Hostname: page-component-586b7cd67f-rdxmf Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-11-21T23:31:23.909Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Willingness-to-Pay for Rationed Goods: Bobcat Harvest Permits in Indiana

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  22 January 2024

Nicholas A. Lancaster
Affiliation:
Department of Agricultural Economics, Purdue University, West Lafayette, IN, USA
Carson J. Reeling*
Affiliation:
Department of Agricultural Economics, Purdue University, West Lafayette, IN, USA
John G. Lee
Affiliation:
Department of Agricultural Economics, Purdue University, West Lafayette, IN, USA
Richard T. Melstrom
Affiliation:
School of Environmental Sustainability, Loyola University Chicago, Chicago, IL, USA
Joe N. Caudell
Affiliation:
Indiana Department of Natural Resources, Division of Fish and Wildlife, Bloomington, IN, USA
Geriann Albers
Affiliation:
Indiana Department of Natural Resources, Division of Fish and Wildlife, Bloomington, IN, USA
*
Corresponding author: Carson J. Reeling; Email: [email protected]
Rights & Permissions [Opens in a new window]

Abstract

We use contingent valuation to estimate hunter and trapper willingness to pay (WTP) for a hypothetical bobcat harvest permit being considered in Indiana. Harvest permits would be rationed, with limits on aggregate and individual harvests. A model of permit demand shows that WTP may be subject to “congestion effects” which attenuate welfare gains from relaxing harvest limits. Intuitively, relaxing limits may directly change an individual’s expected harvest and, hence, WTP. Participation may subsequently change, with congestion offsetting welfare increases. These effects may lead to apparent scope insensitivity that may be endemic in the context of rationed goods.

Type
Research Article
Creative Commons
Creative Common License - CCCreative Common License - BY
This is an Open Access article, distributed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution licence (http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/), which permits unrestricted re-use, distribution and reproduction, provided the original article is properly cited.
Copyright
© The Author(s), 2024. Published by Cambridge University Press on behalf of Southern Agricultural Economics Association

1. Introduction

Management of Indiana bobcats with a closed harvest season has resulted in the population growing substantially after declining for decades due to agricultural development and unregulated harvest (Johnson et al., Reference Johnson, Walker and Hudson2010). Bobcat sightings have been reported in nearly every Indiana county (INDNR, 2022) and recent research in the state has been conducted to create a bobcat population model (Jones et al., Reference Jones, Zollner, Swihart, Godollei, Hudson and Johnson2020; Jones et al., Reference Jones, Johnson, Hudson, Zollner and Swihart2022a; Reference Jones, Swihart, Gliech, Albers, Johnson, Hudson and Zollner2022b). With a growing population in portions of the state (Johnson et al., Reference Johnson, Walker and Hudson2010), there is increased pressure to allow some regulated hunting and/or trapping. The Indiana Department of Natural Resources’ (INDNR) mission is to enrich the quality of life for present and future generations by balancing the biological, ecological, recreational, and economic benefits of Indiana’s fish, wildlife, and habitats (INDNR, 2023). This means, like with many state agencies, if there is interest in regulated hunting and trapping of a species and it can be done while maintaining the population, the agency may consider a regulated hunting and/or trapping season. Therefore, it is important for wildlife managers to understand hunter and trapper demand for harvesting bobcats when considering management options.

To this end, we use the contingent valuation method (CVM) to estimate willingness to pay (WTP) for a hypothetical bobcat harvest permit among resident Indiana hunters and trappers. CVM has been used to analyze new markets and demands for recreation permits (Sutton et al., Reference Sutton, Stoll and Ditton2001). The methodology has been used to estimate WTP for wildlife, allowing wildlife managers to set harvest regulations more efficiently. For example, Adhikari et al. (Reference Adhikari, Poudyal, Muller and Yoest2023) and Ufer et al. (Reference Ufer, Christensen, Ortega, Pinizzotto and Schuler2022) use CVM to value programs to fund chronic wasting disease control in Tennessee and Michigan, respectively. Mattsson et al. (Reference Mattsson, Boman and Ezebilo2014) use CVM to value moose hunting in Sweden. Brunke et al. (Reference Brunke, Hunt, Grado and Parks2006) use CVM to estimate hunter demand and WTP for hypothetical fall and spring turkey hunting licenses in Mississippi. Sutton et al. (Reference Sutton, Stoll and Ditton2001) use CVM to estimate angler WTP for fishing licenses and determine how prices affect angler access and regulator revenues. Sutton et al. (Reference Sutton, Stoll and Ditton2001) emphasize the importance of balancing regulator profits from license sales with angler participation. In terms of predatory wildlife species, CVM has predominantly been used to estimate the value of preservation of an endangered or protected species. For example, Broberg and Brännlund (Reference Broberg and Brännlund2008), Ericsson et al. (Reference Ericsson, Bostedt and Kindberg2008), and Chambers and Whitehead (Reference Chambers and Whitehead2003) use CVM to estimate WTP for wolf preservation.

We mailed a questionnaire to 2,000 registered Indiana hunters and trappers with a detailed description of a proposed bobcat harvest season structure. We then presented them with a single-bounded dichotomous choice question asking whether they would buy a permit to participate in the described season. We used responses to this question to estimate the distribution of WTP using standard discrete choice estimators. We find mean WTP for a permit with a bag limit (or maximum harvest per person per season) of one animal and a statewide harvest quota (or the limit on the aggregate annual harvest of bobcats) of 300 animals to be $13.50. To our knowledge, no prior work estimates WTP for bobcat harvest permits in Indiana or elsewhere.

Best practice in conducting a CVM study is to demonstrate validity of the WTP estimates by testing for consequentiality and scope effects. Consequentiality implies that respondents who believe the survey results will impact policy have different WTP than those who do not hold such beliefs (Herriges et al., Reference Herriges, Kling, Liu and Tobias2010; Interis and Petrolia, Reference Interis and Petrolia2014). Scope effects are present whenever WTP varies systematically with the quality or quantity of a good (Johnston et al., Reference Johnston, Boyle, Adamowicz, Bennett, Brouwer, Cameron, Hanemann, Hanley, Ryan, Scarpa, Tourangeau and Vossler2017). Testing for scope effects in the context of rationed goods like a hunting permit is not straightforward, however. Intuitively, hunter utility and, hence, welfare should increase with the number of animals they expect to harvest. Yet harvests are limited in aggregate by statewide quotas and individually by bag limits that restrict the number of animals a single hunter can take. We show that relaxing either quotas or bag limits can create general equilibrium effects that have countervailing impacts on expected harvest, clouding interpretation of scope effects. To our knowledge, this has not been noted in prior research. We explore how individuals respond to changes in bag limits and quotas and find that the resulting scope effects are consistent with intuition. Our discussion clarifies the role of these variables in testing for scope effects in the provision of rationed goods.

2. A theoretical model of bobcat harvest permit demand under rationing

We start by deriving a random utility maximization (RUM) model of bobcat harvest permits under rationing. Assume a regulatory agency sets a statewide harvest quota of x 1 bobcats. The quota limits the total number of bobcats that can be harvested in aggregate by all hunters within a given season; there is no restriction on the quantity of harvest permits sold, but we assume the harvest season ends when the x 1 th bobcat is harvested. Footnote 1 Harvests by a single individual are subject to a bag limit, x 2. We, therefore, let X = [x 0 x 1 x 2] denote the vector of harvest permit attributes including a constant term, x 0, that accounts for other, unobserved factors that influence the utility from harvesting relative to the utility from not purchasing a permit.

The number of licensed hunters, or those who decided to purchase a permit at a given price p, is n. The expected harvest for a hunter who purchases a permit is $H({\bf X},n)$ , where we assume H x 1 > 0 and H n < 0. Intuitively, the expected harvest is increasing in the quota because a larger quota means hunters are more likely to harvest an animal prior to the quota being met in aggregate. Conversely, the expected harvest decreases with the number of hunters because a fixed quota is more likely to get filled before a hunter can successfully fill their own bag limit. The sign of H x 2 is ambiguous. If the quota binds, a larger bag limit may reduce one’s expected harvest; everyone’s ability to harvest more animals implies the quota may be filled more quickly, and hence an individual hunter may have fewer chances to harvest his or her own animals. If the quota does not bind, then increasing the bag limit will increase harvest.

Let the utility hunter i receives be $U_{i}(H_{i}({\bf X},n),y_{i};{\bf Z}_{i})+\varepsilon _{i}$ , where y i is the hunter’s income absent any permit expenditures, Z i is a K-dimensional vector of personal characteristics, and ε i is an unobserved shock. We assume ∂U i /∂H, ∂U i /∂y i ≥ 0. The probability hunter i chooses to purchase a permit with attributes X and price p is

(1) $$\pi \left( {{\bf{X}},n,{y_i},p,{{\bf{Z}}_i}} \right) = \Pr \left( {{U_i}\left( {{H_i}\left( {{\boldsymbol X},n} \right),{y_i} - p;{{\bf{Z}}_i}} \right) + {\varepsilon _{i1}} \ge U\left( {0,{y_i};{{\bf{Z}}_i}} \right) + {\varepsilon _{i0}}} \right)$$

where the subscript on ε denotes different states of the world (i.e., whether the hunter purchases a permit or not). Of course, n depends endogenously on π(⋅). Let the total number of potential hunters in the market for a permit be N. Then

(2) $$n = N\int \cdots \int \pi \left( {{\bf{X}},n,y,p,{\bf{Z}}} \right)f\left( {{\bf{Z}},y} \right){\rm{d}}{z_1} \cdots {\rm{d}}{z_K}{\rm{d}}y,$$

where f (⋅) is the joint density of the hunters’ demographic characteristics. The equilibrium number of hunters, $n\left( {{\bf{X}},p,N} \right)$ , solves (2). We can then rewrite the representative hunter’s utility with the permit as $U\left( {{H_i}\left( {{\bf{X}},n\left( {{\bf{X}},p,N} \right)} \right),{y_i} - p;{{\bf{Z}}_i}} \right)$ . A first-order Taylor series expansion of U(⋅) around some arbitrary $\tilde{{\bf X}}$ , $\tilde p$ , $\tilde y$ i , and $\tilde N$ yields

(3) $$U\left( {{\bf{X}},{y_i} - p,N} \right) \approx {\alpha _i} + {{\bf{\unicode{x03B2} }}}_i^{'}{\bf{X}} - \left( {{\mu _i} - {\lambda _i}} \right){p_i} + {\mu _i}{y_i} + {\theta _i}N,$$

where

(4a) $${\alpha _i} = {\left. {\left[ {\matrix{ {{U_i} - \mathop \sum \nolimits_j {{\partial {U_i}} \over {\partial {H_i}}}\left( {{{\partial {H_i}} \over {\partial {x_j}}} + {{\partial {H_i}} \over {\partial n}}{{\partial n} \over {\partial {x_j}}}} \right){{\tilde x}_j} - {{\partial {U_i}} \over {\partial {H_i}}}{{\partial {H_i}} \over {\partial n}}{{\partial n} \over {\partial {y_i}}}\tilde p} \cr { - {{\partial {U_i}} \over {\partial {y_i}}}\left( {{{\tilde y}_i} - \tilde p} \right) - {{\partial {U_i}} \over {\partial {H_i}}}{{\partial {H_i}} \over {\partial n}}{{\partial n} \over {\partial N}}\tilde N} \cr } } \right]} \right|_{{\bf{\tilde X}},\tilde p,{{\tilde y}_i},\tilde N}},$$
(4b) $$\hskip-50pt{\beta _{ij}} = {\left. {{{\partial {U_i}} \over {\partial {H_i}}}\left( {{{\partial {H_i}} \over {\partial {x_j}}} + {{\partial {H_i}} \over {\partial n}}{{\partial n} \over {\partial {x_j}}}} \right)} \right|_{{\bf{\tilde X}},\tilde p,{{\tilde y}_i},\tilde N}},j = 0,1,2,$$
(4c) $$\hskip-168pt{\mu _i} = {\left. {{{\partial {U_i}} \over {\partial {y_i}}}} \right|_{{\bf{\tilde X}},\tilde p,{{\tilde y}_i},\tilde N}},$$
(4d) $$\hskip-140pt\lambda _{i}=\left.{\partial U_{i} \over \partial H_{i}}{\partial H_{i} \over \partial n}{\partial n \over \partial y_{i}}\right| _{\tilde{{\bf X}},\tilde{p},{\tilde{y}_{i}},\tilde{N}}$$

and

(4e) $$\hskip-136pt\theta =\left.{\partial U\over \partial H}{\partial H\over \partial n}{\partial n \over \partial N}\right| _{\tilde{{\bf X}},\tilde{p},{\tilde{y}_{i}},\tilde{N}}.$$

Substituting (3) into (1) and simplifying yields ${\pi _i} = \Pr \left( {{\bf{\unicode{x03B2}}}_i^{'}{\bf{X}} + {\eta _i}{p_i} \ge - \left[ {{\varepsilon _{i1}} - {\varepsilon _{i0}}} \right]} \right)$ ,

where η i = − (μ i λ i ). Assuming the difference in error terms follows a logistic distribution, we can estimate this choice probability using a standard logit model. Note that heterogeneity in preference parameters β i and η i can be attained in general via a random parameter or mixed logit approach or by simply interacting the permit attributes X by respondent characteristics Z i . We use the latter approach when presenting estimates later. The definitions of the parameters in (4a)–(4e) inform our discussion of scope effects below.

Given estimates ${{\bf{\hat{\unicode{x03B2}}}}}_i$ and ${\hat \eta _i}$ , and noting that E(ε i1ε i0) = 0 given our distributional assumption, mean WTP for a permit with attributes X is

(5) $$E\left( {WT{P_i}} \right) = \int \cdots \int {{\bf{\hat{\unicode{x03B2}}}}}_i^{'}{\bf{X}}/\left| {{{\hat \eta }_i}} \right|f\left( {\bf{Z}} \right){\rm{d}}{z_1} \cdots {\rm{d}}{z_K}.$$

3. Survey and data

We estimate (5) for a bobcat harvest permit using data from a mail survey of 2000 Indiana hunters and trappers in summer 2021 following the protocols outlined by Dillman et al. (Reference Dillman, Smyth and Christian2014). Respondent addresses were randomly drawn from the INDNR’s license sales database. Because relatively few people trap in Indiana, we oversampled trappers by sending half of the questionnaires to those who purchased a trapping license and the other half to those who purchased a hunting license. Footnote 2 The INDNR uses 10 regional management units (RMUs) consisting of similar counties for managing deer populations and harvest (Swihart et al., Reference Swihart, Caudell, Brooke and Ma2020). RMUS 3, 4, and 9 (Fig. 1) were oversampled as the INDNR is sponsoring intensive wildlife population modeling and economic research in these regions. Our survey is a component of these efforts, and hence we attempted to ensure our data adequately captures preferences of sportspersons in these areas. Footnote 3 Twice as many respondents were solicited from the aforementioned RMUs due to the predator-prey relationship between bobcats and deer. The 1,000 trapper addresses represent 21.5% of licensed trappers in the state. By contrast, the 1,000 hunter addresses represent less than one percent of licensed hunters. This oversampling is important because trapping is the primary means by which we expect bobcats would be harvested in Indiana. Of the active furbearer harvesters responding to our survey, only 19% exclusively harvest furbearers through hunting, 37% harvest exclusively through trapping, and the remaining 44% both hunt and trap. Of our respondents, 121 reported that they hunted and trapped in the most recent season.

Figure 1. Regional management units for Indiana.

The questionnaire consisted of five sections. The first section collected general information about respondents’ furbearer harvesting activities and contained the CVM question; we describe this question in detail below. Sections 2 and 3 asked about respondents’ travel and equipment expenses relating to furbearer hunting and trapping, respectively. Section 4 asked respondents to provide their opinions on furbearer hunting or trapping using a Likert scale to gauge levels of agreement. Section 5 collected demographic information, including gender, age, race, household income, and education. A copy of the questionnaire is provided in Appendix A.

In Section 1, respondents were given a description of a proposed bobcat season that outlined regulations including locations of legal harvest, statewide quota, individual bag limits, harvest equipment, and proposed procedures for checking in harvested bobcats. After this description, respondents were asked if they would be willing to purchase a bobcat permit for a given, experimentally-generated price. Figure 2 provides an example of this question. The permit price was randomly drawn for each respondent from a distribution comprising values $6.75, $9.25, $11.25, $19.25, $24, and $45 per year. Footnote 4 For context, the smallest price is the same as that of existing hunting stamps in Indiana (e.g., game bird habitat or waterfowl stamps, both of which are $6.75). Footnote 5 The largest price is approximately double that of existing large game permits (e.g., deer permits are $24 and turkey permits are $25). Prices in other Midwestern states range from approximately $5 to $10 for permits with similar bag limits, quotas, and seasons, although many other states (e.g., Michigan, Illinois, and Wisconsin) allocate licenses via lotteries and hence these prices simply represent application fees. In any case, as price equals marginal WTP at equilibrium, we believe our price range provides reasonable coverage of the distribution of WTP.

Figure 2. Bobcat willingness to pay question with randomly varying quotas, bag limits, and license prices presented to respondents.

The use of a single dichotomous choice question to elicit WTP is standard and incentive-compatible (Carson and Groves, Reference Carson and Groves2007; Freeman, Reference Freeman2003). Other elicitation formats (e.g., double-bounded dichotomous choice, payment card, or experimental auction) would provide more information. However, the single-bound dichotomous choice format fits the nature of the goods being valued in our CVM problem; hunters and trappers are used to paying a single, stated price for a harvest permit. Alternative formats risk making the decision problem seem unrealistic.

The “baseline” bobcat permit has a bag limit of one animal and a statewide quota of 300. In our survey, the statewide quota varied randomly among respondents, with half receiving a quota of 300 and half of 600. The bag limit also varied randomly among respondents and independently of price and quota, with half receiving an individual bag limit of one and half a bag limit of two. The bag limits and statewide quotas were suggested by INDNR biologists and deemed as reasonable parameters for initial bobcat harvests. Variation in the quota and bag limit, akin to a 2 × 2 experimental design, allows us to test for scope effects.

Following the payment question, respondents who indicated they would not purchase a permit were asked a follow-up question to determine why they would not do so, which aided in identifying protest responses. Finally, we asked respondents a series of Likert scale questions to gauge how they felt their responses would impact the creation of a bobcat permit in Indiana. The questions asked if respondents felt i) their responses would affect the creation of a bobcat season; ii) overall survey responses would affect the creation of a bobcat season; and iii) the INDNR would charge the price the respondent was presented for a bobcat permit if a season was created (Fig. 3). These questions were meant to assess consequentiality and are a standard means of assessing the validity of responses to CVM questions (Johnston et al., Reference Johnston, Boyle, Adamowicz, Bennett, Brouwer, Cameron, Hanemann, Hanley, Ryan, Scarpa, Tourangeau and Vossler2017).

Figure 3. Consequentiality questions presented to respondents.

We pretested the survey using three focus group discussions conducted via Zoom in May 2021. Participants comprised experienced furbearer hunters and trappers known to INDNR biologists and included four furbearer trappers and an individual who both hunted and trapped furbearers. Participants completed our draft survey beforehand and gave us feedback on each question during the discussion. The final draft of the survey shown in Appendix A reflects this feedback. We chose our price distribution based on focus group feedback using a modification of the CVM question in Fig. 2. Formally, we used an open-ended question asking participants to state their WTP for the bobcat permit we described. We recorded their responses and fit a PERT distribution to these data. The prices we chose correspond with the 0th, 15th, 30th, 70th, 85th, and 100th percentiles of the fitted distribution.

Following Dillman et al. (Reference Dillman, Smyth and Christian2014), we initially mailed the questionnaire to respondents on July 2, 2021, followed two weeks later by a reminder postcard. We mailed a second questionnaire to nonrespondents two weeks after the reminder postcard. In total, we received 422 responses. We subsequently screened out those we judged to be protest responses (identified by selection of multiple responses when only one response was requested, inclusion of offensive comments in the survey, returning a blank survey, or returning a cover letter only and/or an offensive letter). We identified 15 surveys as protests, and an additional 8 respondents did not answer the WTP question, leaving us with 399 usable responses. Although this 20% response rate is lower than typical for surveys of wildlife-associated recreation, response rates in this literature have been trending downward (Stedman et al., Reference Stedman, Connelly, Heberlein, Decker and Allred2019) and are usually lowest in surveys that include stated preference questions (e.g., Whitehead, Reference Whitehead1993; Melstrom and Kaefer, Reference Melstrom and Kaefer2020).

Table 1 presents respondent demographics. Our respondents were predominantly white (97%) and male (98%), without a post-secondary degree (62%), with a household income of less than $100,000 annually (74%), and with an average age of 52.6 years. This is broadly consistent with the distribution of hunter characteristics for the US as a whole (see the final column in Table 1; US DOI et al., 2016); nationally, hunters are predominantly middle-aged (46.7 years old) white (98.2%) males (90.3%), without a bachelor’s degree (66.6%) and earn an annual household income of less than $100,000 (70.3%). However, tests of proportions indicate that our sample is more male, older, and less well-educated.

Table 1. Demographic information from the 399 survey respondents

a Figures may not sum to one due to rounding.

b Superscript * denotes sample estimates that differ from population estimates at the 5 percent level or better.

c NSFHWAR refers to the 2016 National Survey of Fishing, Hunting, and Wildlife-Associated Recreation. This data reports the proportion of individuals with 1–3 years of college. This is equivalent to the sum of our “some college” and “associate’s degree or equivalent” figures. We therefore combine these estimates when comparing against the population data.

Respondents received a hypothetical bobcat hunting/trapping season description with one of four bag and quota combinations. Proportions of usable surveys received were nearly equal across bag and quota combinations, with 25.3% receiving bag limit = 1 and quota = 300, 25.6% receiving bag limit = 1 and quota = 600, 23.6% receiving bag limit = 2, quota = 300, and 25.6% receiving bag limit = 2 and quota = 600. Table 2 is a balance table that shows respondent demographics by treatment. Pairs of figures marked with common superscripts denote attributes that are statistically different from one another at the 5% level or better. The subsamples are largely similar across treatments.

Table 2. Balance table showing demographics for each treatmenta,b

a All figures are proportions unless otherwise noted.

b Superscripts * and ** indicate pairs of estimates that are statistically different from one another at the 5% level. For example, the proportion of respondents with income between $100,000 and $149,999 are different for the Bag limit = 1, quota = 300 and Bag limit = 1, quota = 600 treatments (indicated by the * superscript) and for the Bag limit = 1, quota = 600 and Bag limit = 2, quota = 600 treatments (indicated by the ** superscript).

4. Results

The first and last columns in Table 3 show parameter estimates for two specifications of our RUM model. The specifications differ in the combination of sociodemographic characteristics Z i included as covariates. Model 1 includes no demographics and assumes respondents’ preferences over bobcat permits are homogeneous. Model 2 includes age, education, and a dummy variable equal to one if the respondent reported harvesting furbearers to sell for income. Our hypothesis is that respondents with potential financial motivations for harvesting bobcats may have a different objective function than those who only harvest furbearers recreationally. We represent education as a dummy variable equal to one if the respondent has attended college and zero otherwise.

Table 3. Logit model parameter estimates

a Standard errors are in parentheses below each coefficient.

The estimated coefficients on price are negative, statistically significant at the five percent level or better, and are of similar magnitudes across models. In Model 1, we find utility increases with the bag limit, whereas increasing the quota has no statistically significant effect. Interpretation of the coefficients in other models is not straightforward due to the interactions between covariates.

To assess fit, we estimated each model using only the respondents for which we observe all covariates included in Model 2 and calculate the corresponding Akaike and Bayesian Information Criteria. We find that Model 1 fits the data best, and hence we use these estimates in calculating WTP.

Figure 4 shows WTP estimates for our RUM model. We calculate 95% confidence intervals using the delta method. The first bar shows WTP for the baseline bobcat permit (i.e., a bag limit of one and a statewide quota of 300) among all respondents, regardless of their answers to the consequentiality questions in Fig. 3. Mean WTP is $13.50, although this estimate is not statistically significantly different from zero (p = 0.106).

Figure 4. Willingness to pay estimates from the RUM model.

As a robustness check, we also estimate WTP using a nonparametric Turnbull estimator. For conciseness, we describe this estimator and present results in Appendix B. Mean WTP under the Turnbull estimator is $21.73.

4.1. Consequentiality

We performed two tests of the validity of this baseline estimate. The first assesses consequentiality among our respondents. Specifically, we compare our baseline WTP estimate to that estimated from subsamples of respondents comprising (i) only those who agreed to at least one of the three consequentiality statements in Fig. 3 and (ii) those who did not agree to any of the consequentiality statements. We consider a respondent to have agreed with a consequentiality statement if they indicated that they “Somewhat Agree” or “Strongly Agree.” This comparison provides insight into how seriously participants believe their responses will impact the creation of a bobcat season at the price they received. We anticipate those with nonconsequential responses will have a different and potentially nonsensical distribution of WTP than those with consequential beliefs (Herriges et al., Reference Herriges, Kling, Liu and Tobias2010; Interis and Petrolia, Reference Interis and Petrolia2014). Roughly two-thirds of respondents who saw the baseline permit agreed with the consequentiality statements. The second column of Table 3 shows parameter estimates for this model, and we find mean WTP among those respondents to be $34.85 (see the bars labeled “consequentiality comparisons” in Fig. 4). This estimate is statistically significant. In contrast, mean WTP is actually negative among those who do not agree with the consequentiality statements. The 95% confidence interval is large and includes zero. Our Turnbull estimates presented in the appendix find a similar decrease in mean WTP, and the difference in WTP between those who do and do not find the survey consequential is statistically significant.

4.2. Scope effects

From (5), scope effects of changing the quota and bag limit will depend on the signs of β i , which depends on two terms (see (4b)). The first, (∂U i /∂H i )(∂H i /∂x j ), we call the “direct” scope effect from changing attribute j. This term measures the ceteris paribus effect of changing the quota or bag limit on harvest and, hence, utility, since ∂U i /∂H i > 0 by assumption. The second term, (∂U i /∂H i )(∂H i /∂n)(∂n/∂x j ), is the “congestion” scope effect from changing attribute j. Intuitively, changing the permit attributes may affect the number of hunters who purchase a permit and attempt to harvest bobcats, n. Since ∂H i /∂n < 0 by assumption, a positive value for ∂n/∂x j will generate greater competition for harvests, reducing harvests and, hence, welfare for the representative hunter.

Consider first the quota effect β i1 reported in the first column of Table 3. We would expect the direct effect to be positive; increasing the quota while holding bag limits fixed increases the probability an individual hunter can fill his or her bag limit before the aggregate quota is met. The congestion effect is negative, however, as ∂n/∂x 1 > 0 given the logistic distribution for the ε terms and ∂H/∂n ≤ 0. Hence, the congestion effect attenuates the direct effect of increasing the quota. This is consistent with our estimates, which show no statistically significant scope effects from changing the quota across any of the models.

Consider next the effect of the bag limit β i2 reported in the first column of Table 3. The scope effects from changing the bag limit are ambiguous given our lack of intuition about the sign of ∂H/∂x 2. If ∂H/∂x 2 > 0, then the direct effect of changing the bag limit will be positive, but the congestion effect will attenuate the scope effect, as above. If ∂H/∂x 2 < 0, then the direct effect is negative but the congestion effect is positive; increasing the bag limit will reduce WTP due to increased competition given the fixed quota, but this will reduce permit demand (i.e., n will decline), attenuating the negative direct effect. We find mixed evidence of this effect in our logit and Turnbull estimates.

Estimates of WTP for different combinations of the bobcat bag limit and statewide quotas are labeled “scope effects comparisons” in Fig. 4. Increasing the quota has a negative but statistically indiscernible effect on WTP, consistent with the negative but statistically insignificant coefficient on quota shown in the first column of Table 3. Increasing the bag limit has a large and positive effect on mean WTP regardless of the quota. The nonparametric Turnbull estimates in the appendix reveal slightly different scope effects; increasing the bag limit while holding the quota fixed at 300 decreases WTP, whereas increasing the quota while holding the bag limit fixed at two increases WTP (although neither of these differences is statistically significant.) Taken together, we find no systematic relationship between WTP and the quantity respondents are allowed to harvest either individually or in aggregate. This is consistent with our theoretical results showing that we may expect variable scope effects in permit demand.

5. Discussion and conclusion

Wildlife managers are facing declines in hunting participation across the U.S. (Enck et al., Reference Enck, Mattfeld and Decker1996, Reference Enck, Decker and Brown2000; Mehmood et al., Reference Mehmood, Zhang and Armstrong2003; Miller and Vaske, Reference Miller and Vaske2003; US DOI et al., 2016; US DOI et al., 2011). While permit fees have historically been kept low, with marginal fee increases disproportionately low in relation to changes in the cost of living (Sutton et al., Reference Sutton, Stoll and Ditton2001), reduced hunting participation forces wildlife managers to increase permit prices or create new permits in order to maintain funding for wildlife management (Brunke et al., Reference Brunke, Hunt, Grado and Parks2006). Research has confirmed a significant inverse relationship between permit fees and the number of permits purchased (Brunke et al., Reference Brunke, Hunt, Grado and Parks2006). Therefore, regulators must exercise caution when setting permit fees. This paper shines new light on the relationship between permit fees and demand by measuring hunters’ WTP for a new permit. Because bobcats currently have no hunting or trapping season in Indiana, we cannot measure the effect of price on demand using historic permit sales data. Furthermore, we cannot estimate WTP using revealed preference valuation methods that rely on observing individual decisions to purchase a good or undertake an activity; there simply are no such data as bobcat harvest is not allowed. Hence, we must use stated preference methods – which draw on individuals’ choices in hypothetical scenarios – to estimate WTP for bobcat permits. We use CVM, under which individuals are asked whether they would be willing to pay an experimentally generated price to acquire the scenario or good (Sorg and Loomis, Reference Sorg and Loomis1985). Responses to these questions can be used to estimate the number of individuals who would make the purchase at any given price (Brookshire et al., Reference Brookshire, Randall and Stoll1980).

CVM, like other stated preference methods, is flexible but may be subject to biases, including strategic behavior, information bias, and instrument biases (Schulze et al., Reference Schulze, d'Arge and Brookshire1981). The presence of bias is due to the reliance of CVM upon an individual’s response to a hypothetical market (Stoll, Reference Stoll1983). In a recent meta-analysis, Penn and Hu (Reference Penn and Hu2018) found that this hypothetical bias can inflate measures of WTP by nearly 200% relative to their true values, although the use of questions that assess consequentiality (like we include in our questionnaire; Fig. 3) can mitigate this bias.

Tests of consequentiality and scope effects can also provide evidence of the validity of CVM estimates. Indeed, consequentiality has been deemed necessary to ensure incentive compatibility and is broadly defined as the belief that the respondent’s choice will influence policy with a non-zero probability (Carson et al., Reference Carson, Groves and List2014; Herriges et al., Reference Herriges, Kling, Liu and Tobias2010; Vossler et al., Reference Vossler, Doyon and Rondeau2012). Herriges et al. (Reference Herriges, Kling, Liu and Tobias2010) find that respondents who perceived a survey as inconsequential had a lower WTP than those who perceived the survey to be at least slightly consequential in the creation of the policy. Similarly, our test of consequentiality reveals a significant change in the distribution of WTP for those who do not believe their answers will affect bobcat management policy.

Reduced perception of consequentiality among respondents may be linked to the level of trust placed in the regulatory agency. Distrust in regulatory agencies’ ability to effectively manage wildlife and the resulting destructive behavior of hunters is well-documented in the literature. Illegal harvests of wolves in Denmark have been linked to distrust of authorities setting regulations to mitigate the negative impacts of wolves (Højberg et al., Reference Højberg, Nielsen and Jacobsen.2017). Muth and Bowe’s (2008) review on illegal harvests in North America revealed that disagreement with regulations was one of the top drivers of poaching. While our survey does not touch upon the subject of poaching, we propose that finding diminished or zero WTP for an economically important species could be linked to regulator trust. Distrust in a regulatory agency may originate from differing ideals. Gigliotti et al. (Reference Gigliotti, Sweikert, Cornicelli and Fulton2020) showed that trust in the Minnesota Department of Natural Resources was tied to landowners’ beliefs, with landowners holding similar conservation values, placing greater trust in the regulatory agency. Similarly, Manfredo et al. (Reference Manfredo, Teel, Sullivan and Dietsch2017) surveyed residents across the United States and found that residents with conservation principles similar to regulatory agencies were more likely to place trust in the regulator relative to those who are skeptical of government regulation of wildlife. Likewise, a 2021 survey of Indiana residents regarding deer management showed level of trust in the manager is predominantly linked to respondents’ characteristics (Stinchcomb et al., Reference Stinchcomb, Ma, Swihart and Caudell2022). Possibly, lower WTP among the individuals who did not perceive our survey as consequential could be due to beliefs that governance of wildlife is undesirable.

We found mixed evidence of scope effects. This could be due to countervailing indirect effects in equilibrium. Evaluating scope effects in the context of rationed goods like bobcat harvest permits is not theoretically straightforward, as we demonstrate here. That aggregate harvests are fixed at a given quota level implies hunters’ expected harvests will depend on the number of hunters who purchase a permit and compete to fill their bag limit. Since we expect hunter utility – and hence the share of potential hunters that purchase a permit – is increasing in expected harvest, the number of hunters and expected harvest are determined endogenously as a function of the bag limit and quota. To the extent that these permit attributes have different ceteris paribus impacts on expected harvest, then increasing either the bag limit or quota may systematically affect equilibrium participation – and hence expected harvest and WTP – in different and countervailing ways. Discerning which attribute is most relevant for testing scope effects in the context of rationed goods is important for demonstrating the validity of WTP estimates; however, to our knowledge, no prior work addresses this issue. We leave a more rigorous study of this question for future research. Finally, there are some counterintuitive and inconsistent scope effects when comparing the logit estimates with the Turnbull estimates in the appendix. One possible explanation is that our data are simply noisy. Another explanation is that differences are due to the relative flexibility of the Turnbull model, which imposes no distributional assumptions on WTP.

Indiana is among seven U.S. states that have bobcat populations but do not have open regulated hunting or trapping seasons for bobcats. Our WTP estimate can provide information to these jurisdictions should they consider a regulated season, allowing them to have some baseline information on how to price a stand-alone bobcat license. For states that allow the take of bobcats on existing hunting or trapping licenses, it can aid agencies in justifying license price increases by understanding the value-added of expanding a license to include bobcats.

More broadly, this paper demonstrates a methodology that state agencies can use to set license prices as they have additional species for which they are considering new harvest opportunities. Many states are seeing population expansions for wildlife, whether due to climate change (Thomas, Reference Thomas2010), species recovery (e.g., LaRue et al., Reference LaRue, Nielsen, Dowling, Miller, Wilson, Shaw and Anderson2012; Roberts and Crimmins, Reference Roberts and Crimmins2010), or reintroduction programs (e.g., Bricker et al., Reference Bricker, Serfass, Hanley, Stevens, Pearce, Bohrman, Bricker, Serfass, Hanley, Stevens, Pearce and Bohrman2022; Popp et al., Reference Popp, Toman, Mallory and Hamr2014). For some species, that leads to considerations of limited, regulated seasons, such as in 2021 when Missouri opened its first regulated black bear season or Nebraska opened its first regulated river otter season. Because a basic tenant of wildlife management is to work to ensure that most individuals have equitable access to hunting and fishing opportunities (Geist et al., Reference Geist, Mahoney and Organ2001), state agencies have a responsibility to ensure hunting opportunities do not become a highly desired but prohibitively expensive good. Having a viable technique to calculate WTP or having examples of WTP for certain species in the literature ensures state agencies have information to set pricing that finds a reasonable balance between cost and ensuring access to those who want to participate across income levels.

Supplementary material

The supplementary material for this article can be found at https://doi.org/10.1017/aae.2024.1.

Data availability statement

The data that support the findings of this study are available from the corresponding author, C.J.R., upon reasonable request.

Author contribution

Conceptualization: N.A.L., C.J.R., J.G.L., R.T.M., J.N.C., G.A.; Methodology: N.A.L., C.J.R.; Formal Analysis: N.A.L., C.J.R., R.T.M.; Data Curation: N.A.L., C.J.R.; Writing—Original Draft: N.A.L., C.J.R., J.G.L., R.T.M., J.N.C., G.A.; Writing – Review and Editing: N.A.L., C.J.R., J.G.L., R.T.M., J.N.C., G.A.; Supervision: C.J.R., J.G.L.; Funding Acquisition: C.J.R., J.G.L., R.T.M.

Competing interests

The authors declare none.

Funding statement

This project was funded by a Wildlife Restoration and Basic Hunter Education fund grant (F20AF11151, W-48-R-05) in cooperation with the Indiana Department of Natural Resources, Division of Fish & Wildlife, and the U.S. Fish & Wildlife Service.

Footnotes

1 This is consistent with the procedure being considered for bobcat harvests in Indiana and also matches the procedure used for regulating other species in the state. For example, harvests of river otters must be reported online within 24 hours. Prior to setting traps each day, trappers must check the IDNR website to confirm whether the season is still open. Harvests that take place after the season is closed are subject to forfeiture or other penalties.

2 Hunting licenses in the state of Indiana allow harvest of small game species (e.g., rabbits and squirrels), birds (e.g., doves and pheasants), and furbearers (e.g., coyotes, foxes, raccoons, opossums) exclusively through hunting methods.

3 A t-test finds respondents from RMUs 3, 4, and 9 are 6 percentage points more likely to identify as white and have incomes that are 10% smaller than those from other RMUs. Otherwise, the differences between the demographic characteristics of these groups of respondents are not statistically significant.

4 Non-integer-valued prices are not unusual for harvest permits in Indiana. For example, the current price of a combined hunting and fishing license for disabled veterans is $2.75 per year. Waterfowl and Game Bird stamps were $6.75 per year until 2022. Fishing license prices were $14.25 per year until the mid-2000s. We therefore do not believe that non-integer prices seemed unfamiliar or posed unreasonable cognitive demands on respondents, all of whom are licensed sportsmen and -women. We were sure to round prices to the nearest quarter for consistency with past real-world license prices.

5 Hunting stamps represent an enhancement of a standard hunting license which, when purchased, allow harvest of additional game species not covered by the standard license. These work similarly to the way we described the bobcat harvest permit in Fig. 2.

References

Adhikari, R.K., Poudyal, N.C., Muller, L.I., and Yoest, C.. “Hunter willingness-to-pay for disease testing: Evidence from chronic wasting disease in white-tailed deer.” Journal of Agricultural and Applied Economics 55,3(2023):115.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bricker, E.A., Serfass, T.L., Hanley, Z.L., Stevens, S.S., Pearce, K.J., and Bohrman, J.A.. “Conservation Status of the North American River Otter in the United States and Canada: Assessing Management Practices and Public Perceptions of the Species.” Small Carnivores: Evolution, Ecology, Behaviour, and Conservation. Bricker, E.A., Serfass, T.L., Hanley, Z.L., Stevens, S.S., Pearce, K.J., and Bohrman, J.A.., eds. Hoboken, N.J: Wiley, 2022.Google Scholar
Broberg, T., and Brännlund, R.. “On the value of large predators in Sweden: A regional stratified contingent valuation analysis.” Journal of Environmental Management 88,4(2008):1066–77.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Brookshire, D.S., Randall, A., and Stoll, J.R.. “Valuing increments and decrements in natural resource service flows.” American Journal of Agricultural Economics 62,3(1980):478–88.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Brunke, K.D., Hunt, K.M., Grado, S.C., and Parks, E.M.. “Willingness to pay for fall and spring turkey hunting permits in Mississippi.” Proceedings of the Southeast Association of Fish and Wildlife Agencies 60(2006):43–8.Google Scholar
Carson, R.T., and Groves, T.. “Incentive and informational properties of preference questions.” Environmental and Resource Economics 37,1(2007):181210.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Carson, R.T., Groves, T., and List, J.A.. “Consequentiality: A theoretical and experimental exploration of a single binary choice.” Journal of the Association of Environmental and Resource Economists 1,1/2(2014):171207.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Chambers, C.M., and Whitehead, J.C.. “A contingent valuation estimate of the benefits of wolves in Minnesota.” Environmental and Resource Economics 26,2(2003):249–67.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dillman, D.A., Smyth, J.D., and Christian, L.M.. Internet, Phone, Mail, and Mixed-Mode Surveys: The Tailored Design Method. Hoboken, N.J: John Wiley & Sons, 2014.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Enck, J.W., Mattfeld, G.F., and Decker, D.J.. “Retaining likely dropouts from hunting: New York’s apprentice hunter program.” Transactions of the North American Wildlife and Natural Resources Conference 61(1996):358–66.Google Scholar
Enck, J.W., Decker, D.J., and Brown, T.L.. “Status of hunter recruitment and retention in the United States.” Wildlife Society Bulletin 28(2000):817–24.Google Scholar
Ericsson, G., Bostedt, G., and Kindberg, J.. “Wolves as a symbol of people’s willingness to pay for large carnivore conservation.” Society and Natural Resources 21,4(2008):294309.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Freeman, A.M. III. The Measurement of Environmental and Resource Values: Theory and Methods. Washington, D.C: Resources for the Future, 2003.Google Scholar
Geist, V., Mahoney, S.P., and Organ, J.F.. “Why hunting has defined the North American model of wildlife conservation.” Transactions of the North American Wildlife and Natural Resources Conference 66(2001):175–85.Google Scholar
Gigliotti, L.M., Sweikert, L.A., Cornicelli, L., and Fulton, D.C.. “Minnesota landowners’ trust in their Department of Natural Resources, salient values similarity and wildlife value orientations.” Environment Systems and Decisions 40(2020):577–87.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Herriges, J., Kling, C., Liu, C.C., and Tobias, J.. “What are the consequences of consequentiality?Journal of Environmental Economics and Management 59(2010):6781.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Højberg, P.L., Nielsen, M.R., and Jacobsen., J.B.. “Fear, economic consequences, hunting competition, and distrust of authorities determine preferences for illegal lethal actions against gray wolves (Canis lupus): A choice experiment among landowners in Jutland.” Denmark., Crime, Law and Social Change, 67(2017):461–80.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Indiana Department of Natural Resources (INDNR). (2022). Internet site: https://www.in.gov/dnr/fish-and-wildlife/wildlife-resources/animals/bobcats/ (Accessed October 22, 2022).Google Scholar
Indiana Department of Natural Resources (INDNR). (2023). Internet site: https://www.in.gov/dnr/fish-and-wildlife/about-us/ (Accessed March 17, 2023).Google Scholar
Interis, M.G., and Petrolia, D.R.. “The effects of consequentiality in binary- and multinomial choice surveys.” Journal of Agricultural and Resource Economics 39(2014):201–16.Google Scholar
Johnson, S.A., Walker, H.D., and Hudson, C.M.. “Dispersal characteristics of juvenile bobcats in South-Central Indiana.” The Journal of Wildlife Management 74(2010):379–85.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Johnston, R.J., Boyle, K.J., Adamowicz, W., Bennett, J., Brouwer, R., Cameron, T.A., Hanemann, W.M., Hanley, N., Ryan, M., Scarpa, R., Tourangeau, R., Vossler, C.A.. “Contemporary guidance for stated preference studies.” Journal of the Association of Environmental and Resource Economists 4(2017):319405.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Jones, L.R., Zollner, P.A., Swihart, R.K., Godollei, E., Hudson, C.M., and Johnson, S.A.. “Survival and mortality sources in a recovering population of bobcats (Lynx rufus) in South-Central Indiana.” The American Midland Naturalist 184(2020):222–32.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Jones, L.R., Johnson, S.A., Hudson, C.M., Zollner, P.A., and Swihart, R.K.. “Habitat selection in a recovering bobcat (Lynx rufus) population.” PLOS One 17(2022a):e0269258.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Jones, L.R., Swihart, R.K., Gliech, D.F., Albers, G., Johnson, S.A., Hudson, C.M., and Zollner, P.A.. “Estimating state carrying capacity of bobcats (Lynx rufus) using improved maximum clique algorithms.” Landscape Ecology 37(2022b):2383–97.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
LaRue, M.A., Nielsen, C.K., Dowling, M., Miller, K., Wilson, B., Shaw, H., and Anderson, C.R.. “Cougars are recolonizing the midwest: Analysis of cougar confirmations during 1990-2008.” The Journal of Wildlife Management 76(2012):1364–9.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
(2020)Melstrom, R.T., and Kaefer, M.. “How diverse are preferences for urban fisheries? Evidence from a choice experiment.” Human Dimensions of Wildlife 25,6(2020):503–16.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Manfredo, M.J., Teel, T.L., Sullivan, L., and Dietsch, A.M.. “Values, trust, and cultural backlash in conservation governance: The case of wildlife management in the United States.” Biological Conservation 214(2017):303–11.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mattsson, L., Boman, M., and Ezebilo, E.E.. “More or less moose: How is the hunting value affected?Scandinavian Journal of Forest Research 29,2(2014):170–3.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mehmood, S., Zhang, D., and Armstrong, J.. “Factors associated with declining hunting license sales in Alabama.” Human Dimensions of Wildlife 8,4(2003):243–62.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Miller, C., and Vaske, J.. “Individual and situational influences on declining hunter effort in Illinois.” Human Dimensions of Wildlife 8,4(2003):263–76.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Muth, R.M., and Bowe, J.F.. “Illegal harvest of renewable natural resources in North America: Toward a typology of the motivations for poaching.” Society & Natural Resources 11,1(1998):924.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Penn, J.M., and Hu, W.. “Understanding hypothetical bias: An enhanced meta-analysis.” American Journal of Agricultural Economics 100,4(2018):1186–206.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Popp, J.N., Toman, T., Mallory, F.F., and Hamr, J.. “A century of elk restoration in Eastern North America.” Restoration Ecology 22,6(2014):723–30.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Roberts, N.M., and Crimmins, S.M.. “Bobcat population status and management in North America: Evidence of large-scale population increase.” Journal of Fish and Wildlife Management 1,2(2010):169–74.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Schulze, W.D., d'Arge, R.C., and Brookshire, D.S.. “Valuing environmental commodities: Some recent experiments.” Land Economics 57,2(1981):151–72.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sorg, C.F., and Loomis, J.. “An introduction to wildlife valuation techniques.” Wildlife Society Bulletin 13(1985):3846.Google Scholar
Stedman, R.C., Connelly, N.A., Heberlein, T.A., Decker, D.J., and Allred, S.B.. “The end of the (research) world as we know it? Understanding and coping with declining response rates to mail surveys.” Society & Natural Resources 32,10(2019):1139–54.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Stinchcomb, T.R., Ma, Z., Swihart, R.K., and Caudell, J.N.. “Expanding and evaluating public satisfaction with wildlife governance: Insights from deer management in Indiana, USA.” Environmental management 70,5(2022):780–92.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Stoll, J.R.Recreational activities and nonmarket valuation: The conceptualization issue.” Journal of Agricultural and Applied Economics 15,2(1983):119–25.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sutton, S.G., Stoll, J.R., and Ditton, R.B.. “Understanding anglers’ willingness to pay for increased fishing license fees.” Human Dimensions of Wildlife 6,2(2001):115–30.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Swihart, R.K., Caudell, J.N., Brooke, J.M., and Ma, Z.. “A flexible model-based approach to delineatew wildlife management units.” Wildlife Society Bulletin 44,1(2020):7785.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Thomas, C.D.Climate, climate change and range boundaries.” Diversity and Distributions 16,3(2010):488–95.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ufer, D.J., Christensen, S.A., Ortega, D.L., Pinizzotto, N., and Schuler, K.. “Stamping out wildlife disease: Are hunter-funded stamp programs a viable option for chronic wasting disease management?Conservation Science and Practice 4,9(2022):e12779.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
U.S. Department of the Interior, U.S. Fish and Wildlife Service, and U.S. Department of Commerce, U.S. Census Bureau. 2016 National Survey of Fishing, Hunting, and Wildlife-Associated Recreation, 2016.Google Scholar
U.S. Department of the Interior, U.S. Fish and Wildlife Service, and U.S. Department of Commerce, U.S. Census Bureau. 2011 National Survey of Fishing, Hunting, and Wildlife-Associated Recreation, 2011.Google Scholar
Vossler, C.A., Doyon, M., and Rondeau, D.. “Truth in consequentiality: Theory and field evidence on discrete choice experiments.” American Economic Journal: Microeconomics 4,4(2012):145–71.Google Scholar
Whitehead, J.C.Total economic values for coastal and marine wildlife: Specification, validity, and valuation issues.” Marine Resource Economics 8,2(1993):119–32.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Figure 0

Figure 1. Regional management units for Indiana.

Figure 1

Figure 2. Bobcat willingness to pay question with randomly varying quotas, bag limits, and license prices presented to respondents.

Figure 2

Figure 3. Consequentiality questions presented to respondents.

Figure 3

Table 1. Demographic information from the 399 survey respondents

Figure 4

Table 2. Balance table showing demographics for each treatmenta,b

Figure 5

Table 3. Logit model parameter estimates

Figure 6

Figure 4. Willingness to pay estimates from the RUM model.

Supplementary material: File

Lancaster et al. supplementary material 1

Lancaster et al. supplementary material
Download Lancaster et al. supplementary material 1(File)
File 526.7 KB
Supplementary material: File

Lancaster et al. supplementary material 2

Lancaster et al. supplementary material
Download Lancaster et al. supplementary material 2(File)
File 84.3 KB