2010 average exchange rate). Because dowries were given at various points in time, and the value of money fluctuates across time, this value is also adjusted for inflation to the value of 2010 Taka using the price of medium rice which may avoid overcorrection for inflation common with standard consumer price index (CPI) adjustments (although adjustment with standard CPI in this case yields similar results, see Lankes et al., Reference Lankes, Shenk, Towner and Alam2022). To normalise the dowry variable, 1 was added to each value and then log transformed.

Husband's status was similarly estimated with a measure of years of education the husband had completed. Further, husbands’ occupations were classified by their social status (from low to high status occupations: 1 = agricultural and unskilled, 2 = semi-skilled, 3 = skilled labour and business, 4 = education-based and professional).

Information about women's fathers (occupational status and years of education) was used to both estimate the status of a woman's family of origin and their level of market integration. The family's level of market integration was measured via the father's occupation in two ways. Firstly, father's occupation was classified based on their level of market integration (as above). Secondly, father's occupation was classified as agricultural or not (0 = no, 1 = yes).

Analysis

Data were analysed in Stata 15 and R version 4.0.3. We firstly used the complete sample of ever married women and their female children (n = 1598) to describe changes in marriages and other characteristics by age group, i.e. generational changes. We considered changes in types of marriages (love vs. arranged), marriages to relatives, education (own and husband's), and age at marriage.

Each prediction was then tested using regression-based models with clustered robust standard errors to account for non-independence of observations among mothers and daughters from the same family. Models were restricted to women and their daughters who were aged 50 and younger at the time of interview and had ever been married (n = 1340); this was done because in 2010 love marriages were extremely rare among women over 50 years old. Cases with missing data were excluded from analyses, resulting in variation in the final sample size across analyses. Each model had a different set of controls identified using directed acyclic graphs (DAGs; see below for details).

To test the first prediction that [P1] women who had arranged marriages will have higher status spouses, we ran two models with different outcome measures of spouse status: husband's education (linear regression) and occupational status (multinomial logistic regression. To test the second prediction that [P2] being in an arranged marriage predicts younger ages at marriage, we ran a linear regression model with marriage type predicting age at marriage. In addition to the first model, we ran a moderation analysis to explore the role of cousin marriage. Here, to predict age at marriage we included an interaction term between marriage type and cousin marriage. To test the third prediction that [P3] being from a more market integrated family would result in a lower probability of being in an arranged marriage, we ran two logistic regression models. In the first, the main predictor was the level of market integration of the woman's father's occupation, ranging from low to high. In the second set of models the primary predictor was a binary indicator of whether or not the woman's father's occupation was agricultural. Finally, to test the prediction that [P4] education modifies the association between marriage type and odds of marrying a relative, a logistic regression was run with marriage to a relative (yes/no) as the outcome and an interaction term between marriage type and educational attainment.

Directed acyclic graphs

We used DAGs to illustrate the predicted causal relationships between variables and identify confounders to adjust for using the dagitty package in R (Textor et al., Reference Textor, von der Zander, Gilthorpe, Liskiewicz and Ellison2016). Directed acyclic graphs are a form of graphical causal model which help to identify the cause–effect relationships we wish to model (Ankan et al., Reference Ankan, Wortel and Textor2021). Based on our existing knowledge of causal relationships between variables, DAGs allow for the construction of a statistical model that can provide valid causal inference between the predicted relationships visualised in the DAG (McElreath, Reference McElreath2020). By including directional ties between variables, the use of DAGs allows the modelling of confounded (e.g. when A is associated with C because they are both causally influenced by B) and collider (e.g. when A and C both independently cause B) pathways. This permits the production of a statistical model that controls confounding relationships (e.g. closes the back door by including additional terms), and also avoids conditioning on the collider, which ensures the back doors remain closed (by not including these terms). The final DAG that underpins all models in this analysis is visualised in Figure 1, and is based on known relationships (as reviewed above) between key variables included in data collection, including age at marriage, cousin marriage, educational attainment of fathers, daughters and husbands, husbands’ occupational status, level of market integration, dowry amount and marriage type. As a result, each model (with a unique outcome and exposure) has different controls suggested by the minimally sufficient adjustment set for that specific causal relationship produced by the DAG, following confirmation of the implied conditional independencies (Ankan et al., Reference Ankan, Wortel and Textor2021). The full process of creating and checking these DAGS can be found in the Supporting Information code, and full model outputs can be found in the Supporting Information results.

Figure 1. The directed acyclic graph (DAG) of all the predicted causal relationships between the variables included in the analysis. As this DAG underpins different model sets, variables have not been labelled as ‘exposures’ and/or ‘outcomes’, nor have the causal or biasing paths been highlighted.

Results

Changes over time in marriage and education

Marriages that were not fully arranged are uncommon in this sample of women. Of all marriages for which information is available (n = 1598), 5.8% were not fully arranged, including 3.2% love–arranged marriages and 2.6% purely love marriages. Women who are in arranged marriages are older than women in love marriages (37 years vs. 31 years; t (d.f.) = 4.23 (1596); p < 0.001; Table 1). Half of all recorded love marriages were to women under 30 years old at the time of interview and three-quarters were to women aged 36 years and younger. Women in arranged marriages were married at younger ages than women in love marriages (17 vs. 18 years; t (d.f.) = −2.70 (1593); p = 0.007) and were less likely to be married to a relative compared with women in love marriages (19.8% of love marriages were to relatives vs. 9.0% of arranged marriages; χ 2 = 10.44; p = 0.001). Women in arranged marriages were more likely to have had a dowry than women in love marriages (81.0% vs. 66.2%; χ 2 = 8.96; p = 0.003) and this was largely driven by the fact that only half of women in purely love marriages had a dowry vs. 79.0% of those in love–arranged marriages (χ 2 = 17.83; p < 0.001). Women's own education and that of their husbands was higher among women in love marriages compared with those in arranged marriages (women's mean years of education: 5.9 years vs. 5.0; t (d.f.) = −2.08 (1596); p = 0.038; husbands’ mean years of education: 6.9 vs. 5.7; t (d.f.) = −2.28 (1240); p = 0.022; Table 2). Women in love marriages were more likely to have a father (χ 2 = 9.66; p = 0.022) and husband (χ 2 = 9.72; p = 0.021) with an occupation classified as low–middle market integration (as compared with low, middle or high market integration) than women in arranged marriages. Women in love marriages were more likely to be married to a man with a non-agricultural occupation than women in arranged marriages (χ 2 = 4.51; p = 0.034).

Table 1. Marriage characteristics by marriage type

a Includes love and love–arranged marriages.

b Chi-squared test if categorical; t-test if continuous.

Table 2. Woman's, husband's and family's status by marriage type

a Includes love and love–arranged marriages.

b Chi-squared test if categorical; t-test if continuous.

c Among those who received any dowry.

Just as age is a key correlate of marriage type, age also correlates with other characteristics of women, their marriages, their husbands and fathers. In particular we find that age at marriage was higher among younger women (Figure 2). Some 42% of women aged over 61 married at ages 12 years or below and 1.9% at ages 18–21 years compared with women aged 30 years and younger, among whom 1.4% married at age 12 and younger and 45.8% at ages 18–21 years (χ 2 = 282.3; p < 0.001). Having had a dowry was also more common among younger women; while 38% of women aged 61 and above had a dowry, 86% of women aged 30 and under had a dowry (χ 2 = 110.5; p < 0.001).

Figure 2. Women's marriage type, age at marriage, marriage to relative, and education by current age (n = 1598).

Younger women had more years of education compared with older women, as did their husbands and fathers. While 69% of women aged 61 and above had no education, only 6.7% of women aged 30 years and under had no education (χ 2 = 439.9; p < 0.001). Women who were older also were also more likely than younger women to have a father with no education (χ 2 = 36.8; p < 0.001) or to be married to a man with no education (χ 2 = 112.0; p < 0.001) (Figure 3).

Figure 3. Women's father's and husband's years of education by women's current age.

Prediction testing

From here we limit our sample to women aged under 50 years old as there was a lack of variation in marriage type in the sample older than 50 years.

Prediction 1: arranged marriage is positively associated with husband status

We find no evidence that women in arranged marriages were more likely to obtain husbands with either more education (β = −0.718, 95% confidence interval, CI [−1.546, 0.109], n = 961; Supporting Information, Table 1.1.1) or occupational status (low status relative risk ratio, RRR = 1.066, 95% CI [0.524,2.169]; unskilled labour RRR = 0.1.279, 95% CI [0.616, 2.656]; skilled labour RRR = 1.034, 95% CI [0.435, 2.456], relative to education-based employment, n = 1308; Supporting Information, Table 1.2.1) when controlling for marriage to a relative, daughter's education, father's education and level of market integration as determined by father's occupation. We found more evidence to support the role of women's status, as both women's (β = 0.703, 95% CI [0.643, 0.763], n = 977; Supporting Information, Table 1.1.2) and fathers’ educational attainment (β = 0.458, 95% CI [0.385, 0.531], n = 973; Table 1.1.3) was positively associated with the women's husbands’ educational attainment. Likewise, for husbands’ occupation, we do not find evidence that arranged marriages are predictive of a husband's occupational status (Supporting Information, Table 1.2.1), but we do find that a daughter's education predicts her husband having an education-based occupation (Supporting Information, Table 1.2.2).

Prediction 2: arranged marriage predicts a younger age at marriage

We do not find evidence for a relationship between marriage type and age at marriage, controlling for cousin marriage, daughter's and father's education and market integration (Supporting Information, Table 2.1). The beta estimate, however, is in the expected direction (β = −0.674, 95% CI [−1.374, 0.081], n = 1303), suggesting a weak negative relationship between arranged marriage and age at marriage. We ran an additional model with an interaction between arranged marriage and cousin marriage to predict age at marriage. While the interaction term was non-significant (β = −0.789, p = 0.417, 95% CI −2.697, 1.119]; Supporting Information, Table 2.2), this analysis showed that compared with an arranged, non-cousin marriage, an arranged cousin marriage occurred 0.871 years earlier (p = 0.005, 95% CI [−1.477, −0.266, n = 1311). As a result, the average age of marriage for a cousin-arranged marriage was 17.05 years, compared with 18.34 for a cousin non-arranged marriage, or 18.43 for a non-arranged, non-cousin marriage and 17.92 for a non-cousin, non-arranged marriage.

Prediction 3: higher levels of market integration are associated with a lower likelihood of having an arranged marriage

We do not find support for the prediction that level of market integration at the family level, as measured by father's occupation, is an important predictor of marriage type (Supporting Information, Table 3.1 and Supporting Information, Table 3.2). While compared with low levels of market integration, low–middle market integration (non-food-production occupations) was significantly associated with a decrease in odds of arranged marriage (odds ratio, OR = 0.499, 95% CI [0.282, 0.882], n = 1333), this finding did not hold among either middle–high or high levels of market integration, which demonstrated (non-significant) increased odds of arranged marriages. Furthermore, a father's occupation being agriculture/food production, as compared with not being involved in agriculture or food production, was not associated with marriage type (OR = 0.793, 95% CI [0.552, 1.381], n = 1340).

Prediction 4: women with lower educational attainment who enter love marriages will be more likely to marry a relative

In line with our predictions, being in an arranged marriage (controlling for daughter's and father's education and market integration) was associated with a decrease in the odds of cousin marriage (OR = 0.392, 95% CI [0.212, 0.726], n = 1314; Supporting Information, Table 4.1). We predicted that this effect would be dependent on exposure to non-relatives (via education), and therefore ran an additional interaction between marriage type and education attainment. While the confidence interval for an interaction between marriage type and education overlaps with 1 (OR = 0.364, 95% CI [0.885, 1.170], n = 1314; Supporting Information, Table 4.2), the direction of the effect is as predicted (Figure 4). That is, the trend in the data indicates that women with lower education who were in love marriages were more likely to marry a cousin than women with more education or women who were in arranged marriages regardless of education level.

Figure 4. Predicted probability of marrying a relative and 95% confidence intervals by marriage type and years of education based on model 4.

Discussion

Our findings confirm high rates of arranged marriage in Matlab, Bangladesh. Love marriages were concentrated among younger women, including both love–arranged marriages, in which parents facilitate the marriage of daughters to a spouse chosen by the daughter, and purely love marriages, which take place without parental facilitation. Love–arranged marriages are more common than purely love marriages for older women while among younger women the split between love–arranged and purely love marriages was more even. It is probable, in this context, that many marriages that are not fully arranged are still taking place with some parental involvement evidenced by the fact that even among marriages classified as purely love marriages (that is, excluding love–arranged marriage), half took place with a dowry. This suggests at least some level of parental involvement in the marriage, either by parents coming to agree with their daughter's choice over time or by them choosing to save face by formally approving the marriage and giving a dowry to socially legitimise the marriage. We find that marriage type is a poor predictor of spouse characteristics, possibly because in practice there are limited socioeconomic distinctions between arranged and love marriages – and particularly between arranged and love–arranged marriages. Rather, measures of the family's status or bargaining power (father's education) and women's own educational status are more important predictors of spouse status. This supports the idea that regardless of whether a marriage is arranged, parents can improve their daughters’ chances on the marriage market by investing directly in their daughter through her education.

There is some evidence that arranged marriages occur at younger ages than non-arranged marriages (Prediction 2), in line with hypotheses derived from parent-offspring conflict theories (Schaffnit, Hassan et al., Reference Schaffnit, Hassan, Urassa and Lawson2019; Corno and Voena, Reference Corno and Voena2016). However, this result is largely accounted for by the small number of arranged marriages to relatives, which occurred significantly earlier than arranged marriage to non-relatives. While this is contrary to our expectations, this result is easy to understand. Given existing family ties, marriages to relatives are likely to be easier to arrange because the proposed spouses have pre-existing relationships to ease the process; they may even be arranged far in advance of the actual wedding. Our results did highlight that marriages to relatives were much more likely to be love marriages, rather than arranged marriages (Prediction 4). This is in line with previous research in Matlab and South Asia, which found that given restricted interactions with non-relatives of the opposite sex, relatives have far more occasion to interact and fall in love (Ghimire et al., Reference Ghimire, Axinn, Yabiku and Thornton2006; Shenk, Towner et al., Reference Shenk, Kaplan and Hooper2016). However, we saw no evidence, that love marriages occurred at younger ages among relatives. It may be the case then that, compared with arranged marriages with non-relatives, relatedness did not necessarily speed up the process of prospective spouses falling in love and deciding to marry.

We did not find any evidence that family-level indicators of market integration (estimated by women's fathers’ occupation) predict the type of marriage. However, the rise of non-arranged marriages does appear to be linked to several aspects of market integration on a societal level, although this finding is descriptive. Market integration is clearly linked to increasing parental investments in South Asia, particularly in education, but also to investment in dowry (Shenk, Reference Shenk2004; Srinivas, Reference Srinivas1984); we see this in our own data with younger women being more likely to have had a dowry, having higher education and being married to men with higher education. We argue that such investments, especially in daughter's education, have created a situation in which love marriages are now possible where they were not in the past. Increasing parental investment owing to market integration has led to increasing female education. This results in delayed marriage for those women participating in education, which can be seen in increasing ages at marriage. Together, higher levels of education and older ages at marriage mean that women now have (a) greater bargaining power than in the past, (b) more opportunities to meet a husband outside of their parents’/family's network and (c) greater ability to attract a high-status spouse owing to their own status rather than having to rely on their father's or family's status. Together this creates an environment where non-arranged marriages (including many approved by parents) may become more common despite a deeply entrenched arranged marriage system. This suggests that we are currently seeing a shift within Matlab from the ‘traditional’ path to ensuring high spouse/marriage quality to a ‘market integration’ path (Figure 5). In the former, parents use their status to arrange advantageous marriages, in part through dowry. In the latter, parents invest heavily in their daughters (e.g. through education), which means that daughters are in a position to attract a high-status spouse, either on their own (through their education) or with parental assistance (through their dowry).

Figure 5. Visualisation of traditional and market integrated pathways to a high-quality spouse/marriage.

There is some evidence that the two key parental investments that allow for the new ‘market integrated’ path to marriage in this setting – investment in dowry and education – may trade off against each other (Goel & Barua, Reference Goel and Barua2021; Walker et al., Reference Walker, Gurven, Burger and Hamilton2008; Shenk, Reference Shenk2004; Shahidul, Reference Shahidul2014), but generally speaking parents invest significantly in both. Yet our results show that while investment in a daughter's education is a significant predictor of her husband's status, investment in dowry had only a small, positive and non-significant relationship with husband's status. This is probably because education has many collateral effects relevant to arranged marriage. For example, more years of education are accompanied by delays to marriage, increased human capital for women, an increased ability to invest in her own children's human capital (Shenk, Reference Shenk2004; Shenk, Towner et al., Reference Shenk, Kaplan and Hooper2016; Goel & Barua, Reference Goel and Barua2021), and additional opportunities to meet men who match her socioeconomic status. In contrast, dowry represents a major financial investment that is associated with spouse education – a measure of quality – but may have relatively few collateral effects (although see Shenk, Reference Shenk2007 for a possible positive effect on child outcomes). This may also be because dowry is paid by parents and thus is linked to parental resources and status and/or spouse resources and status, rather than representing an independent characteristic of the bride.

In fact, it is not clear whether dowry should go on the upper or lower path of Figure 5. On the one hand, parents typically pay dowry and thus it is a strong reflection of parental status and resources. On the other hand, dowries accompany daughters into a marriage. Dowry thus serves as both a direct and indirect investment in the status and resources of the daughter and her children, increases women's bargaining power in her marital family (Shenk, Reference Shenk2007; Makino, Reference Makino2019; Goel & Barua, Reference Goel and Barua2021) and can be classified as a form of parental investment. In all likelihood, dowries represent aspects of parents’, women's and husbands’ status, thus such interpretations may be hard to distinguish.

While family-level market integration does not seem to affect marriage patterns, at least using our simple measures, we do find that an individual-level marker of market integration, education, clearly affects individual marriage outcomes. We also suggest that society-level changes in education, and the accompanying strengthened bargaining power of women with higher education (Ikhar et al., Reference Ikhar, Banerjee, Bandhopadhyaya, Tiwari and Deshmukh2022), leads to altered marriage opportunities for everyone, even those who themselves do not have high education. This can be seen in the interaction between education and marriage type; women with low education levels are able to participate in love marriages despite their young age and lack of (relative) economic power because a new pathway to marriage has been opened within their society. Owing to constraints around who young unmarried girls and women interact with, these marriages are typically to male relatives with whom they are able to interact more freely. Yet we see that the opportunity for non-arranged marriages, which arises partially owing to increasing women's education, is available across all levels of education. This pattern also echoes patterns of prestige-biased transmission (Boyd & Richerson, Reference Boyd and Richerson1985) in which adoption of behaviours by higher-status members of a society may transmit new social norms or allow for the adoption of new behaviours by others.

Limitations and future research

This study benefits from a rich dataset from a single population with a large sample size. One of the strengths of this study was having access to data on marriage from two generations of women. This allowed us to both increase our sample size and also add instances of a relatively rare outcome (non-arranged marriages). Even so, the outcome remains very rare in this population which may limit the generalisability and interpretability of the statistics we present. Our largely null results may be the product of a Type II error, and future studies should endeavour to work with larger samples of love marriages to replicate the results presented here. A trade-off in the benefits of including data from focal women's daughters was that we lost various measures of childhood socioeconomic position and parents’ status that were only available for focal women but not their daughters. Future work would benefit from using data which allows for broader measures of family status and spouse quality. Such measures could then be used to build path models that in turn may help to explain the primary drivers and consequences of arranged marriage, as well as the potential moderating effects of level market integration at the society and individual level.

It is also important to note that the father's occupation data used to proxy market integration is measured at the time of the survey (or at the time that he retired), but the marriages of women in our sample happened before this time. While based on ethnographic knowledge, we have reason to believe that occupations are relatively stable across the lifespan in this part of Bangladesh, it is nonetheless likely that the effect of market integration as measured here may be underestimated. While we do have qualitative data on related topics (e. g. Shenk, Towner et al., Reference Shenk, Kaplan and Hooper2016), our understanding of arranged marriage in Matlab would benefit from further use of qualitative methods (e.g. Baraka et al., Reference Baraka, Lawson, Schaffnit, Wamoyi and Urassa2022; Akurugu et al., Reference Akurugu, Dery and Bata2022) to clarify the connections between market integration and marriage decisions.

It is also important to note that, as the instances of love marriages are higher among younger women, our findings speak more to the younger generation than to the older. Moreover, in the time since these data were collected, the marriage system in Matlab has continued to evolve. Since 2010 the digital era has come to Matlab, and mobile phones – particularly smart phones with connections to messaging apps and social media – have become common and heavily used among young people, especially those who are wealthier, more educated and studying in high school or college. Through their phones they have more contact with other young people, including both locals but also those who are unknown or distant who they would not have come into contact with in the past. ICDDR,B fieldworkers in Matlab have observed an increase in the incidence of love marriage in general, including many love marriages among younger people, contributing to a surprising trend towards lower ages at marriage in the area in the last decade – and ICDDR,B internal data show that in 2018 arranged–love and love marriage together accounted for around 15% of recent marriages with an increasing trend.

In this paper we focused on the arranged marriage of daughters, in part because arranged marriages are more common for daughters than for sons. Future research in Matlab would do well to consider within-family tradeoffs in distributing resources between sons and daughters. Parents in this context, as in much of South Asia, attempt to weigh investments in daughter's status (e.g. education) against investments in her dowry, wanting to strike the right balance to attract an advantageous marriage (Goel & Barua, Reference Goel and Barua2021; Shahidul, Reference Shahidul2014). The same is not true for sons since he does not take a dowry into marriage with him and thus investments can be channeled fully into increasing his status. This may create conflicts within families as they weigh the various tradeoffs in within-child and between-child investments to optimise benefits for the family unit.

Conclusion

Marriages arranged by parents with accompanying dowry payments remain the norm in Matlab, Bangladesh. The area, however, is in the midst of rapid market integration – a process which has been associated with changes in, and the weakening of, arranged marriage systems in other settings (Reed, Reference Reed2019; Allendorf & Pandian, Reference Allendorf and Pandian2016). While we do not find support for the idea that family-level markers of market integration are associated with marriage type in this sample, we argue that on a societal level market integration has led to changes which have altered key dynamics in the marriage market in the region. These changes, seen in parental investment strategies and resultant improvements in children's bargaining power, have opened a new path to entering a marriage in Matlab, one which relies on women using their own status, gained through intensive parental investments in their education, to help in the negotiation of advantageous marriages. We argue that increasing female education, a key accompaniment of market integration and major form of parental investment in market integrating societies, is particularly important in opening this novel pathway owing to its far-reaching collateral effects relevant to marriage processes. Over time we expect that these forces will result in marriage decisions increasingly being made jointly between parents and children, as has been shown in urban India (Reed, Reference Reed2019; Allendorf & Pandian, Reference Allendorf and Pandian2016) and other related contexts.

Acknowledgements

The authors would like to think our study participants for their helpfulness during this project. We would also like to thank our 2010 field team – Shifat Khan, Nargis Sultana, Latifun Nahar, Akterun Naher, Lutfa Begum, Mouloda Aziz and Farhana Akand – for invaluable assistance with data collection. This research was made possible by our longstanding collaboration with ICDDR,B. We would finally like to thank three anonymous reviewers for useful comments on the manuscript.

Author contributions

MKS, MCT, and NA designed the project. MKS and NA oversaw data collection. SS and AEP analysed the data. SS, MKS, and AEP drafted the manuscript. MKS, NA, MCT, R Sear, R Sosis, and JS funded data collection and/or analysis. All authors provided comments and revisions on the manuscript.

Financial support

This research was funded by US National Science Foundation Award BCS-0924630 and John S. Templeton Grant ID 61426.

Conflict of interest

R. Sear is an editor at EHS.

Research transparency and reproducibility

The code used to run the statistical models in this paper are available as supplementary files.

Data availability

The data that support the findings of this study are not currently publicly available owing to IRB limitations. Data are available from MS and subject to a data use agreement.

Supplementary material

To view supplementary material for this article, please visit https://doi.org/10.1017/ehs.2022.54

References

Agey, E., Morris, A., Chandry, M., & Gaulin, S. J. C. (2021). Arranged marriage often subverts offspring mate choice: An HRAF-based study. American Anthropogist, 123(4), 861878.10.1111/aman.13656CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Akurugu, C. A., Dery, I., & Bata, P. D. (2022). Marriage, bridewealth and power: Critical reflections on women's autonomy across settings in Africa. Evolutionary Human Sciences, 4, 115. https://doi.org/10.1017/ehs.2022.27.Google Scholar
Alam, N., Ali, T., Razzaque, A., Rahman, M., Haq, M. Z., Saha, S. K., … Streatfield, P. K. (2017). Health and Demographic Surveillance System (HDSS) in Matlab, Bangladesh. International Journal of Epidemiology, 46(3), 809816. https://doi.org/10.1093/ije/dyx076.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Alexander, R. D. (1974). The evolution of social behavior. Annual Review of Ecology and Systematics, 5, 325383. https://doi.org/10.1093/acprof:oso/9780199590742.003.0004.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Allendorf, K., and Pandian, R. K. (2016). The decline of arranged marriage? Marital change and continuity in India HHS Public Access. Population Development Reviews, 42(3), 435464. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1728-4457.2016.00149.x.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ankan, A., Wortel, I. M. N., & Textor, J. (2021). Testing graphical causal models using the R package ‘Dagitty’. Current Protocols, 1(2), e45. https://doi.org/10.1002/cpz1.45.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Apostolou, M. (2007). Elements of parental choice: The evolution of parental preferences in relation to in-law selection. Evolutionary Psychology, 5(1), 147470490700500. https://doi.org/10.1177/147470490700500107.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Apostolou, M. (2010). Sexual selection under parental choice in agropastoral societies. Evolution and Human Behavior, 31(1), 3947. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.evolhumbehav.2009.06.010.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Apostolou, M. (2011). Parental influence over mate choice in a post-industrial context. Letters on Evolutionary Behavioral Science, 2(1), 1315. https://doi.org/10.5178/lebs.2011.12.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Apostolou, M. (2015). Parent–offspring conflict over mating: domains of agreement and disagreement. Evolutionary Psychology, 13(3), 112. https://doi.org/10.1177/1474704915604561.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Baraka, J., Lawson, D. W., Schaffnit, S. B., Wamoyi, J., & Urassa, M. (2022). Why marry early? Parental influence, agency and gendered conflict in Tanzanian marriages. Evolutionary Human Sciences, 4, e49. https://doi.org/10.1017/ehs.2022.46.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Berghe, P. L. van den (1979). Human family systems: An evolutionary view. ElsevierGoogle Scholar
Boone, J. L. (1986). Parental investment and elite family structure in preindustrial states: A case study of late medieval–early modern portuguese genealogies. American Anthropologist, 88(4), 859878. https://doi.org/10.1525/aa.1986.88.4.02a00050.Google Scholar
Boyd, R., & Richerson, P. J. (1985). Culture and the evolutionary process. University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
Broude, G. J., & Greene, S. J. (1983). Cross-cultural codes on husband–wife relationships. Journal of Ethnology, 22(3), 263.Google Scholar
Chagnon, N. A., Lynch, R. F., Shenk, M. K., Hames, R., & Flinn, M. V. (2017). Cross-cousin marriage among the Yanomamö shows evidence of parent–offspring conflict and mate competition between brothers. Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences of the United States of America, 114(13), E25902597. https://doi.org/10.1073/PNAS.1618655114.Google ScholarPubMed
Chapais, B. (2008). Primeval kinship: How pair-bonding gave birth to human society. Harvard University Press.10.4159/9780674029422CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Colleran, H. (2020). Market integration reduces kin density in women's ego-networks in rural Poland. Nature Communications, 11(1), 19. https://doi.org/10.1038/s41467-019-14158-2.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Coontz, S. (2006). Marriage, a history: How love conquered marriage. Penguin Books.Google Scholar
Corno, L., & Voena, A. (2016). Selling daughters: Age of marriage, income shocks and the bride price tradition. Institute for Fiscal Studies, Working Paper, W16/08.Google Scholar
Ghimire, D. J., Axinn, W. G., Yabiku, S. T., & Thornton, A. (2006). Social change, premarital nonfamily experience, and spouse choice in an arranged marriage society. American Journal of Sociology, 111(4), 11811218. https://doi.org/10.1086/498468.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Goel, P. A., and Barua, R. (2021). Female education, marital assortative mating, and dowry: Theory and evidence from districts of India. Journal of Demographic Economics, 127. https://doi.org/10.1017/dem.2021.23.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
ICDDR,B (2018). Health and Demographic Surveillance Stystem Matlab: Registration of Matlab Health and Demographic Events 2016, Vol. 51.Google Scholar
Ikhar, M. R., Banerjee, S., Bandhopadhyaya, K., Tiwari, M. K., & Deshmukh, P. (2022). Are women with more of ‘social capital’ more empowered? A cross-sectional analysis from rural Wardha, central India. Journal of Family Medicine and Primary Care, 11(2), 472. https://doi.org/10.4103/jfmpc.jfmpc_2495_20.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Kaplan, H. (1996). A theory of fertility and parental investment in traditional and modern human societies. American Journal of Physical Anthropology, 101(S23), 91135. https://doi.org/10.1002/(SICI)1096-8644(1996)23+<91::AID-AJPA4>3.0.CO;2-C.3.0.CO;2-C>CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kaplan, H., Lancaster, J. B., Tucker, W. T., & Anderson, K. G. (2002). Evolutionary approach to below replacement fertility. American Journal of Human Biology, 14(2), 233256. https://doi.org/10.1002/ajhb.10041.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Kramer, K. L., & Lancaster, J. B. (2010). Teen motherhood in cross-cultural perspective. Annals of Human Biology, 37(5), 613628. https://doi.org/10.3109/03014460903563434.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Lankes, J., Shenk, M. K., Towner, M. C.., & Alam, N. (2022). Dowry inflation: Perception or reality? Population Research and Policy Review, 41, 16411672. https://doi.org/10.1007/S11113-022-09705-7.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lawson, D. W., & Borgerhoff Mulder, M. (2016). The offspring quantity–quality trade-off and human fertility. Philosophical Transactions of the Royal Society, London B: Biological Science, 371, 20150145.10.1098/rstb.2015.0145CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Lawson, D. W., & Mace, R. (2011). Parental investment and the optimization of human family size. Philosophical Transactions of the Royal Society B: Biological Sciences, 366, 333343. https://doi.org/10.1098/rstb.2010.0297.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Lévi-Strauss, C. (1949). The elementary structures of kinship. Beacon Press.Google Scholar
Lu, F. (2007). Integration into the market among Indigenous peoples. Current Anthropology, 48(4), 593602. https://doi.org/10.1086/519806.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Makino, M. (2019). Dowry and women's status in rural Pakistan. Journal of Population Economics, 32, 769797.10.1007/s00148-018-0713-0CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Maqsood, A. (2021). Love as understanding: Marriage, aspiration, and the joint family in middle-class Pakistan. American Ethnologist, 48(1), 112. https://doi.org/10.1111/amet.13000.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mattison, S. M., Hare, D., MacLaren, N. G., Reynolds, A. Z., Sum, C.-Y., Liu, R., … Wander, K. (2022). Context specificity of ‘market integration’ among the matrilineal Mosuo of southwest China. Current Anthropology, 63(1), 118124. https://doi.org/10.1086/719266.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
McElreath, R. L. (2020). Statistical rethinking: A bayesian course with examples in R and STAN. Chapman and Hall.10.1201/9780429029608CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Murdock, G. P. (1949). Social structure. Macmillan.Google Scholar
Raj, A., & Boehmer, U. (2013). Girl child marriage and its association with national rates of HIV, maternal health, and infant mortality across 97 countries. Violence against Women, 19(4), 536551. https://doi.org/10.1177/1077801213487747.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Reed, M. (2019). The persistence of arranged marriage in urban India: New evidence from the Delhi national capital region. In Annual Meeting of the Population Association of America. http://paa2019.populationassociation.org/uploads/193533.Google Scholar
Santhya, K. G. (2011). Early marriage and sexual and reproductive health vulnerabilities of young women: A synthesis of recent evidence from developing countries. Current Opinion in Obstetrics & Gynecology, 23(5), 334339. https://doi.org/10.1097/GCO.0b013e32834a93d2.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Schaffnit, S. B., Hassan, A., Urassa, M., & Lawson, D. W. (2019). Parent–offspring conflict unlikely to explain ‘child marriage’ in northwestern Tanzania. Nature Human Behaviour, 3, 346353. https://doi.org/10.1038/s41562-019-0535-4.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Schaffnit, S. B., and Lawson, D. W. (2021). Married too young? The behavioral ecology of ‘ child marriage. Social Sciences, 9(161). https://doi.org/https://doi.org/10.3390/socsci10050161.Google Scholar
Schaffnit, S. B., Urassa, M., & Lawson, D. W. (2019). ‘Child marriage’ in context: Exploring local attitudes towards early marriage in rural Tanzania. Sexual and Reproductive Health Matters, 27(1), 1571304. https://doi.org/10.1080/09688080.2019.1571304.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Shahidul, S. M. (2014). Parents’ class background and hypergamy in the marriage market of Bangladesh: Does the dowry affect school dropout among girls? Asia-Pacific Education Researcher, 23(3), 709715. https://doi.org/10.1007/s40299-013-0142-5.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Shenk, M. K. (2004). Embodied capital and heritable wealth in complex cultures: A class-based analysis of parental investment in urban South India. Research in Economic Anthropology, 23, 307333.10.1016/S0190-1281(04)23013-XCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Shenk, M. K. (2005). Kin investment in wage-labor economies. Human Nature, 16(1), 81114. https://doi.org/10.1007/s12110-005-1008-1.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Shenk, M. K. (2007). Dowry and public policy in contemporary India: The behavioral ecology of a ‘social evil’. Human Nature, 18(3), 242263. https://doi.org/10.1007/s12110-007-9006-0.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Shenk, M. K. (2017). Arranged marriages. In Shackelford, T. K. & Weekes-Shackelford, V. A. (Eds.) Encyclopedia of evolutionary psychological science. Springer International. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-319-16999-6.Google Scholar
Shenk, M. K., Kaplan, H. S., & Hooper, P. L. (2016). Status competition, inequality, and fertility: Implications for the demographic transition. Philosophical Transactions of the Royal Society, London B: Biological Science, 371, 20150150. https://doi.org/10.1098/rstb.2015.0150.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Shenk, M. K., & Scelza, B. A. (2012). Paternal investment and status-related child outcomes: Timing of father's death affects offspring success. Journal of Biosocial Science, 121. https://doi.org/10.1017/S0021932012000053.Google ScholarPubMed
Shenk, M. K., Starkweather, K., Kress, H. C., & Alam, N. (2013). Does absence matter?: A comparison of three types of father absence in rural Bangladesh. Human Nature, 24(1), 76110. http://apps.webofknowledge.com.libproxy.ucl.ac.uk/full_record.do?product=UA&search_mode=GeneralSearch&qid=2&SID=R2HcN7EAJppNn5iGilI&page=1&doc=1.10.1007/s12110-013-9160-5CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Shenk, M. K., Towner, M. C., Kress, H. C., & Alam, N. (2013). A model comparison approach shows stronger support for economic models of fertility decline. Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences of the United States of America, 110(20), 80458050. https://doi.org/10.1073/pnas.1217029110.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Shenk, M. K., Towner, M. C., Voss, E. A., & Alam, N. (2016). Consanguineous marriage, kinship ecology, and market transition. Current Anthropology, 57, S000. https://doi.org/10.1086/685712.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Srinivas, M.N. (1984). Some Reflections on Dowry. Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Textor, J., von der Zander, B., Gilthorpe, M. K., Liskiewicz, M., & Ellison, G. T. H. (2016). Robust causal inference using directed acyclic graphs: The R package ‘Dagitty’. International Journal of Epidemiology, 45(6), 18871894.Google ScholarPubMed
Trivers, R L. (1974). Parent–offspring conflict. American Zoologist, 14(1), 249264. https://doi.org/10.1093/icb/14.1.249.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Voland, E. (1998). Evolutionary ecology of human reproduction. Annual Review of Anthropology, 27, 347374. https://doi.org/10.1146/annurev.anthro.27.1.347.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Walker, R. S., Gurven, M., Burger, O., & Hamilton, M. J. (2008). The trade-off between number and size of offspring in humans and other primates. Proceedings of the Royal Society B: Biological Sciences, 275(1636), 827833. https://doi.org/10.1098/rspb.2007.1511.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Walker, R. S., Hill, K. R., Flinn, M. V., & Ellsworth, R. M. (2011). Evolutionary history of hunter–gatherer marriage practices. PLoS ONE, 6(4), 27. https://doi.org/10.1371/journal.pone.0019066.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Wamoyi, J., Fenwick, A., Urassa, M., Zaba, B., & Stones, W. (2011a). Parental control and monitoring of young people's sexual behaviour in rural north-western Tanzania: Implications for sexual and reproductive health interventions. BMC Public Health, 11(1), 106. https://doi.org/10.1186/1471-2458-11-106.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Wamoyi, J., Fenwick, A., Urassa, M., Zaba, B., & Stones, W. (2011b). Socio-economic change and parent–child relationships: Implications for parental control and HIV prevention among young people in rural north western Tanzania. Culture, Health and Sexuality, 13(6), 615628. https://doi.org/10.1080/13691058.2011.562305.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Weissner, P. (2009). Parent–offspring conflict in marriage: Implications for social evolution and material culture among the Ju/’hoansi Bushmen. In Shennan, S. (Ed.) Pattern and process in cultural evolution (pp. 251263). University of California Press.Google Scholar
Figure 0

Figure 1. The directed acyclic graph (DAG) of all the predicted causal relationships between the variables included in the analysis. As this DAG underpins different model sets, variables have not been labelled as ‘exposures’ and/or ‘outcomes’, nor have the causal or biasing paths been highlighted.

Figure 1

Table 1. Marriage characteristics by marriage type

Figure 2

Table 2. Woman's, husband's and family's status by marriage type

Figure 3

Figure 2. Women's marriage type, age at marriage, marriage to relative, and education by current age (n = 1598).

Figure 4

Figure 3. Women's father's and husband's years of education by women's current age.

Figure 5

Figure 4. Predicted probability of marrying a relative and 95% confidence intervals by marriage type and years of education based on model 4.

Figure 6

Figure 5. Visualisation of traditional and market integrated pathways to a high-quality spouse/marriage.

Supplementary material: File

Schaffnit et al. supplementary material

Schaffnit et al. supplementary material 1

Download Schaffnit et al. supplementary material(File)
File 18.4 KB
Supplementary material: PDF

Schaffnit et al. supplementary material

Schaffnit et al. supplementary material 2

Download Schaffnit et al. supplementary material(PDF)
PDF 341.8 KB
Supplementary material: File

Schaffnit et al. supplementary material

Schaffnit et al. supplementary material 3

Download Schaffnit et al. supplementary material(File)
File 20.8 KB