Hostname: page-component-586b7cd67f-rdxmf Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-11-24T21:04:30.004Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Democracy, political partisanship, and state capacity in Latin America

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  16 November 2015

Davide Grassi
Affiliation:
Dipartimento di Culture, Politica e Società, Università degli Studi di Torino, Torino, Italia
Vincenzo Memoli*
Affiliation:
Dipartimento di Scienze Politiche e Sociali, Università degli Studi di Catania, Catania, Italia
*

Abstract

Social scientists have often neglected, or not sufficiently explored, the role of political factors in shaping state capacity. When they did, they mostly focused on key institutional features of political regimes, especially democracy. In this paper, we broaden this approach: besides the institutional traits of democracy, we analyze how governments and their ideologies influence state capacity. In particular, we assess the impact of democracy and executives’ partisanship on a composite index of state capacity, based on political order, administrative ability, and extractive capacity. To this end, we apply a pooled cross-sectional time-series model to 18 Latin American countries between 1995 and 2009. Our findings suggest that, in recent years, state capacity in the region was significantly affected by both democratic features and the ideological bearing of elected governments.

Type
Research Article
Copyright
© Società Italiana di Scienza Politica 2015 

Introduction

This paper argues that both democracy and political partisanship have a bearing on state capacity. We tested this relationship for Latin America, between 1995 and 2009, and found that democracy weakens the negative influence of authoritarianism on stateness, but it is insufficient to promote state strengthening. In addition, we explored the potential causal link between changes in political partisanship and stateness. Although several qualitative studies have underpinned the mechanisms that relate partisanship to a stronger state capacity (Slater, Reference Slater2008; Besley and Persson, Reference Besley and Persson2009; Kirby, Reference Karl2009), we are among the first to test this hypothesis quantitatively, finding generally supportive evidence: our investigation opens new avenues of research into the topic and originally contributes to the literature on state capacity.

A number of studies have analyzed the relationship between democracy and state capability both in wider geographical contexts and in particular regional settings. Adserà et al. (Reference Adserà, Boix and Payne2003) found that higher political accountability improves state capacity by lowering corruption and the risk of expropriation of property and by strengthening bureaucratic quality and the rule of law. Besley and Persson (Reference Besley and Persson2009) noticed that along with the incidence of war and other more specific variables, the historical weight of parliamentary democracy is a remarkably stable predictor of both the legal and the fiscal capacity of the state. Other scholars, finally, claim that regimes with regular elections and other political freedoms will eventually produce stronger (or, more accurately, better funded) states (Schmitter et al., Reference Schmitter, Wagemann and Obydenkova2005: 11). The role of democracy, however, is still controversial as, historically, developmental states in Asia existed under authoritarian regimes (for instance in Taiwan and South Korea).Footnote 1 Bratton (Reference Bratton2008) found that in Africa democracy appears to be empirically connected with such components of state capacity as rule of law, control of corruption, effectiveness, legitimacy, and accountability. Slater (Reference Slater2008), finally, looked at three Asian countries (Malaysia, Indonesia, and the Philippines): he concluded that competitive elections have facilitated state building in the region by stimulating the formation of stronger political parties; a more vigorous state commitment to citizen registration; and the imposition of centralized authority over societal strongmen.

In Latin America, democracy has been analyzed mostly as an outcome of state weakness. This political regime does not appear in major accounts of determinants of state capacity: Centeno (Reference Centeno2009), for instance, suggests that the main determinants of state capacity have been specific historical legacies; (non-state) institutional quality, as the degree of confidence in public and private institutions; economic and social inequality; and globalization. Cardenas (Reference Cardenas2010), however, identified political inequality as one of four factors that potentially explain the exceptionally low state capacity in the region, along with economic inequality, interstate conflict, and civil war. He adds, however, that the positive effects of democracy are undermined in the presence of high economic inequality. Likewise, in their analysis of the determinants of welfare states in a series of world regions that include Latin America, Haggard and Kaufmann (Reference Haggard and Kaufman2008) argued that, ceteris paribus, democracy promotes more progressive social welfare states: democratic rule provides incentives for politicians to reach the poor and those more exposed to risk, and opportunities for the latter to organize, thus strengthening the nature and scope of a crucial state capacity – providing citizens with fundamental social services. Whether or how democracy affects state capacity in Latin America, however, remains an open question. Acemoglu and Robinson (Reference Acemoglu and Robinson2008) noticed that, in spite of an unambiguous trend toward greater democracy, state capacity has remained particularly low in the area, for the persistence of de facto powers. Even if de jure institutions (political rights, elections, and checks on the executive) are established, the political balance may not change. A similar conclusion was reached by Cheibub (1998), for whom, over the period from 1970 to 1990, the government’s extractive capacity was not much stronger in democracies than in authoritarian regimes. There are, in sum, several counter-arguments to the notion that democracy always benefits stateness. Democratization and polarized competition can destabilize a state, and democratic petitions may overload and weaken political institutions (Hagopian and Mainwaring, Reference Hagopian and Mainwaring2005). Rather than contributing to legitimizing state institutions and improving their effectiveness the adoption of formally democratic institutions may actually produce a deterioration of state authority and public services.

An often overlooked premise to these reflections is that most states that eventually proved successful in achieving a robust stateness did not have the necessary capacities or the right bureaucracies to do so at first: they built them (UNRISD, 2010: 259). A political leadership committed to fast growth and equality must usually reach a political settlement with domestic actors to define the direction of public policy and then create a developmental and welfare-enhancing bureaucracy to support it (Haggard and Kaufmann, Reference Haggard and Kaufman2008). In a similar way, state capacity may be purposely undermined: the weak state capacity of Latin America (to levy taxes, in particular) is also due to powerful social groups that in some countries successfully opposed increases in the tax burden (Huber and Stephens, Reference Huber and Stephens2012: 41).

Redistributing social and political power in favor of subaltern groups is important in order to build bureaucratic capacities that support both growth and redistribution: the active inclusion of such groups in the political process enables states to frustrate pressures from dominant elites, which oppose redistribution and tax revenue increases. Mobilized subaltern groups press for an expansion of public provisions and the institutional capacity necessary to deliver administratively demanding universal public services such as public housing and high-quality education and healthcare. If these arguments are correct, left governments seem well suited to strengthen state capacity. Left governments are committed to lifting people out of poverty, reducing inequality, and providing quality public services, particularly education and health. In order to be able to do this, they have to increase tax collection, which is a basic indicator of state capacity. They also want to get away from clientelism, because their competitors on the right are usually quite good at getting voters by these means and they prefer an effective, non-corrupt, bureaucracy that treats people impartially, as citizens with rights, not as supplicants who are asking for a favor, and can be asked for something (like a vote) in return. Moreover, they want to avoid capture of the state by elites and private interests, because this will derail their program of providing quality services for all citizens, from law enforcement to child care.

Governments of other ideological bents, however, may also be interested in strengthening state capacity: order and legality, for instance, are a central concern of right of center parties, as crime and violence are inimical to business investments and growth and are most often targeted against wealthy individuals. Thus, in countries such as Colombia, executives in the right (and center) have strengthened political order and the overall capacity of the state by reducing political violence: they successfully fought rebel organizations, paramilitary groups, rural and urban vigilante bands, and private security services, and they were able to contain more or less organized crime and lower the number of homicides and kidnappings (Feldman, Reference Feldmann2012: 743). More generally, right-leaning governments may uphold state capacity as, in weaker states, enforceable property rights, duly supported by smoothly functioning legal institutions, are inadequate and widespread corruption is prominent. These limitations, in turn, generate insecurity and unpredictability, which are inimical to new investments, the creation of jobs, and the development of business (Fukuyama, Reference Fukuyama2007; De Soto, Reference De Soto1989).

In addition, once democracy is established, ideological orientation crucially interacts with electoral competition. When election results are disputed, irrespective of ideological orientation, parties may be driven to undertake policies that they might otherwise disregard, for the exclusive purpose of winning elections (Haggard and Kaufman, Reference Haggard and Kaufman2008: 360). Policies may be undertaken to capture the independent voter at the center and will be more conservative, or progressive, than a purely ideological stance implies. Accordingly, left-wing and right-wing governments become more similar: the former cannot pursue their preferred policy of welfare state expansion because of budget constraints, and the latter cannot pursue their preferred policy of cutbacks because their constituency has grown attached to the welfare state’s programs (Schumacher and Vis, Reference Schumacher and Vis2009). In Uruguay, for instance, a broad social alliance backed by the left Frente coalition was able to exercise a wide-ranging veto power against neoliberal pension reforms. Politicians from traditional parties, among which the conservative Blanco party, fearing the loss of the pensioners, either backed the reform or did not take a position. The existing welfare system enjoyed wide political support, not only among organized stake-holders but also within the broader electorate: politicians bent on reforming the welfare system had to reckon with both (Luna, Reference Luna2006). In short, whether in Latin America governments on the left have contributed to state capacity more than their counterparts on the right is a question better answered empirically.

This paper is organized as follows: in the next few pages, we will define our main dependent, independent, and control variables. In the following paragraph, we will submit our major hypotheses and outline the mechanisms by which our variables are related. Next, we will estimate the effect over time of democracy, executives’ partisanship, and other sociodemographic factors on different measures of stateness in Latin America. Finally, we will illustrate and discuss our findings, with references to the political experience of the region. Conclusions, as usual, will wrap up the analysis.

State capacity

The concept of state capacity, and its operationalization, is problematic and heavily contested in the literature (Studies in Comparative International Development 2008, special issue; Revista de Ciencia Política 2012, special issue).Footnote 2 In fact, there is greater scholarly agreement on key dimensions of the state than on how to operationalize such dimensions or the notion of the state itself (Carbone, Reference Carbone2013: 6). We believe that a definition of state capacity should be centered on a basic, narrow scope of state functions to avoid the problem of conflating causal and constitutive relationships, thus using causes or outcomes as indicators of the concept (Hanson and Sigman, Reference Hanson and Sigman2013). We define state capacity, broadly, as the ability of state institutions to effectively implement official goals (Sikkink, Reference Sikkink1991). This approach eludes normative conceptions about what the state ought to do or how it ought to do it – for instance, in the aftermath of the neoliberal turn in Latin America and the cutbacks of state intervention and bureaucracy, this definition should avoid confusing minimal but capable states, as Chile, with those that are fundamentally weak (Soifer, Reference Sojo2012: 86–87). More specifically, our definition of state capacity relies on Mann’s ‘infrastructural power’ concept – that is, ‘the institutional capacity of a central state, despotic or not, to penetrate its territories and logistically implement decisions’ (Reference Mann2008). Central to his notion, then, is ‘the question of the state’s authority over territory’, as well as ‘whether governments can implement policies, including the provision of public goods’ (Fortin, Reference Fortin2010: 656).

Empirical studies of the state typically highlight at least one of three constituent elements (Soifer, Reference Sojo2012; Hanson and Sigman, Reference Hanson and Sigman2013): the enforcement of a degree of internal political order through a monopolistic control over the means of coercion; the presence of a basic administration [a ‘usable bureaucracy’ in the words of Linz and Stepan (Reference Linz and Stepan1996): 11]; and the ability of the state to extract revenue from their citizens (North, 1981).Footnote 3 The coercive dimension is crucial in Weber’s (1965) definition of state, as an organization that possesses a monopoly on the legitimate use of physical force within its territory. The enforcement of internal political order by the state includes the capacity to defend its frontiers, uphold domestic order, and enforce law and policies by curbing violence. Administrative capacity refers to the ability to plan and develop policies and to produce and deliver public goods and services. This, in turn, requires technical competence, professional civil servants, a curbing of public corruption, and an effective reach across state territory. In particular, a professional bureaucracy tends to be somewhat autonomous from political pressure and displays an established mechanism for recruitment and training. In relation to this dimension, we believe it is important to avoid conflating a government’s policy choices with the ability of states to implement these policies – that is, to distinguish between the ability to administer from the services themselves (Soifer, Reference Sojo2012: 591). For this reason, in measuring this dimension, we avoid looking at the outcomes of public goods and services. Extractive capacity, finally, refers to the ability of the state to raise taxes and extract revenue from its citizens, and implies a series of competences and skills that are crucial for a definition of overall state capability: means to access population; instruments to gather and organize complex information; the possibility to count on honest civil servants; and ways of ensuring popular compliance with tax policies (Hanson and Sigman, Reference Hanson and Sigman2013: 4). For extractive capacity, as well, particular attention should be paid to distinguish the policy choice to tax from the ability of the state collection apparatus to collect the assessed taxes.

Measuring state capacity is equally challenging. We agree with Hendrix (Reference Hendrix2010: 283) that any single variable is unlikely to adequately capture the multidimensional concept of state capacity. However, many composite indexes of state capacity also include potential causes (as the lack of democracy) and predicted consequences (such as humanitarian disasters) into their definitions (Mata and Ziaja, Reference Mata and Ziaja2009; Gutiérrez, Reference Gutiérrez2011; Soifer, Reference Sojo2012). The ideal measure of state capacity, in short, should consist of an index with multiple number of indicators, which carefully avoids conflating key dimensions of the dependent variables with its potential causes and effects. On the basis of these considerations, we resolved to use the State Capacity Dataset (1960–2009) elaborated by Hanson and Sigman (Reference Hanson and Sigman2013). This data set measures state capacity based on the three main dimensions discussed above: extractive, administrative, and coercive capacities. These in turn are measured by 24 main indicators. In detail, administrative capacity is assessed through four sets of data: the International Country Risk Guide bureaucratic quality index; additional indexes related to administrative capacity and civil service quality;Footnote 4 a measure of census frequency, which signifies both the ability to collect data and effective territorial reach; and an indicator of contract intensive money, which represents the state’s capacity to regulate economic exchange. Overall, extractive capacity is first measured by tax revenues as a proportion of GDP. As argued above, however, this information by itself is unable to distinguish between policy choices and extractive capacity. Thus, additional measures were added, as the proportion of tax revenue coming from income, property, and domestic consumption taxes relative to revenue originating from international trade, as with customs duties. The greater the former, which are administratively more complex and require a more structured bureaucratic apparatus, the higher the expected level of extractive (and administrative) capacity.Footnote 5 Other indicators, finally, determine the degree to which revenue collection is connected with context-bound expectations. For instance, the Arbetman-Rabinowitz et al. data set (2012) gauges the ratio of actual tax revenue relative to an expected tax yield given a country GDP per capita, mineral production, exports, and other factors. Coercive capacity, to conclude, is also measured by four groups of data. First, there are data on military expenditures and personnel. The relationship of these figures with coercive capacity, however, is problematic as a large military force may indicate war or insecurity, which significantly weaken state capacity. Thus, additional data have been added, showing whether and how much the state itself is involved in perpetrating violence, has a monopoly on the use of force, and is present in the territory, by looking at the artificiality of state borders or the extent to which its land is mountainous, and therefore more difficult to reach. The authors of the data set, to conclude, identify, by way of latent variable analysis, a series of underlying factors that signify both overall state capacity and more specific aspects of this concept (Hanson and Sigman, Reference Hanson and Sigman2013).Footnote 6

Determinants of state capacity: regime and partisanship

With democracy, we refer to a political regime characterized by universal suffrage, the protection of key civil and political rights (including the presence of alternative sources of information), and free, transparent, and competitive elections. In addition, formal democratic institutions must be sovereign (Dahl, Reference Dahl1989). Thus, an analysis of democracies should exclude hybrid or ‘electoral authoritarian’ regimes, as they do not hold free and fair elections (Levitsky and Way, Reference Levi and Sacks2002). Democracies, however, may also be incomplete and partial: ‘defective’ democracies offer only limited guarantees for political rights (Merkel, Reference Merkel2001); ‘illiberal’ democracies provide inadequate protection for civil rights and the rule of law (Zakaria, 1997); in ‘delegative’ democracies, finally, elected officials are scarcely responsive to citizen preferences, inadequately constrained by other agencies of government, and insufficiently respectful of the rule of law (O’Donnell, Reference O’Donnell1993). We resolved to use minimalist notions and measures of democracy, rather than more substantive ones, to avoid mixing up attributes of political authority and state qualities (as its capacity) we wanted to disentangle. Consequently, we eliminated from our procedural measure of democracy, based on the Polity IV data, the component of the scale that refers to conflict (lack of political order).Footnote 7 The resulting scale runs between −2 (full autocracy) and +7 (full democracy).Footnote 8

Partisanship refers to ideal worldviews and the instruments held necessary to accomplish them: in Latin America, as in more advanced industrial countries, parties may be classified based on a left/center-left vs. right/center-right dichotomy.Footnote 9 We follow the classification suggested by Coppedge (Reference Coppedge1997) and updated by Huber et al. (Reference Huber, Rueschemeyer and Stephens2012). Coppedge’s experts classified parties, along this dimension, into six categories: left, center-left, center, center-right, right, and personalist. Thus, parties of the right (Brazilian ARENA) presented themselves as, or appealed to, heirs of traditional elites, fascists, neo-fascists, or the military with a conservative message (Coppedge, Reference Coppedge1997: 8). Coppedge classified as center-right (Argentine UCD) parties that ‘targeted middle- or lower-class voters in addition to elite voters, by stressing cooperation with the private sector, public order, clean government, morality, or the priority of growth over distribution’. In turn, he classified as centrist (Argentine UCR) those parties that ‘stressed classic political liberalism, the rule of law, human rights, or democracy, without a salient social or economic agenda’. Also included in this category are ‘governing parties whose policies are so divided between positions both to the left and to the right of center that no orientation that is mostly consistent between elections is discernible’. Going to the other side of the partisan spectrum, center-left parties (Venezuelan Acción Democrática) ‘stress justice, equality, social mobility, or the complementarity of distribution and accumulation in a way intended not to alienate middle or upper-class voters’. Left parties (Partido Socialista de Chile; any Communist party) ‘employ Marxist ideology or rhetoric and stress the priority of distribution over accumulation and/or the exploitation of the working class by capitalists and imperialists and advocate a strong role for the state to correct social and economic injustices’.Footnote 10 Finally, parties are classified as personalist if they ‘base their primary appeal on the charisma, authority, or efficacy of their leader rather than on any principles or platforms, which are too vague or inconsistent to permit a plausible classification of the party in any other way’ (Peruvian Cambio 90 or Bolivian Movimiento al Socialismo).

We use the instruments outlined above to measure the partisan orientation of governments in Latin America during periods of democratic rule [Executive Partisan Balance (EPB)].Footnote 11 When EPB increases, the ideological orientation of the executive moves toward the left (Huber et al., Reference Huber, Rueschemeyer and Stephens2012). In order to account for the necessary time needed to change state capacity through the formulation and passing of the relevant legislation, the training or re-training of civil service officials, and the like, the variable is cumulated for the 15 years preceding the year of observation.Footnote 12 Finally, a set of standard control variables, both economic and social, has been added to our model. Stateness difference controls for the weight of past state capacity and has been measured by calculating the difference in state capacity levels over the previous 14 years. Economic development, indicated by GDP per capita at current USD in 1994, is taken from the World Bank, as are country size and oil rents; ethnic fractionalization is measured by using the data presented in the article Fractionalization by Alesina et al. (Reference Alesina, Devleeschauwer, Easterly, Kurlat and Wacziarg2003).

Hypotheses

Democracy is thought to reduce violent conflict by providing institutionalized channels of communication with political opponents, by offering to incorporate them into the debate, and by conceding to some of their political and social demands.Footnote 13 The rationale for this strategy, over and above the intrinsic desirability of democracy, is that by making the government more accountable, citizens have less cause for violent opposition. Accordingly, people will be more likely to identify with democracy and the state. Opening up a closed media will also allow greater public scrutiny of poorly performing areas of state function. Creating space for independent civil society permits advocacy groups to monitor and critique state performance and work together with the state to offer new policy ideas. Finally, by making politicians, and at least indirectly also administrators, accountable, democratic procedures and sanctions help control arbitrary power and the diffusion of corruption (Carbone, Reference Carbone2013). However, we do not rule out that the relationship between democracy and stateness may assume a non-linear form: different levels of democracy may have a diverse impact on stateness as suggested by part of the literature (Bäck and Hadenius, Reference Barret, Chavez and Rodríguez-Garavito2008). Thus, our first hypothesis is that more complete and mature democratic governments will improve state capacity in either a linear or a quadratic form (Hypothesis 1).

The evidence and scholars’ opinions on the role of partisanship in democratic governments are mixed. Comparative historical evidence indicates that incumbency of left parties is key for welfare state development (Huber and Stephens, Reference Huber and Stephens2012). More specific studies have also established a strong relationship linking robust mass mobilization and leftist-party rule to the development of an infrastructurally capable welfare state.Footnote 14 In Latin America, finally, recent left governments, consistent with their major political objectives, have made efforts toward deepening democracy and citizens’ rights, rebuilding state capacity, freeing while regulating markets, and creating an adequate technical and political environment for competent policymaking (Bresser-Pereira, Reference Bresser-Pereira2001). Other studies, however, point at the strengthening of state capacity under right-leaning governments (Rangel, Reference Rangel2005; Fukuyama and Colby, Reference Fukuyama2011). Finally, scholars have underlined a process of ideological convergence by major political parties and executives that blurs partisan and policy differences. As a result, we leave an initial answer to this issue to our empirical analysis (Hypothesis 2).

To conclude, we add a number of standard control variables. First, we posit that current levels of state capacity are influenced by past levels. It is reasonable to assume (and extensively recognized) that state capacity changes slowly, and that past levels of state strength strongly affect current ones; thus, we added a stateness difference variable to our model. Second, we introduce economic development to test a possible spurious relationship between our main variables: both democratic governments and state capacity might be the product of economic development over time. For Schmitter et al. ‘the richer and more developed the country, the more it will spend on public goods provided by its state’ (Reference Schmitter, Wagemann and Obydenkova2005: 7). Income increases may foster state capacity because richer countries can be expected to afford better institutions and administrative structures and many variables correlated with income, such as schooling levels or urbanization, may decrease the social tolerance of corruption (Pellegrini and Gerlagh, Reference Pellegrini and Gerlagh2008: 255). Saylor (Reference Saylor2012) also argues that the pursuits of private profit can be a powerful state building motive: when hunting profit during booms, export-oriented actors regularly seek new state-supplied public goods, whose provision promotes the expansion of state capacity. All these mechanisms imply an independent effect of the level of economic development on state capacity. Thus, we insert a specific hypothesis (Hypothesis 3).

All else being equal, excessively large territories may prove hard to establish institutionalized rule on, given that vertical integration and horizontal coordination becomes more difficult (Herbst and Mills, Reference Herbst and Mills2006). Thus, we expect larger countries to be associated with lower state capacity (Hypothesis 4). Ethnic fractionalization is associated with a challenging environment for institutions in balance between inclusion of minority groups and preservation of governing effectiveness and efficiency (Ben-Meir, Reference Bäck and Hadenius2006). In countries where fractionalization is high, citizens have low confidence in political institutions (Sojo, Reference Soifer2011) and the democratic process is less likely to take hold. Accordingly, it is reasonable to hypothesize that where fractionalization is high it will be negatively related to stateness (Hypothesis 5).Footnote 15 Finally, excessive dependence on oil exports weakens state capacity by loosening the tie between tax burden and the right to political representation (Hypothesis 6). The mechanisms connecting oil rents and state capacity are at least two: first, large oil rents (when both the state and democracy are not yet mature) weaken state capacity because they exempt the state from building an efficient tax extraction system. Oil-producing countries tend to have weaker state apparatuses than their income levels would predict, because rulers have less need to invest in the bureaucratic capacity to collect taxes. Thus, they are unusually detached from and unaccountable to the general population, and their populations, in turn, are less likely to demand political responsibility and representation in government. Oil wealth also produces greater spending on patronage, which, in turn, weakens existing pressures for representation and accountability (Karl, 2004).Footnote 16

Data, methodology, and findings

Our paper focalizes in a diachronic way on stateness in Latin America. Although the choice of the subcontinent ensures comparability within a most similar research design, it also represents an ideal testing ground for our main hypothesis – the impact of political factors on state strength. In Latin America, democracies are abundant and differ in quality (as opposed, for instance, to the Middle East), whereas political parties follow ideologies that have been classified along a right-to-left continuum perceived to be meaningful for the structuring of politics (as opposed, for instance, to the worldviews of most African and Asian parties). The presence of political beliefs that generate consistent and coherent policy choices, even if less easily identifiable than in the developed West, is vital for an investigation of the potential links between political parties acting in a democracy, partisanship, and state capacity, and validates the election of the subcontinent to assess our research questions. Our analysis comprises all Latin American countries with population above 2,000,000, observed over the 1995–2009 period: we initially considered 22 countries in total, 11 belonging to Central America and 11 to South America. Missing data problems forced us to exclude four of them from our final report.Footnote 17

As we rely on a short series of observations obtained from many countries over time, we adopted a pooled cross-sectional time series.Footnote 18 The advantage of longitudinal panel information, compared with cross-sectional information, consists in its potential for an analysis of social, political, and economic dynamics at different levels. To test whether a fixed effects or random effects (RE) model is more appropriate for our data set, we applied the Hausman test.Footnote 19 On the basis of test results, we used different RE longitudinal regression models on a long unbalanced panel data set, using the software STATA.Footnote 20 In principle, state capacity could cause both more democracy and the rise of left. It could cause higher-quality democracy by prompting political actors to choose to play within a set of institutions effectively enforced rather than opting for non-institutional means of political competition. In addition, the poor will press the state and the political arena for redistribution when they are confident that existing state institutions are sufficiently capable to implement their preferred policies. Thus, support for parties promising increased service provision (i.e. the left) varies with state capacity for any level of inequality. In conclusion, as the relationship between democracy and stateness raises reciprocity questions, we tested for the endogeneity of democracy. Our results confirm that our model is free from such problem.Footnote 21

We then proceed to a visual analysis of the values of our dependent variable (Figure 1). During the period of observation, our measure of state capacity has increased especially in countries where the quality of democratic governments has been intermediate to strong, and the left has exercised power for significant periods of time, as in Chile, the Dominican Republic, Uruguay, Peru, and Costa Rica. However, less-prominent increases in state strength also occurred where governments were controlled mostly by parties of the right, as in Guatemala and Colombia.Footnote 22 In contrast, decreases in state capacity took place in five countries, some of which have been governed by personalist executives, such as Argentina and Bolivia, whereas in others a left executive was in power only shortly, such as in Ecuador (since 2007) and Paraguay (since 2008). Only Brazil represents a clear case of a left-leaning country characterized by a declining state strength.Footnote 23

Figure 1 Differences in stateness (1995–2009).Note: State capacity data set (see Hanson and Sigman, Reference Hanson and Sigman2013).

To explore the impact of our independent variables, we develop three models (Table 1). In the first two, we focus separately on levels of democracy and the impact of executives’ partisanship, along with control variables. Subsequently, we estimate the aggregate bearing of these variables on the dependent variable. More precisely, in the first model we regressed the indicator of state capacity against our level of democracy index (in linear and quadratic forms, see Table 1) controlling for context variables: a lagged (14 years) stateness variable; level of economic development in 1994; the size of the country; oil rents; and ethnic fractionalization. Contrary to expectations, results on democracy suggest a non-linear but negative impact during the period of observation (R 2=42%). In short, the negative bearing of less-democratic governments fades progressively away when political performance improves and democracy matures, but a negative effect still persists. A positive effect is detected, on the other hand, when we regress executive partisan balance (EPB) against state capacity levels (see Table 1): increasing the presence of the left in government also increases state capacity levels (R 2: 30.5%).

Table 1 The effect of democracy and partisanship on stateness in Latin American

Note: We have applied a random effects generalized least squares regression.

*P<0.10; **P<0.05; ***P<0.01; ****P<0.001.

In model 3, finally, we incorporate levels of democracy and EPB, along with our control variables: democracy and EPB are still significant and unfold the above-mentioned effects, whereas state capacity levels are also increased by the difference of stateness variable. Finally, levels of economic development, land size, the proportion of oil in the economy and ethnic diversity have the expected influence, but fail to reach statistical significance. Figure 2 describes in detail the interaction affecting our democracy variable: levels of democracy have a significant and negative impact on the probability of increasing the levels of stateness. This effect, as noticed above, decreases as democracy takes hold, but democracy, by itself, has been insufficient to advance state capacity in Latin America between 1995 and 2009. When countries become fully democratic (score 5 on the chart),Footnote 24 finally, the variable loses significance.

Figure 2 Marginal effect of democracy.Note: The figure displays the predictive margins with 95% confidence interval of democracy (Polity IV×Polity IV) reported in Table 1 model 3.

In sum, between 1995 and 2009, the effect of our political regime variables on state capacity has been significant and negative, but increasing levels of democracy have weakened its intensity. We find that, at the end of the last decade, higher competitiveness and openness of executive recruitment, as well as more substantial constraints on the chief executive, have been unable by themselves to promote state capacity. Our study empirically confirms a series of investigations that underline this critical relationship. On the one hand, Latin American democracies have been generally unable to solve the problem of socio-economic inequality and, on occasions, have even failed to remove glaring political inequalities, both of which represent severe obstacles to more capable states (Huber et al., Reference Huber, Stephens, Mustillo and Pribble1997; Cardenas, Reference Cardenas2010). Moreover, de jure democratic institutions, such as political rights and elections, may be established, but the political balance, strongly influenced by de facto powers, may not change: when the former only reflect the latter, democracy is associated to a decay in state authority (Cheibub, 1998; Acemoglu and Robinson, Reference Acemoglu and Robinson2008). In Latin America, the recurring opposition of the most powerful segments of society to social and fiscal reforms aimed at expanding public services and at distributing their costs more equally has considerably constrained the tasks and responsibilities of local states, preventing them from developing more completely both their structures and their functions (Huber and Stephens, Reference Huber and Stephens2012). Democratization and polarized antagonism, finally, may undermine state institutions, and democratic requests may occasionally overburden and destabilize political and state undertakings (Hagopian and Mainwaring, Reference Hagopian and Mainwaring2005).

We also find that political partisanship affects stateness. Our conclusions are partly in line with, and complete, those by Cardenas (Reference Cardenas2010), Haggard and Kaufmann (Reference Haggard and Kaufman2008), Acemoglu and Robinson (Reference Acemoglu and Robinson2008), and Hagopian and Mainwaring (Reference Hagopian and Mainwaring2005). Cardenas claims that the weakness of the state in Latin America depends on pervasive economic inequality: economic inequality, however, is also a reflection of left parties’ weakness, and we illustrated the mechanisms relating these parties to state capacity. For Haggard and Kaufmann, democracy may strengthen the state by promoting more progressive social welfare systems. In Latin America, in turn, more progressive social welfare systems have been usually associated with the presence of a stronger left: left governments have more incisively promoted redistributive welfare and prevented the purposeful boycotting of crucial state powers such as tax extraction, which encroached upon the privileges of local elites.Footnote 25 Thus, left parties have fostered both a deepening of democracy and a containment of social and economic privileges, which have contributed to a strengthening of state capacity: it is through the crucial intermediation of these parties that the gap between political and social powers has been reduced, and state strength has somehow increased in the region.Footnote 26 In particular, a ‘new left’ emerged in the subcontinent at the end of the 1990s, which accepts the essential principles of market economics, while endorsing reforms such as the enactment of welfare plans for the least advantaged, a revived concern for public safety, a more active role for the state as supervisor and arbitrator between capital and labor, the growth and upgrading of public services, and the inauguration of a more progressive tax system (Barrett et al., Reference Ben-Meir2008: 22).Footnote 27

In Chile, for instance, the Lagos (2000–06) and Bachelet (2006–10) administrations sponsored important reforms in the area of public health, education, and social security, which resulted in an unprecedented growth of social benefits aimed at its poorest citizens; passed a series of laws on probity in the Public Administration (2003) and transparency (2009); reduced the number of civil servants directly designated by the executive; and introduced a Senior Management Service System (Alta Dirección Pública), whose positions were filled through public competition, thus making civil service careers more professional and meritocratic. The armed forces’ special prerogatives over elected officials, in addition, were drastically reduced (Bertelsmann, 2010).Footnote 28 In the welfare sector, in particular, President Lagos promoted a Regime of Explicit Health Guarantees (Plan de Acceso Universal con Garantías Explícitas, also known as Plano AUGE), whose objective was to expand the quality and availability of public sector health services, especially for lower-income groups. In its original form, the plan directed to deliver medical care to people meeting certain age requirements and suffering from one of a set of specified diseases. The AUGE plan set new standards for both the quality and the quantity of the services offered, establishing maximum waiting times for the provision of medical treatment and ensuring that the necessary activities, procedures, and technologies would be provided only by registered and accredited healthcare professionals (Missoni and Solimano, Reference Missoni and Solimano2010). This reform, finally, was to be accompanied by an information system and by studies to assess compliance monitoring and impact assessment. In short, a series of institutions and practices were deployed and strengthened, which have been usually associated with capable states.

What characterizes these policies is the political will to mold the state as a mechanism to address the huge social deficits caused by neoliberal policies and, in some cases, to re-establish an institutional infrastructure to seek to ensure a more responsive, democratic, and well-functioning public administration.Footnote 29 Thus, although the ‘new left’ governments ‘have opted for the strategy of “bending and moulding” the existing political institutions and economic model rather than doing away with it … it may be that when the margins are bent and molded enough, they will change their relation to the core to the extent that the core itself will become something different and better’ (Panizza, Reference Panizza2005: 730). To sum up, the political agenda of the left in the region has generally tended to develop, both historically and more recently, some of the abilities and resources usually associated with state capacity. In particular, ‘new left’ governments have strengthened the state’s role in social provision, implementing programs that are more extensive in their reach and that provide better and more complete benefits (Kirby, Reference Karl2009). Specifically, these governments have supplied a democratic and inclusive social contract, although within the confines of market-oriented, export-led growth (Grugel and Riggirozzi, Reference Grugel and Riggirozzi2012).Footnote 30

These conclusions do not rule out that right governments might strengthen state capacity. In Colombia, for instance, state capacity increased under a right executive, whereas other factors that according to the literature contribute to this result, such as democratic quality, were absent or weakened. Although the actual extent of their success remains unclear (Feldmann, Reference Feldmann2012), right-wing governments contributed to restore political order, in relation to both political and common violence. Since Uribe’s peace talks with the AUC (Autodefensas Unidas de Colombia) started in 2003, hundreds of paramilitary leaders have been jailed and a dozen key chiefs were handed over to the United States. In short, a demobilization process was initiated that translated into the neutralization of a formidable military force. Homicide rates have also plunged from ~28,000 in 2002 to 15,459 in 2010. Tax extraction capacity has likewise improved, increasing from 1990 (10.9% of GDP) to 2009 (17.8% of GDP) after reaching a peak of 18.2% between 2005 and 2007 (Gómez et al., Reference Gómez, Carlos and Jiménez2012: 13).Footnote 31 Civil service performance, finally, benefited from a 2004 law that sought to put an end to 5 years of legal ambiguity in which provisional appointments reached 38% of the career personnel, and new merit-based criteria were introduced for entering the civil service (Grindle, Reference Grindle2010: 22). In short, right governments improved especially political order and were able to expand overall state capacity.

Conclusion

Our study adds to a topic of research – namely, the impact of democracy on state capacity – which has hardly been addressed thus far. Although the bearing of democracy on state capacity has been discussed and empirically analyzed by (a limited number of) previous studies, we offer a novel investigation on the role of partisanship in the process, outline the mechanisms by which democracy and EPB affect state capacity, and measure their effect on state strength. In Latin America, left governments have facilitated the active political inclusion of less-favored social groups, by empowering states to resist pressures from dominant classes opposed to income redistribution or more intense tax extraction, thus strengthening administrative capacity and overall stateness. At least during the period covered by this study, these goals were not accomplished by all democratic governments in Latin America and democracy, by itself, has been unable to unchain this process. The recent appearance of ‘new left’ governments seems to have fueled a novel phase of state strengthening, which counters the downsizing of state capacity that took place in previous decades. The extent and historical relevance of this shift needs to be fully clarified: we have documented, however, its empirical thrust and underlined its theoretical relevance. Although political parties of different convictions have also been able to strengthen state capacity, by implementing different policies in relevant areas of stateness, we maintain that, the latest expansion of left governments has resulted in stronger states, with higher administrative capacity and higher levels of political order.

Our results open intriguing avenues of research on the consequences of democracy and complement similar studies on the consequences of left parties’ power in the area (Huber et al., Reference Huber, Nielsen, Pribble and Stephens2006). In addition, our approach tackles a major criticism levied against democratization studies: too often political scientists have focused on the formal requisites of democracy and overlooked the constellation of de facto social and economic powers that decisively shape the political trajectories and fortunes of people in the area. Our analysis takes both aspects into account: the strategy of left parties conjugates broader political participation with more extended social and political programs for the least advantaged and with an improvement of domestic political order. State capacity is a crucial instrument by which fuller political participation may translate into valuable social gains for the weakest in society. By granting the political incorporation of formerly excluded social groups and strengthening the capacity of the state to intervene in society to reduce social and economic inequalities, left parties make democracy more mature and, at the same time, inhibit the factual powers that effectively restrain progressive social change, thus reducing the gap between ‘formal’ and ‘substantial’ democracy, which allowed to promote stateness. Accordingly, our analysis carries major practical implications: if state capacity may be directed and stimulated politically, developing countries and governments may hope to strengthen their capacity to tackle the problems they have traditionally faced, from poverty to illiteracy and from political violence to public corruption, thus improving their chances to advance their social and economic conditions, while deepening the participatory and representative nature of their respective political regimes.

Acknowledgment

This research is part of a project on ‘The economic, social and political consequences of democratic reforms: a quantitative and qualitative comparative analysis (COD)’, funded by a Starting Grant of the European Research Council (Grant Agreement no. 262873, ‘Ideas’, 7th Framework Programme of the EU).

Data

The replication data set is available at http://thedata.harvard.edu/dvn/dv/ipsr-risp

Footnotes

1 Some point at a non-linear relationship: Charrón and Lapuente (Reference Charrón and Lapuente2010) found that poorer countries have higher ‘administrative capacity’ under authoritarian rule, whereas moderate-to-wealthier countries perform better under democratic rule. Bäck and Hadenius (Reference Barret, Chavez and Rodríguez-Garavito2008) likewise argued that the relationship between level of democratization and ‘administrative capacity’ is significant and negative at low levels of democratization, but significant and positive at higher levels.

2 Following wide usage we treat here the terms state capacity, state capability, and stateness as equivalent (see Fukuyama, Reference Fukuyama and Colby2005).

3 We exclude a ‘legitimacy’ dimension from our notion of state – that is, the rightful exercise of power as perceived by citizens, for two reasons. First, because we conceive it as being instrumental to, rather than constitutive of, state capacity: while legitimacy is often critical to the actual working of a state, it does not appear to be so much an essential feature but rather an instrument that assists the effective organization and functioning of a state apparatus over its land and people (Levi, Reference Levistsky2002: 40). Gilley (Reference Gilley2006: 517) observed that several democratic countries such as France, New Zealand or South Africa, seem to do relatively poorly when state legitimacy is considered, whereas authoritarian governments, such as China or Azerbaijan, exhibit comparatively high legitimacy levels. Levi and Sacks (Reference Levitsky and Way2009: 326) also submitted convincing evidence that political rights are not related to legitimacy, operationalized as widespread approval of a government’s right to force people to pay taxes. A second reason to exclude legitimacy is because using it, when examining the democracy–stateness relationship, may lead to endogeneity problems.

4 Such as the Weberianness Index elaborated by Rauch and Evans (Reference Rauch and Evans2000); or the Effective Implementation of Government Decision Rating (IMD World Competitiveness Center, Reference Kirby2011).

5 Along this line, Hanson and Sigman argued that five variables in the data set measure both extractive and administrative capacity (Reference Hanson and Sigman2013, Table 1).

6 For further details on the data set, refer to Hanson and Sigman (Reference Hanson and Sigman2013).

7 Following Carbone and Memoli (2015), we eliminated ‘regulation of participation’ (PARREG) and ‘competitiveness of participation’ (PARCOMP), both of which include references to factional violence and civil war, while maintaining the three remaining components of the index – that is, ‘competitiveness of executive recruitment’ (XRCOMP), ‘executive constraints’ (XCONST), and ‘openness of executive recruitment’ (XROPEN).

8 We excluded alternative measures of democracy, such as the Mainwaring et al. (2001), as in their index crucial elements of our dependent variable such as political order contribute to define the presence and strength of democracy, creating endogeneity problems. Mainwaring and Brinks argued, for instance, that government or paramilitary campaigns against guerrillas and drug trafficking in Colombia (1980s to the present) and Peru (1980s and early 1990s) have represented a less than democratic experience for peasants caught in the middle, and have labeled consequently these countries as undemocratic during the corresponding periods (Ibid.: 7). Huber and Stephens’ measure of democracy (Huber et al., Reference Huber, Rueschemeyer and Stephens2012), on the other hand, is based on four categories (Authoritarian Regimes, Bureaucratic Authoritarian Regimes, Restricted Democracies, and Full Democracies): we preferred to use the Polity data, which allowed us to better differentiate different levels of democracy in each country.

9 Although in most Latin American countries political parties tend to be less consolidated and their worldviews and commitments are less clearly articulated than in the developed West, expert surveys classify most regional parties into the same left, center-left, center, center-right, or right spectrum, with a residual category of personalist parties and a small number of parties that escape taxonomy (Coppedge, Reference Coppedge1997; Huber et al., Reference Huber, Nielsen, Pribble and Stephens2006: 949).

10 A host of authors underline the existence of many ‘lefts’ in Latin America (for instance, Pribble, 2013; Levitsky and Roberts, 2011; Weyland et al., 2010; and Cameron and Hershberg, 2010). They want to differentiate between a programmatic left (as in Brazil, Chile, and Uruguay) and a non-programmatic left (as in Argentina and Bolivia), although they are not always explicit about this. This classification is valuable, as it is reasonable to assume that only a programmatic left party would invest in building state capacity. Our taxonomy (Huber et al., Reference Huber, Rueschemeyer and Stephens2012) is mostly in line with these authors.

11 More precisely, following Huber et al. (Reference Huber, Nielsen, Pribble and Stephens2006), we measured the executive partisan balance of power by weighting the executive partisan orientation in a given year by −1 for right, −0.5 for center-right, 0 for center, 0.5 for center-left, and 1 for left parties. This measure has also been dubbed as ‘ideological center of gravity’ (Huber et al., Reference Huber, Nielsen, Pribble and Stephens2006: 954).

12 In Latin America, a 15-year period corresponds roughly to three average presidential terms (Martinez-Gallardo, Reference Martinez-Gallardo2011: 13).

13 At least above certain levels of income (2750 USD), a long-standing and relatively sound democracy has been associated with a lessening of internal conflict and a reduced chance of the use of political violence (Collier and Rohner, Reference Collier and Rohner2008). Mansfield and Snyder (Reference Mansfield and Snyder2005), however, argue that countries taking early steps on the journey from dictatorship toward electoral politics are especially prone to civil war, violent revolution, and ethnic and sectarian bloodshed.

14 For instance, in the Indian state of Kerala (Slater, Reference Slater2008).

15 Others point out that ethnic composition does not fuel violence and fragmentation per se, it does so only when trigger factors ignite structural contradictions, such as manipulative leadership, opportunistic neighbors, and shattered or rising expectations (Gurr, Reference Gurr1994).

16 We coded 0 those countries where oil rents are <10% of GDP, and 1countries where oil rents are >10% of GDP.

17 Namely Cuba, Guyana, Haiti, and Honduras. The countries considered are Argentina, Bolivia, Brazil, Chile, Colombia, Costa Rica, Dominican Republic, Ecuador, El Salvador, Guatemala, Jamaica, Mexico, Nicaragua, Panama, Paraguay, Peru, Uruguay, and Venezuela.

18 This limited period of time implies that we possibly underestimate contingently less-relevant and path-dependent components of state capacity. Political violence, for instance, does not change much in our sample as the region has been mostly pacified by 1995, except for countries such as Colombia and Peru. Basic administrative capacity, on the other hand, varies little as changes in bureaucratic quality – that is, in the degree of autonomy from political pressures and in the established mechanism for civil service recruitment and training – depend crucially on their implementation, which is a slow process that may be distorting the original intents of legislators (Grindle, Reference Grindle2010: 1).

19 The null hypothesis is that the preferred model is random effects. We obtained a P>χ 2>0.05; thus, we opted for a random effects model. On this point see Green (Reference Green2008).

20 As we found some heteroskedasticity, we used cluster-robust standard errors, which yield a consistent VCE estimator (see Arellano, Reference Arellano2003; Stock and Watson, Reference Stock and Watson2008; Wooldridge, Reference Zakaria2009).

21 The robust score χ 2 (1)=0.341 (P=0.560) and robust regression F (1,111)=0.320 (P=0.573) confirm that the null hypothesis (democracy is exogenous) cannot be rejected.

22 A complementary interpretation on Peru is suggested by Levistsky (Reference Levi2013). In a historical perspective, he finds that state weakness inhibited both Garcia and now Humala from engaging in a left-leaning agenda. In essence, he finds that weak parties and weak states tend to reinforce one another.

23 Some of the social policies promoted by the Lula government, as the Bolsa Familia Plan, have been associated with a positive effect on state capacity (Hunter and Borges-Sugiyama, Reference Hunter and Sugiyama2014). However, during the Lula and Rousseff administrations violent crimes continued to reach extraordinarily high levels (Waiselfisz, Reference Waiselfisz2013); and tax collection as a percentage of GDP somewhat declined (World Bank, Reference Wooldridge2014). Thus, the capacity of the state both to provide effective citizens’ protection and to punish criminals lessened, as impunity and other institutional deficiencies allowed a culture of violence to thrive.

24 This score represents the level 6 on the Polity IV scale.

25 Some have argued that this agenda is far too modest and fails to realize the more revolutionary rupture with the previous neoliberal order that many hoped for (Barrett et al., Reference Ben-Meir2008; MacDonald and Ruckert, Reference Macdonald and Ruckert2009). However, bearing in mind the changing nature and role of the state facilitated by these reforms, they may add up to a more decisive break with the past than is immediately evident.

26 It may be useful to recall that, historically, the states typically identified by the literature as the most capable in the region (Centeno, Reference Centeno2009; Cardenas, Reference Cardenas2010) have tended to overlap with the most robust democracies, as Costa Rica and Uruguay, closely followed by Chile and Argentina. In the first three countries, left-leaning political parties bent on redistribution were pre-eminent in the process of welfare state building, whereas in Argentina social policies were first introduced and later defended by a populist and semi-authoritarian political movement (Grassi, Reference Grassi2014).

27 These new governments have been dubbed ‘new left’ governments. Its major representatives in our sample are the Chávez presidency in Venezuela (since 1998); the Lagos and Bachelet governments in Chile (since 2000); the Lula and Rousseff executives in Brazil (since 2002); the Frente Amplio government in Uruguay (since 2004); the Ortega government in Nicaragua; the Correa government in Ecuador; the García presidency in Peru (since 2006); and the Lugo government in Paraguay (since 2008). The Kirchners governments in Argentina (since 2003) have been coded as ‘other’ and the Morales executive in Bolivia (since 2005) as ‘personalist’ until 2008 and ‘other’ thereafter. ‘Other’ stands for a political regime that represents an identifiable ideology, program, region, interest, or social group that cannot be classified in left-right terms (Huber et al., Reference Huber, Rueschemeyer and Stephens2012, for details).

28 During this period, tax collection increased slightly, by less than 1 percent (Gómez et al., Reference Gómez, Carlos and Jiménez2012: 13).

29 We acknowledge that our hypothesis on the role of left parties becomes problematic when applied to other areas of the world. In Korea, Taiwan, and Thailand, for instance, the formidable expansion of a wide array of social entitlements, with its related impact on state capacity, has been driven by centrist and even conservative parties that have used social policies, especially basic social services and particularly education, for political ends. On the other hand, this ‘anomalous’ result is explained in part by the fact that conservative parties were seeking to neutralize social challenges on other salient issues, often along a democratic–authoritarian dimension (Haggard and Kaufman, Reference Haggard and Kaufman2008: 360).

30 The presence of a significant political left had an impact on the reforms introduced in the region because of the difficult economic situation, softening most of its harshest features. In Uruguay, for instance, the traditional public pensions system, managed by the state, gave way to a mixed system that integrated private companies and a complementary capitalization arrangement for the upper income sectors. Although these changes deeply transformed the old system, this remained statist and coherent with social goals abandoned by other regional governments.

31 Dealing with Colombia, Flores-Macías (Reference Flores-Macías2014) argued that security crises provide a unique window of opportunity to expand the tax capacity of the state, particularly for right parties, as shown by president Uribe’s 2002 adoption of the so-called ‘war tax’, which has emerged as one of the Colombian state’s most important policy responses to the Farc challenge.

References

Acemoglu, D. and Robinson, J. (2008), ‘The role of institutions in growth and development’. Commission on Growth and Development Working Paper No. 10, World Bank, Washington, DC.Google Scholar
Adserà, A., Boix, C. and Payne, M. (2003), ‘Are you being served? Political accountability and quality of government’, The Journal of Law, Economics and Organization 19(1): 445490.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Alesina, A., Devleeschauwer, A., Easterly, W., Kurlat, S. and Wacziarg, R. (2003), ‘Fractionalization’, Journal of Economic Growth 8(2): 155194.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Arbetman-Rabinowitz, M., Kugler, J., Abdollahian, M., Johnson, K. and Kang, K. (2011), Replication data for: Relative Political Capacity Dataset, http://hdl.handle.net/1902. 1/16845. Transresearch Consortium [Distributor] V3 [Version].Google Scholar
Arellano, M. (2003), Panel Data Econometrics, Oxford: Oxford University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bäck, H. and Hadenius, A. (2008), ‘Democracy and state capacity: exploring a J-shaped relationship’, Governance 21(1): 124.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Barret, P., Chavez, D. and Rodríguez-Garavito, C. (eds) (2008), The Latin American Left: Utopia Reborn, London: Pluto Press.Google Scholar
Ben-Meir, A. (2006), ‘Challenges to democracy in the Arab and Muslim world’, Review of International Law and Politics 6: 105110.Google Scholar
Bertelsmann, S. (2010), Bertelsmann Transformation Index 2010, Politische Gestaltung im internationalen Vergleich, Gütersloh: Verlag Bertelsmann Stiftung.Google Scholar
Besley, T. and Persson, T. (2009), ‘The origins of state capacity: property rights, taxation and politics’, American Economic Review 99(4): 12181244.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bratton, M. (2008), ‘Do free elections foster capable government? The democracy-governance connection in Africa’. Afrobarometer Working Paper No. 104, 331–354.Google Scholar
Bresser-Pereira, L. (2001), ‘The new left viewed from the South’, in A. Giddens (ed.), The Global Third Way Debate, Cambridge: Polity Press, pp. 358371.Google Scholar
Cameron, M.A. and Hershberg, E. (2010), Latin America’s Left Turns: Politics, Policies, and Trajectories of Change, Boulder, CO: Lynne Rienner Publishers.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Carbone, G. (2013), ‘Democratisation as a state-building mechanism: a preliminary discussion of an understudied relationship’, Political Studies Review 13(1): 1121.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Carbone, G. and Memoli, V. (2015), ‘Does democratization foster state consolidation? Democratic rule, political order and administrative capacity’, Governance 28(1): 524.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cardenas, M. (2010), ‘State capacity in Latin America’. Presidential Lecture of the Latin American and Caribbean Economic Association (LACEA), October 3, 2009, Buenos Aires, Argentina.Google Scholar
Centeno, M. (2009), ‘El Estado en América Latina’, Revista Cidob d’Afers Internacionals 85–86: 1131.Google Scholar
Charrón, N. and Lapuente, V. (2010), ‘Does democracy produce quality of government?’, European Journal of Political Research 49(4): 443470.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cheibub, J. (1998), ‘Political regimes and the extractive capacity of Governments: taxation in democracies and dictatorships’, World Politics 50(3): 349376.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Collier, P. and Rohner, D. (2008), ‘Democracy, development and conflict’, Journal of the European Economic Association 6(2–3): 531540.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Coppedge, M. (1997), ‘A classification of Latin American Political Parties’. Kellogg Institute Working Paper No. 244, Notre Dame, Paris.Google Scholar
Dahl, R. (1989), Democracy and its Critics, New Haven, CT: Yale University Press.Google Scholar
De Soto, H. (1989), The Other Path, New York, NY: Harper and Row.Google Scholar
Feldmann, E.A. (2012), ‘Measuring the Colombian “Success” story’, Revista de Ciencia Política 3: 739752.Google Scholar
Flores-Macías, G.A. (2014), ‘Financing security through elite taxation: the case of Colombia’s “Democratic security Taxes”’, Studies in Comparative International Development 49(4): 477500.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fortin, J. (2010), ‘A tool to evaluate state capacity in post-communist countries, 1989–2006’, European Journal of Political Research 49(5): 654686.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fukuyama, F. (2005), ‘Stateness first’, Journal of Democracy 16(1): 8488.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fukuyama, F. (2007), ‘Liberalism versus State-Building’, Journal of Democracy 18(3): 1013.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fukuyama, F. and Colby, S. (2011), ‘Half a miracle. Foreign Policy’, May/June. Retrieved 28 October 2015 from http://www.foreignpolicy.com/articles/2011/04/25/half_a_miracle Google Scholar
Gilley, B. (2006), ‘The determinants of state legitimacy: results for 72 countries’, International Political Science Review 27(1): 4771.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gómez, S., Carlos, J. and Jiménez, J.P. (2012), ‘Tax structure and tax evasion in Latin America’. Paper No. 118, Serie macroeconomía del desarrollo, Cepal, Santiago de Chile.Google Scholar
Grassi, D. (2014), ‘Democracy, social welfare and political violence: the case of Latin America’, Journal of International Relations and Development 17(2): 242273.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Green, W.H. (2008), Econometric Analysis, 6th edn., Upper Saddle River, NJ: Prentice Hall.Google Scholar
Grindle, M.S. (2010), ‘Constructing, deconstructing, and reconstructing career civil service systems in Latin America’. HKS Faculty Research Working Paper Series, RWP10-025, John F. Kennedy School of Government, Harvard University, Cambridge.Google Scholar
Grugel, J. and Riggirozzi, P. (2012), ‘Post‐neoliberalism in Latin America: rebuilding and reclaiming the state after crisis’, Development and Change 43(1): 121.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gurr, T.R. (1994), ‘Peoples against states: ethnopolitical conflict and the changing world system: 1994 presidential address’, International Studies Quarterly 38: 347377.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gutiérrez, F. (2011), ‘Evaluating state performance: a critical view of state failure and fragility indexes’, European Journal of Development Research 23(1): 2042.Google Scholar
Haggard, S. and Kaufman, R.R. (2008), Development, Democracy and Welfare States, Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Hagopian, F. and Mainwaring, S. (2005), The Third Wave of Democratization in Latin America: Advances and Setbacks, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Hanson, J.K. and Sigman, R. (2013), ‘Leviathan’s latent dimensions: measuring state capacity for comparative political research’. Manuscript, Maxwell School of Citizenship and Public Affairs, Syracuse University, New York.Google Scholar
Hendrix, C. (2010), ‘Measuring state capacity: theoretical and empirical implications for the study of civil conflict’, Journal of Peace Research 47(3): 273285.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Herbst, J. and Mills, G. (2006), ‘Africa’s big dysfunctional states : an introductory overview’, in C. Clapham, J. Herbst and G. Mills (eds), Big African States, Johannesburg: Wits University Press, pp. 116.Google Scholar
Huber, E. and Stephens, J.D. (2012), Democracy and the Left: Social Policy and Inequality in Latin America, Chicago, IL: University of Chicago Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Huber, E., Rueschemeyer, D. and Stephens, J.D. (1997), ‘The paradoxes of contemporary democracy: formal, participatory, and social dimensions’, Comparative Politics 29(3): 323342.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Huber, E., Nielsen, F., Pribble, J. and Stephens, J.D. (2006), ‘Politics and inequality in Latin America and the Caribbean’, American Sociological Review 71(6): 943963.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Huber, E., Stephens, J., Mustillo, T. and Pribble, J. (2012), ‘Latin America and the Caribbean political dataset, 1945–2008’. Retrieved 28 October 2015 from http://www.unc.edu/~jdsteph/documents/common/data/Codebook_LAC_Political_2012.doc Google Scholar
Hunter, W. and Sugiyama, N.B. (2014), ‘Transforming subjects into citizens: insights from Brazil’s Bolsa Família’, Perspectives on Politics 12(4): 829845.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
IMD World Competitiveness Center (2011), ‘World competitiveness on line’. Retrieved from https://worldcompetitiveness.imd.org/ Google Scholar
Karl, T. (2004), Encyclopedia of Energy, Vol. 4, Elsevier Inc, Atlanta. Google Scholar
Kirby, P. (2009), ‘Globalisation and the state: what lessons does the Latin American “new left” have to offer?’. Annual Globalisation Lecture, Institute for the Study of the Americas, University of London, January 21, London.Google Scholar
Levi, M. (2002), ‘The state of the study of the state’, in I. Katznelson and H. Milner (eds), Political Science: The State of the Discipline, London: APSA/Norton, pp. 3355.Google Scholar
Levi, M. and Sacks, A. (2009), ‘Legitimating beliefs: sources and indicators’, Regulation & Governance 3(4): 311333.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Levitsky, S. and Roberts, K. (eds) (2011), The Resurgence of the Latin American Left, Baltimore, MD: Johns Hopkins University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Levistsky, S. (2013), ‘Peru the challenge of a democracy without parties’, in J.I. Domínguez and M. Shifter (eds), Constructing Democratic Governance in Latin America, Baltimore, MD: JHU Press, pp. 282315.Google Scholar
Levitsky, S. and Way, L. (2002), ‘The rise of competitive authoritarianism’, Journal of Democracy 13(2): 5165.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Linz, J.J. and Stepan, A. (1996), Problems of Democratic Transition and Consolidation: Southern Europe, South America, and Post-Communist Europe, Baltimore, MD: The Johns Hopkins University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Luna, J.P. (2006), ‘Frente Amplio and the crafting of social democratic alternatives in Uruguay’. Unpublished paper, Instituto de Ciencia Política, Universidad Católica de Chile, Chile.Google Scholar
Macdonald, L. and Ruckert, A. (eds) (2009), Post-Neoliberalism in the Americas, England: Palgrave Macmillan.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mainwaring, S., Brinks, D. and Liñán, A.P. (2001), ‘Classificando Regimes Políticos na América Latina, 1945-1999’, DADOS-Revista de Ciências Sociais 44(4): 645688.Google Scholar
Mann, M. (2008), ‘Infrastructural power revisited’, Studies in Comparative International Development 43(3–4): 355365.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mansfield, E. and Snyder, J. (2005), Electing to Fight: Why Emerging Democracies Go to War, Cambridge: MIT Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Martinez-Gallardo, C. (2011), ‘Designing cabinets: presidential politics and cabinet instability in Latin America’. Kellogg Institute Working Paper 375, University of Notre Dame, Notre Dame.Google Scholar
Mata, J.F. and Ziaja, S. (2009), Users’ Guide on Measuring Fragility, Germany: German Development Inst.Google Scholar
Merkel, W. (2001), ‘Embedded and defective democracies’. Paper presented at the Meeting of the American Political Science Association, Washington, DC, August 31--September 3.Google Scholar
Missoni, E. and Solimano, G. (2010), ‘Towards universal health coverage: the Chilean experience. World health report’. Background Paper, 4, World Health Organization, Switzerland.Google Scholar
North, D. (1981), Structure and change in economic history, New York: Norton.Google Scholar
O’Donnell, G. (1993), ‘On the state, democratization, and some conceptual problems: a Latin American view with some glances at post-communist countries’, World Development 21(8): 13551369.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Panizza, F. (2005), ‘Unarmed Utopia revisited: the resurgence of left-of-centre politics in Latin America’, Political Studies 53: 716734.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Pellegrini, L. and Gerlagh, R. (2008), ‘Causes of corruption: a survey of cross-country analyses and extended results’, Economics of Governance 9: 245263.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Pribble, J. (2013), Welfare and Party Politics in Latin America, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rangel, A. (2005), Sostenibilidad de la Seguridad Democrática, Bogotá: Fundación seguridad y democracia.Google Scholar
Rauch, J.E. and Evans, P.B. (2000), ‘Bureaucratic structure and bureaucratic performance in less developed countries’, Journal of Public Economics 75(1): 4971.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Saylor, R. (2012), ‘Sources of state capacity in Latin America: commodity booms and state building motives in Chile’, Theory and Society 41(3): 301324.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Schmitter, P., Wagemann, C. and Obydenkova, A. (2005), ‘Democratization and state capacity’. Paper presented at the X Congreso Internacional del CLAD sobre la Reforma del Estado y de la Administración Pública, October 18–21, Santiago, Chile.Google Scholar
Schumacher, G. and Vis, B. (2009), ‘Party organization, electoral competition and reform of welfare state generosity in OECD countries, 1973–2002’. Paper Prepared for the Annual Meeting of the APSA, September 3–6, Toronto.Google Scholar
Sikkink, K. (1991), Ideas and Institutions: Developmentalism in Brazil and Argentina, Ithaca, NY and London: Cornell University Press.Google Scholar
Slater, D. (2008), ‘Can Leviathan be democratic? Competitive elections, robust mass politics and state infrastructural power’, Studies in Comparative International Development 43: 252272.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Soifer, H.D. (2012), ‘Measuring state capacity in contemporary Latin America’, Revista de Ciencia Política 32(3): 585598.Google Scholar
Sojo, C. (2011), The State Under Scrutiny: Public Opinion, Stateness and Government Performance in Latin America, Santiago de Chile: Cepal.Google Scholar
Stock, J. and Watson, M. (2008), ‘Heteroskedasticity-robust standard errors for fixed effects panel data regression’, Econometrica 76: 155174.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
UNRISD (2010), ‘Combating poverty and inequality: structural change, social policy and politics’, UNRISD – UN Publications, Geneva. Retrieved 28 October 2015 from http://www.unrisd.org/publications/cpi#sthash.XH2xuawX.dpuf Google Scholar
Waiselfisz, J.J. (2013), Mapa da violência 2013, Rio de Janeiro: Cebal.Google Scholar
Weber, M. (1965), Politics as a Vocation, Philadelphia, PA: Fortress Press.Google Scholar
Weyland, K., Madrid, R.L. and Hunter, W. (eds) (2010), Left ist Governments in Latin America: Successes and Shortcomings, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wooldridge, J. (2009), Introductory Econometrics: A Modern Approach, 4th edn., Cincinnati, OH: South-Western.Google Scholar
World Bank (2014), ‘World development indicators’. Retrieved 28 October 2014 from http://data.worldbank.org/data-catalog/world-development-indicators.Google Scholar
Zakaria, F. (1997), ‘The rise of illiberal democracy’, Foreign Affairs 76(6): 2243.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Figure 0

Figure 1 Differences in stateness (1995–2009).Note: State capacity data set (see Hanson and Sigman, 2013).

Figure 1

Table 1 The effect of democracy and partisanship on stateness in Latin American

Figure 2

Figure 2 Marginal effect of democracy.Note: The figure displays the predictive margins with 95% confidence interval of democracy (Polity IV×Polity IV) reported in Table 1 model 3.

Supplementary material: Link

Grassi et al. Dataset

Link