Hostname: page-component-cd9895bd7-lnqnp Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-12-23T19:10:20.906Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

A Note on nonconvex adjustment costs in lumpy investment models: Mean versus variance

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  31 March 2022

Min Fang*
Affiliation:
Department of Economics, HEC Lausanne, University of Lausanne, 1015 Lausanne, Switzerland Geneva Finance Research Institute and Geneva School of Economics and Management, University of Geneva, 24 rue du General-Dufour, 1211 Geneva, Switzerland
Rights & Permissions [Opens in a new window]

Abstract

This paper revisits the canonical assumption of nonconvex capital adjustment costs in lumpy investment models as in Khan and Thomas [(2008) Econometrica 76(2), 395–436], which are assumed to follow a uniform distribution from zero to an upper bound, without distinguishing between the mean and the variance of the distribution. Unlike the usual claim that the upper bound stands for the size (represented by the mean) of a nonconvex cost, I show that in order to generate an empirically consistent interest elasticity of aggregate investment, both a sizable mean and a sizable variance are necessary. The mean governs the importance of the extensive margin in aggregate investment dynamics, while the variance governs how sensitive the extensive margin is to changes in the real interest rate. As a result, both the mean and the variance are quantitatively important for aggregate investment dynamics.

Type
Articles
Creative Commons
Creative Common License - CCCreative Common License - BY
This is an Open Access article, distributed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution licence (https://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/), which permits unrestricted re-use, distribution, and reproduction in any medium, provided the original work is properly cited.
Copyright
© 2022 Cambridge University Press

1. Introduction

In all current lumpy investment models such as Khan and Thomas (Reference Khan and Thomas2008), the nonconvex capital adjustment cost $\xi _{jt}$ is uniformly distributed with support $U[0,\bar{\xi }]$ independently across firms and time. A conventional calibration of a small upper bound $\bar{\xi }$ which matches the firm-level lumpy investment moments claims that lumpy investment is irrelevant for aggregate dynamics.

However, recent literature [Fang (Reference Fang2020), Koby and Wolf (Reference Koby and Wolf2020) and Winberry (Reference Winberry2021)] reverses the claim that microeconomic investment lumpiness is inconsequential for macroeconomic analysis. As argued by Koby and Wolf (Reference Koby and Wolf2020), whether general equilibrium feedback smooths out the effects of micro frictions is governed by the sensitivity of investment with respect to changes in the costs of and the returns to capital. These costs and returns are either mainly reflected in real interest rate changes or are isomorphic to such changes.Footnote 1

In Khan and Thomas (Reference Khan and Thomas2008), aggregate investment is extremely price-sensitive; the partial equilibrium interest rate semi-elasticity of firm investment is almost 500 percent. As a result, small countercyclical changes in prices are enough to smooth out the movements in investment demand caused by micro lumpiness given prices. In contrast, in Winberry (Reference Winberry2021), Koby and Wolf (Reference Koby and Wolf2020) and Fang (Reference Fang2020), the partial equilibrium interest rate semi-elasticity of firm investment is only between 5 to 8 percent. As a result, they show that lumpy investment matters for business cycle dynamics and the effectiveness of economic policies.

The key argument in these papers Fang (Reference Fang2020), Koby and Wolf (Reference Koby and Wolf2020) and Winberry (Reference Winberry2021)] is that the upper bound $\bar{\xi }$ of the distribution of nonconvex capital adjustment costs should be calibrated as much larger. This upper bound $\bar{\xi }$ determines how sensitive aggregate investment is to changes in the real interest rate. The calibration of a small (large) upper bound $\bar{\xi }$ generates a large (small) interest elasticity of aggregate investment. Quasi-experimental evidence on firm-level investment responses to tax changes [Zwick and Mahon (Reference Zwick and Mahon2017) and Koby and Wolf (Reference Koby and Wolf2020)] suggests a small interest elasticity. Consequently, the upper bound $\bar{\xi }$ should be large.

What is the economics meaning of calibrating such a large upper bound $\bar{\xi }$ ? In all current models, the setup implicitly assumes that the mean $\mu _{\xi }=\bar{\xi }/2$ and the standard deviation $\sigma _{\xi }=\bar{\xi }/\sqrt{12}$ are isometric $\left(\mu _{\xi }=\sqrt{3}\sigma _{\xi }\right)$ . This assumption means that when calibrating $\bar{\xi }$ , we jointly choose the expected size (mean) and the uncertainty (variance) of the nonconvex adjustment cost faced by the firms. Then, which one determines the interest elasticity of aggregate investment?

In this paper, I answer this question through disciplining the economic meanings of the expected size (mean) and the uncertainty (variance) of the nonconvex adjustment cost. I assume the nonconvex adjustment cost follows a uniform distribution with mean and variance $\{\mu _{\xi }, \sigma _{\xi }\}$ :

(1) \begin{equation} \xi _{jt} \sim U\left[\mu _{\xi } - \sqrt{3}\sigma _{\xi }, \mu _{\xi } + \sqrt{3}\sigma _{\xi }\right]. \end{equation}

I first compare the interest elasticity of aggregate investment over both dimensions of $\{\mu _{\xi }, \sigma _{\xi }\}$ , departing from a conventionally calibrated lumpy investment model. The model generates unrealistically large interest elasticities of aggregate investment when either the mean or the variance approach zero. I find that both a sizable mean and a sizable variance are necessary to generate an empirically consistent interest elasticity of aggregate investment.

Further inspection of the mechanism shows that the mean and the variance play different roles. A decomposition of the interest elasticity between the extensive margin and the intensive margin indicates the different roles of the mean and the variance. Without a sizable mean, the unrealistically large interest elasticity is mainly from the unconstrained intensive margin.Footnote 2 Without a sizable variance, the unrealistically large interest elasticity is mainly from the oversensitive extensive margin. The underlying distribution of the extensive margin adjustment probability and intensive margin investment rate confirm these patterns.

Finally, I show the dynamic implications of the importance of having a sizable mean and a sizable variance. Without a sizable mean, there is neither state-dependency nor non-linearity of the state-dependency due to the micro lumpiness. The countercyclical changes in real interest rates hardly generate any state-dependency in aggregate investment. Without a sizable variance, the state-dependency and the non-linearity of the state-dependency are both unrealistically strong. The large interest elasticity to countercyclical changes in real interest rates smooths out the recessionary effects when the economy is in recession. Therefore, a sizable mean and a sizable variance are both quantitatively necessary for aggregate investment dynamics.

This paper is organized as follows. Section 2 presents the model and the solution method. Section 3 shows the interest elasticity of aggregate investment with respect to the mean and the variance, respectively. Section 4 further inspects the mechanism. Section 5 shows the impulse responses in alternative calibrations. Finally, Section 6 concludes.

2. The model

The economy consists of a fixed unit mass of firms $j\in [0,1]$ which produce homogeneous output $y_{jt}$ and a unit measure continuum of identical households who consume output and supply labor.

Technology: The production function is as follows:

(2) \begin{equation} y_{jt} = A_t z_{jt}k_{jt}^\alpha n_{jt}^\nu{, } \ \alpha +\nu \lt 1, \end{equation}

where $k_{jt}$ and $n_{jt}$ indicates the idiosyncratic capital and labor employed by the firm $j$ , and $A_t$ is aggregate productivity. For each firm, the idiosyncratic TFP $z_{jt}$ follows a log-normal AR(1):

(3) \begin{equation} log\left(z_{jt}\right) = -\left(1-\rho ^z\right) \frac{\sigma ^{z^2}}{2\left(1-\rho ^{z^2}\right)} + \rho ^z log\left(z_{jt-1}\right) + \epsilon _{jt}, \quad \epsilon _{jt}\sim N\left(0,\sigma ^z\right). \end{equation}

Adjustment costs: The investment cost function includes two components: a direct cost $i_{jt}$ and a fixed nonconvex capital adjustment cost $\xi _{jt}$ paid in units of labor if the firm adjusts by more than a small proportion of their current capital stock $(|ak|)$ :

(4) \begin{equation} c\!\left(i_{jt}\right) = i_{jt} + \mathbf{1}_{\left(|i_{jt}|\gt ak_{jt}\right)}\cdot w_t\cdot \xi _{jt}, \quad \xi _{jt}. \end{equation}

Firm Optimization: I denote by $V^A\!\left(k_{jt},z_{jt};\;\Omega _t\right)$ , $V^{NA}\!\left(k_{jt},z_{jt};\;\Omega _t\right)$ , and $V\!\left(k_{jt},z_{jt};\;\Omega _t\right)$ $\equiv$ $E_{\xi _{jt}}\tilde{V}\big(k_{jt},z_{jt},$ $\xi _{jt};\;\Omega _t\big)$ the value functions of a firm with an active investment choice, without an active investment choice, and with expected draw of $\xi _{jt}$ . The aggregate state $\Omega _t = \left(A_t, \Theta _t,\mu _t\left(k,z,\xi \right)\right)$ where $\Theta _t$ is a vector comprising the stochastic discount factor and wage at time $t$ , and $\mu _t(k,z,\xi )$ is the distribution of firms. The value functions are as follows:

(5) \begin{equation} V^A\!\left(k_{jt},z_{jt};\;\Omega _t\right) = \max _{i,n} \left\{ y_{jt} - w_t n_{jt} - c\!\left(i_{jt}\right) + \mathbb{E}\!\left[\Lambda _{t,t+1} V\!\left(k^*_{jt+1},z_{jt+1};\; \Omega _{t+1}\right)\right] \right\}, \end{equation}
(6) \begin{equation} V^{NA}\!\left(k_{jt},z_{jt};\;\Omega _t\right) = \max _{i\in [-ak,ak],n} \Big \{ y_{jt} - w_t n_{jt} - c\!\left(i_{jt}\right) + \mathbb{E}\!\left[\Lambda _{t,t+1} V\!\left(k^C_{jt+1},z_{jt+1};\; \Omega _{t+1}\right)\right] \Big \}, \end{equation}

where the stochastic discount factor $\Lambda _{t,t+1}$ is derived from the household problem since households own all the firms. $k^C_{jt+1}$ and $k^*_{jt+1}$ are the constrained and non-constrained capital choices.

The firm will choose to pay the fixed cost if and only if $ V^{A}\!\left(k_{jt},z_{jt};\;\Omega _t\right) - w_t \xi _{jt} \gt V^{NA}\!\left(k_{jt},z_{jt};\;\Omega _t\right)$ . There is a unique threshold $\xi ^*\!\left(k_{jt},z_{jt};\;\Omega _t\right)$ at which the firm breaks even:

(7) \begin{equation} \xi ^*_t\!\left(k_{jt},z_{jt};\;\Omega _t\right) = \frac{V^{A}\!\left(k_{jt},z_{jt};\;\Omega _t\right)-V^{NA}\!\left(k_{jt},z_{jt};\;\Omega _t\right)}{w_t}. \end{equation}

If a firm draws a fixed cost $\xi _{jt}$ below $\xi ^*(k_{jt},z_{jt};\;\Omega _t)$ (which I denote as $\xi ^*$ for short), the firm pays the fixed cost and then actively adjusts its capital, otherwise it does not. The value function is:

(8) \begin{equation} V\!\left(k_{jt},z_{jt};\;\Omega _t\right) = -\frac{w_t \!\left(\xi ^*+\underline{\xi }\right)}{2} + \frac{\xi ^*-\underline{\xi }}{2\sqrt{3}\sigma _{\xi }} V^A\!\left(k_{jt},z_{jt};\;\Omega _t\right) + \left(1-\frac{\xi ^*-\underline{\xi }}{2\sqrt{3}\sigma _{\xi }}\right)V^{NA}\!\left(k_{jt},z_{jt};\;\Omega _t\right), \end{equation}

where $\underline{\xi }=\mu _{\xi } - \sqrt{3}\sigma _{\xi }$ is the lower bound of the fixed cost. The firm expects to pay the fixed cost when drawing $\xi _{jt}$ lower than $\xi ^*(k_{jt},z_{jt};\;\Omega _t)$ . With probability $\frac{\xi ^*-\underline{\xi }}{2\sqrt{3}\sigma _{\xi }}$ , the firm chooses to actively invest, otherwise it stays inactive. Therefore, the capital stock evolves by the law of motion:

(9) \begin{equation} k_{jt+1} = \left \{ \begin{array}{l@{\quad}l@{\quad}l} \left(1-\delta \right)k_{jt} + i^*_{jt} & &{\xi _{jt}\lt \xi ^*\!\left(k_{jt},z_{jt};\;\Omega _t\right)}\\[4pt] \left(1-\delta \right)k_{jt} + i^C_{jt} & &{otherwise}\\ \end{array} \right .. \end{equation}

Household optimization: Households’ expected utility is as follows:

\begin{equation*} E_0\sum _{t=0}^{\infty } \beta ^t \left ( \frac {C_t^{1-\eta }}{1-\eta }-\theta N_t \right ), \end{equation*}

subject to the budget constraint: $C_t + \frac{1}{R_t} B_t \leq B_{t-1} + w_t N_t + \Pi ^F_t$ . Here $\beta$ is the discount factor of households, $\theta$ is the disutility of working, $R_t$ is the real interest rate, $B_t$ is one period bonds, $w_t$ is the nominal wage, and $\Pi ^F_t$ is the nominal profits from all the firms. The first order conditions of consumption, labor, and bonds deliver:

(10) \begin{equation} w_t = -\frac{U_n\!\left(C_t,N_t\right)}{U_c\!\left(C_t,N_t\right)} = \theta C_t^\eta, \end{equation}
(11) \begin{equation} \Lambda _{t,t+1} = \frac{1}{R_t} = \beta \frac{U_c\!\left(C_{t+1},N_{t+1}\right)}{U_c\!\left(C_{t},N_{t}\right)} = \beta \!\left(\frac{C_t}{C_{t+1}}\right)^\eta. \end{equation}

Equilibrium Definition:

Definition 1. A Recursive Equilibrium for this economy is defined by a set of value functions and policy functions $\left\{V\left(k,z;\;\Omega \right)\right.$ , $V^A\left(k,z;\;\Omega \right)$ , $V^{NA}\left(k,z;\;\Omega \right)$ , $\xi ^*\left(k,z;\Omega \right)$ , $k^*\left(k,z;\;\Omega \right)$ , $k^C\left(k,z;\;\Omega \right)\}$ , a set of quantity functions $\left\{C(\Omega )\right.$ , $N(\Omega )$ , $Y(\Omega )$ , $\left.K(\Omega )\right\}$ , a set of price functions $\left\{w(\Omega )\right.$ , $\Lambda (\Omega )$ , $\left.R(\Omega )\right\}$ , and a distribution $\mu '(\Omega )$ that solves the firms’ and households’ problems and satisfies market clearing such that:

  1. (i) Taking the price functions as given, the policy functions solve firms’ optimization.

  2. (ii) Taking the price functions as given, the quantity functions solve households’ optimization.

  3. (iii) Goods market clears: $Y(\Omega ) = C(\Omega ) + I(\Omega ) + \Theta _k(\Omega )$ , where $\Theta _k(\Omega )$ is the total adjustment cost.

Solution method: I follow the sequence space solution strategy as in Boppart et al. (Reference Boppart, Krusell and Mitman2018) to solve the model which involves two parts. First, I solve the Stationary Equilibrium at the steady-state, which delivers all the steady-state equilibrium objects and provides the cross-sectional moments for the calibration. Second, I solve the Transitional Equilibrium starting from the Stationary Equilibrium and transit back to the same Stationary Equilibrium. The Transitional Equilibrium then provides the dynamic moments for the calibration and the impulse response functions. Details of the solution method are presented in the appendix.

3. Mean, variance, and the interest elasticity of investment

Benchmark calibration: I calibrate the benchmark model with mean and variance bundled (henceforth, bundled model) as in Khan and Thomas (Reference Khan and Thomas2008) $\Big($ the uniform distribution has support from 0 to an upper bound: $\xi _{jt}\sim U\left[0,\bar{\xi }\right]$ , so $\left.\mu _{\xi }=\sqrt{3}\sigma _{\xi }=\bar{\xi }/2\right)$ to hit the target investment moments. For fixed parameters, I choose the discount factor $\beta =0.99$ to match an annual interest rate of 4%., elasticity of intertemporal substitution $\eta =1$ for log utility, leisure preference $\theta =2$ to match a one-third working time share, capital exponent $\alpha =0.25$ and the labor exponent $\nu =0.60$ to match a labor share of two-thirds and decreasing returns to scale of 85%, quarterly capital depreciation $\delta =0.026$ , free capital adjustment region $a = 0.001$ , and persistence of idiosyncratic TFP shock $\rho ^z=0.95$ . For fitted parameters, I choose $\sigma ^z=0.05$ and $\bar{\xi }=0.6$ to match the average investment rate (10.5%), the standard deviation of investment rates (0.13), the spike rateFootnote 3 (17%), and the partial equilibrium interest elasticity of aggregate investment (−5), reflecting the empirical moments as measured in Zwick and Mahon (Reference Zwick and Mahon2017) and Koby and Wolf (Reference Koby and Wolf2020).Footnote 4

How to measure the interest elasticity? The partial equilibrium interest elasticity of aggregate investment is defined by how aggregate investment, as yielded by the collective decisions of all heterogeneous firms, responds to an unexpected real interest rate shockFootnote 5. For instance, −5 means when firms face an unexpected real interest rate cut of 1%, partial equilibrium aggregate investment increases by 5%. Quasi-experimental evidence in Zwick and Mahon (Reference Zwick and Mahon2017) and Koby and Wolf (Reference Koby and Wolf2020) suggests this interest-elasticity should be about −5.

My exact numerical exercise in Sections 3 and 4 is to have the economy start at steady-state and hit by a one-time unexpected drop in real interest rate in the first period to generate the real interest rate series $\{r_t\}_{t=0}^T=\{r^*, r^*+\Delta r, r^*, ..., r^*\}$ . I then feed the stochastic discount factor series $\{\Lambda _t\}_{t=0}^T=\left\{\frac{1}{1+r^*}, \frac{1}{1+r^*+\Delta r}, ..., \frac{1}{1+r^*}\right\}$ and the steady-state wage series $\{w_t\}_{t=0}^T=\{w^*\}$ into the partial equilibrium and solve for the aggregate investment series $\{I_t\}_{t=0}^T$ . The partial equilibrium interest elasticity is then calculated as $\partial log I_t/\partial r_t$ at time $t=1$ . More specifically, I choose $\Delta r = -0.25\%$ , therefore, a $\partial log I_1/\partial r_1=-5$ means such a one-time unexpected drop in the real interest rate boosts aggregate investment by 1.25%.

Upper bound $\bar{\boldsymbol\xi }$ and interest elasticity: In Figure 1, I plot the model’s interest elasticity as the choice of $\bar{\xi }$ varies from 0.025 to 1. First, the interest elasticity of aggregate investment is very sensitive to changes in the upper bound of the nonconvex adjustment costs.Footnote 6 Second, a relatively large value of $\bar{\xi }=0.6$ gives an interest elasticity of −5. Conversely, if $\bar{\xi }$ is smaller, the aggregate investment will be oversensitive to interest rate changes. In Khan and Thomas (Reference Khan and Thomas2008), $\bar{\xi }=0.0083/4$ , which will deliver an interest elasticity around −500. This will imply that lumpy investment is irrelevant for aggregate dynamics as in Khan and Thomas (Reference Khan and Thomas2008). However, their irrelevance result is not consistent with the joint dynamics of aggregate investment and the real interest rate over the business cycle as shown in Winberry (Reference Winberry2021).

Figure 1. PE interest elasticity over $\bar{\xi }$ . Note: In the benchmark model, the uniform distribution starts from 0 to an upper bound: $\xi _{jt}\sim U[0,\bar{\xi }]$ . It bundles the mean and the variance by $\bar{\xi }$ : $\mu _{\xi }=\sqrt{3}\sigma _{\xi }=\bar{\xi }/2$ . Therefore, increasing $\bar{\xi }$ increases both $\mu _{\xi }$ and $\sigma _{\xi }$ simultaneously.

Mean, variance, and interest elasticity: Now I depart from the benchmark calibration of $\bar{\xi }=0.6$ . Instead, I study two alternative groups of calibrations: One, fixing the variance $\sigma ^*_{\xi }=\bar{\xi }/\sqrt{12}=0.6/\sqrt{12}$ and varying the mean $\mu _{\xi }$ from 0 to $2\mu ^*_{\xi }=\bar{\xi }$ to show how the interest-elasticity changes and two, fixing the mean $\mu ^*_{\xi }=\bar{\xi }/2=0.6/2$ and varying the variance $\sigma _{\xi }$ from 0 to $2\sigma ^*_{\xi }=\bar{\xi }/\sqrt{3}$ , to show how the interest elasticity changes. I use an identical quasi-experimental real interest rate shock as the one in the bundled model experiment above.

The findings plotted in Figure 2 are very interesting. First, the interest elasticity is not solely determined by the expected size (mean) of the nonconvex cost. Unlike common claims that the interest elasticity is controlled by the expected size of the nonconvex cost, the uncertainty (variance) plays a role. In panel (a), even though the mean is set to be relatively large, when the variance approaches zero, the interest elasticity is massive. Given the fixed mean, the model hits the targeted interest elasticity when the variance is equal or larger to that of the bundled model. Second, the interest elasticity is not solely determined by the uncertainty (variance) of the nonconvex cost. In panel (b), even though the variance is fixed to be relatively large when the mean approaches zero, the interest elasticity is again massive. Given the fixed variance, the model hits the targeted interest elasticity when the mean is equal or larger to that of the bundled model.

Figure 2. PE interest elasticity over $\mu _{\xi }$ and $\sigma _{\xi }$ . Note: The variance-fixed model fixes the variance by choosing $\sigma ^*_{\xi }=\bar{\xi }/\sqrt{12}$ and the mean-fixed model fixes the mean by choosing $\mu ^*_{\xi }=\bar{\xi }/2$ . The two models are identical along both vertical dotted lines when $\mu _{\xi }=0.3$ and $\sigma _{\xi }\simeq 0.17$ .

What is the mechanism behind choosing the mean and the variance, respectively?

4. The mechanism

To further inspect the mechanism behind the differences between the mean and the variance, I demonstrate results from three models with three alternative calibrations: (1) the carefully calibrated bundled model (Bundled); (2) a mean-fixed model $\left(\mu ^*_{\xi }=\bar{\xi }/\sqrt{12}\right)$ with zero variance $\left(Zero\hbox{-}\sigma _{\xi }\right)$ ; and (3) a variance-fixed model $\left(\sigma ^*_{\xi }=\bar{\xi }/2\right)$ with zero mean $\left(Zero\hbox{-}\mu _{\xi }\right)$ .

A decomposition of the interest elasticity: I first show the decomposition of the interest elasticity in all three models in terms of both extensive margin and intensive margin investment in Table 1 following the equation below:

(12) \begin{equation} \frac{d\sum I_j}{dr}=\frac{d\sum _{EM} I_j}{dr} + \frac{d\sum _{IM} I_j}{dr}, \end{equation}

where $d\sum I_j$ is aggregate investment, $d\sum _{EM} I_j$ is aggregate extensive margin investment, and $d\sum _{IM} I_j$ is aggregate intensive margin investment. The carefully calibrated Bundled model has an interest elasticity of −5.1, 96% of the investment response is from the extensive margin, and 4% is from the intensive margin. The Zero- $\sigma _{\xi }$ model has an interest elasticity of about −600, which is almost entirely from the extensive margin. The Zero- $\mu _{\xi }$ model has an interest elasticity of −80, but which is mainly from the intensive margin.

This decomposition shows that the mean and the variance play different roles. Without a sizable mean, the response of the aggregate investment to the interest rate is mainly from the intensive margin. The intensive margin is much too sensitive to real interest rate changes, which delivers a falsely large interest elasticity of aggregate investment. Without a sizable variance, the response of aggregate investment to the interest rate is mainly from the extensive margin. The extensive margin is extremely sensitive to changes in real interest rates. A firm either chooses to pay $\mu _{\xi }^*$ and invest a lot or stay inactive when the real interest rate changes. Firms on the extensive margin choose to ”all-in” which creates the unrealistically large interest elasticity.

Table 1. A decomposition of the interest elasticity

Note: The Bundled model has the calibration that matches the micro investment moments. The Zero- $\sigma _{\xi }$ deviates by setting $\sigma _{\xi }$ to zero while all other parameters are unchanged. The Zero- $\mu _{\xi }$ deviates by setting $\mu _{\xi }$ to zero while all other parameters are unchanged. EM stands for the extensive margin and IM stands for the intensive margin.

Distributions of the extensive margin and the intensive margin: In Figure 3, I plot the interpolated distributions of the extensive margin (adjustment probability) and the intensive margin (investment rate conditional on adjustment) at the steady states using two-dimensional interpolation with respect to productivity and capital stock. Since the intensive margin distributions are not much changed across models, I only plot these for the Bundled model. Warmer and darker colors indicate higher investment rates and higher adjustment probabilities.

Figure 3. Distributions of the extensive margin and the intensive margin. Note: This figure shows the distribution of firms’ investment decisions at both the extensive margin and intensive margin conditional on their productivity and capital stock. Since the intensive margin distributions are not much changed across models, I only plot these for the Bundled model. We could decompose firms’ investment decisions in two steps. Take the Bundled model for example; for firms at Productivity Grid 40 and Capital Grid 30, between 15% and 30% of these firms, according to the extensive margin rules in panel (b), would invest positively by 10% to 20%, according to the intensive margin rules in panel (a), and for firms at Productivity Grid 10 and Capital Grid 35, between 45% and 60% of these firms, according to panel (b), would disinvest, according to panel (a). Aggregate investment of the economy is, therefore, an integration of the extensive margin multiplying the intensive margin over the entire distribution.

In panel (a) for the Bundled model, we see that higher productivity and lower capital firms invest more at the steady state. These firm will also invest more in response to the opportunity presented by the interest rate shock. In contrast, lower productivity and higher capital firms disinvest at the steady state. In panel (b), we see that the extensive margin distribution is layered from 0% probability of adjustment along the diagonal to higher probabilities away from the diagonal where productivity-capital mismatches are more severe. For the highest (lowest) productivity and lowest (highest) capital firms, the adjustment probabilities are larger than 75%. Conditional on draws of the nonconvex adjustment costs, a proportion of the high productivity and low capital firms to the right of the diagonal would then invest positively and the low productivity and high capital firms to the left of the diagonal would than disinvest, both according to the intensive margin rules in panel (a).

However, for the Zero- $\sigma _{\xi }$ model and the Zero- $\mu _{\xi }$ model, the extensive margin distributions are entirely different. The extensive margin in the Zero- $\sigma _{\xi }$ model shows a vertical sorting pattern that is sharply moving from a 0% probability of adjusting to almost a 100% possibility of adjusting. Even slight changes in interest rate would easily cause massive movements in the boundaries, boosting firms at the margins to dramatically change from 0% to >75% or vice versa. As a result, the extensive margin is extremely interest rate sensitive. In contrast, the extensive margin adjustment probability in the Zero- $\mu _{\xi }$ model is always higher than 45% and has much smaller variations. Changes in the interest rate barely cause movements in the boundaries - the extensive margin is not that sensitive to interest rate changes.

5. Implications of aggregate dynamics

To demonstrate the dynamics implications of the the mechanism behind the differences between the mean and the variance, I show the impulse responses of aggregate investment to aggregate TFP shocks in the same three alternative calibrations: (1) the carefully calibrated bundled model (Bundled); (2) the mean-fixed model $\left(\mu ^*_{\xi }=\bar{\xi }/\sqrt{12}\right)$ with zero variance (Zero- $\sigma _{\xi })$ ; and (3) the variance-fixed model $\left(\sigma ^*_{\xi }=\bar{\xi }/2\right)$ with zero mean $\left(Zero\hbox{-}\mu _{\xi }\right)$ .

My exact numerical exercises start the economy at steady-state, then impose an unexpected aggregate productivity shock with persistence $\rho =0.8$ : $\{A_t\}_{t=0}^T=\{A^*, A^* + a, A^* + \rho a, A^* + \rho ^2 a, ..., A^*\}$ . I feed the aggregate productivity series into the general equilibrium and solve for the aggregate investment series $\{I_t\}_{t=0}^T$ . To demonstrate the state-dependency and the non-linearity of the state-dependency due to the micro lumpiness, I solve for four scenarios $\{a\} = \{+5\%, -5\%, +10\%, -10\%\}$ as representations for $\{$ Small Boom, Small Recession, Large Boom, Large Recession $\}$ for all three models, respectively. I then calculate the impulse responses relative to the steady-state in absolute value in percentages $\left\{100\% \times \left|\frac{I_t - I^*}{I*}\right|\right\}_{t=1}^T$ .

The impulse responses are plotted in Figure 4. In panel (a) for the Bundled model, we first observe strong state-dependency: compared to a small recession, aggregate investment responds by 6% more (21.6% relative to 20.4%) in a small boom. Second, the state-dependency is non-linear due to the size of the TFP shock: compared to a large recession, aggregate investment responds by 11% more (43.9% relative to 39.5%) in a large boom. These results show how lumpy investment is consequential for macroeconomic analysis.

Figure 4. GE impulse responses to TFP shocks. Note: The economy starts at steady-state $t=0$ is hit by an unexpected aggregate productivity shock with persistence $\rho =0.8$ : $\left\{A_t\right\}_{t=0}^T=\left\{A^*, A^* + a, A^* + \rho a, A^* + \rho ^2 a, ..., A^*\right\}$ . Scenarios $\{$ Small Boom, Small Recession, Large Boom, Large Recession $\}$ for all three models have a corresponding TFP shocks $\{a\} = \{+5\%, -5\%, +10\%, -10\%\}$ , respectively. The impulse responses relative to the steady-state are absolute value in percentages $\left\{100\% \times \left|\frac{I_t - I^*}{I*}\right|\right\}_{t=1}^T$ .

However, this is not the case for either the Zero- $\sigma _{\xi }$ model or the Zero- $\mu _{\xi }$ model. In panel (b) for the Zero- $\sigma _{\xi }$ model, the state-dependency and the non-linearity of the state-dependency are both unusually strong as well as are the magnitudes of the impulse responses. Aggregate investment responds by 83% more(134% relative to 73%) and by 153% more (220% relative to 87%) in a small/larger boom relative to a small/large recession, respectively. This is all because the extensive margin is extremely sensitive to the countercyclical changes in real interest rates which smooth out the recessionary effects when the economy is in recessions. In panel (c) for the Zero- $\mu _{\xi }$ model, in contrast, there is almost no state-dependency or non-linearity of the state-dependency. Since the response of aggregate investment to the interest rate is mainly from the intensive margin, the countercyclical changes in real interest rates hardly generate any state-dependency in aggregate investment.

6. Concluding remarks

Nonconvex capital adjustment costs play an essential role in generating data-consistent lumpy investment behaviors. The literature usually assumes a uniform distribution for the nonconvex adjustment cost with support from 0 to an upper bound, which does not distinguish the separate roles played by the mean and the variance of the distribution. In this paper, I show that both a sizable mean and a sizable variance are necessary for lumpy investment models to generate an empirically consistent interest elasticity of aggregate investment. The mean governs the degree to which the extensive margin accounts for aggregate investment dynamics. In contrast, the variance controls how sensitive the extensive margin is to interest rate changes. Therefore, both are quantitatively necessary in a reasonably calibrated lumpy investment model.

There are two potential directions of future research. First, more realistic estimations of the mean and the variance using microdata on firm-level investment to better represent the expected size and the uncertainty of the nonconvex capital adjustment cost faced by firms. Second, the separate roles of the mean and the variance potentially matter for other dynamic models with nonconvex adjustment costs such as firm entry and exit, worker hiring and firing, trade entry and exit, inventory dynamics, and many others.

Acknowledgements

This work is generously supported by a grant from the Swiss National Science Foundation under project ID “New methods for asset pricing with frictions”.

Appendix A. Details of the solution methods

Part I: Solving the stationary equilibrium

I first assume the economy at steady-state. This part is very similar as solving an Aiyagari model. The only difference is firms own capital which is subject to adjustment costs. I search for equilibrium wage to clear the labor market. The algorithm is as following:

  1. Step. 1. Guess an equilibrium wage;

  2. Step. 2. Solve the firm’s problem using Value Function Iteration;

  3. Step. 3. Calculate aggregate variables from the firm distribution using Young (Reference Young2010);.

  4. Step. 4. Update the wage with a given weight and return to Step 2 until convergence.

After the convergence, I have the stationary equilibrium aggregate prices $\Omega ^* =$ { $ \Lambda ^*=\beta, w^* = w^*$ }, aggregate quantities $\{C^*(\Omega ^*)$ , $N^*(\Omega ^*)$ , $Y^*(\Omega ^*)$ , $K^*(\Omega ^*)\}$ , firm value functions $\{V^*(k,z;\;\Omega ^*)$ , ${V^A}^*(k,z;\;\Omega ^*)$ , ${V^{NA}}^*(k,z;\;\Omega ^*)$ , policy functions ${\xi ^*}^*(k,z;\;\Omega ^*)$ , ${k'}^*(k,z;\;\Omega ^*)$ , ${l'}^*(k,z;\;\Omega ^*)\}$ , and distribution $\mu (k,z;\;\Omega ^*)$ at the stationary equilibrium state.

Part II: Solving the transitional equilibrium

With the stationary equilibrium solutions in hand, I now move to the solution of the transitional equilibrium using a shooting algorithm. The key assumption here is that after a sufficiently long enough time, the economy will always converge back to its initial stationary equilibrium after any temporary and unexpected (MIT) shocks. The following steps outline the shooting algorithm:

  1. Step. 1. Fix a sufficient long transition period t = 1 to t = T (say 200);

  2. Step. 2. Guess or given a sequence of aggregate price $\{w_t,\Lambda _t\}$ of length T such that the initial prices $\{w_1=w^*,\Lambda _1=\Lambda ^*\}$ (just simply assuming all the prices stay at steady state works well) and terminal prices $\{w_T=w^*,\Lambda _T=\Lambda ^*\}$ . Provide a predetermined shock process of interest, that is, $\{A_t\}$ . This implies a time series for the aggregate state $\{\Omega _t\}_{t=1}^T$ . The aggregate state is just time $t$ .

  3. Step. 3. I know that at time T, the economy is back to its steady state. I have the steady state value function $V\left(k,z;\;\Omega _T\right) = V^*\left(k,z;\;\Omega ^*\right)$ in hand for time T. I solve for the firms’ problem by backward induction given $V\left(k,z;\;\Omega _T\right)$ and $\left\{w_{T-1},\Lambda _{T-1}\right\}$ . This yields the firm value function $V\left(k,z;\;\Omega _{T-1}\right)$ and associated policy functions for capital $k'\left(k,z;\;\Omega _{T-1}\right)$ and labor $l\left(k,z;\;\Omega _{T-1}\right)$ . By iterating backward, I solve the whole series of both policy functions $\left\{k'(k,z;\;\Omega _t)\right\}^T_{t=1}$ and $\left\{l'(k,z;\;\Omega _t)\right\}^T_{t=1}$ .

  4. Step. 4. Given the policy functions and the steady state distribution as the initial distribution $\mu \left(k,z;\;\Omega _1\right) = \mu \left(k,z;\;\Omega ^*\right)$ , I use forward simulation with the non-stochastic simulation in Young (Reference Young2010) to recover the whole path $\left\{\mu (k,z;\;\Omega _t)\right\}_{t=1}^T$ .

  5. Step. 5. Using the distribution $\left\{\mu (k,z)\right\}_1^T$ , I obtain all the aggregate quantities : aggregate output $\{Y\}^T_{t=1}$ , aggregate investment $\{I\}^T_{t=1}$ , aggregate labor demand $\{N\}^T_{t=1}$ , and aggregate capital adjustment costs $\{\Theta _k\}^T_{t=1}$ , we could calculate aggregate adjustment costs $\{\Theta _p\}^T_{t=1}$ . I then use the goods market clearing condition to calculate aggregate consumption $\{C\}^T_{t=1}$ . I then calculate the Excessive Demand $\{\Delta C\}^T_{t=1}$ by taking the differences between currently iterated $\{C\}^T_{t=1}$ and the previous iteration $\left\{C_{old}\right\}^T_{t=1}$ .

  6. Step. 6. Given all the aggregate quantities in the previous step and the Excessive Demand $\{\Delta C\}^T_{t=1}$ , I update all the aggregate prices . I update all equilibrium prices with a line search: $X_t^{new} ={speed} \cdot f_X\left(\left\{\Delta C\right\}^T_{t=1}\right) + (1 -{speed}) \cdot X_t^{old}$ .

Partial equilibrium: Step 1-5 for given sequences of shocks, that is, real interest rate shock which changes the stochastic discount factor $\left\{w_t=w^*,\Lambda _t=\frac{1}{1+r_t}\right\}_{t=1}^T$ for given $\{r_t\}_{t=1}^T$ series.

General equilibrium: Step 1-6 for given sequences of shocks, that is, aggregate productivity shock for given $\{A_t\}_{t=1}^T$ series. Repeat Steps 2-6 until $X_t^{new}$ and $X_t^{old}$ are close enough. Updating all prices in all periods simultaneously reduces the computation burden dramatically.

In all the experiments, I set T = 200, and a step size of 0.1 (only for the $Zero-\sigma _{\xi }$ model, I choose a step size of 0.0001) to ensure convergence, with the necessary distance between $X_t^{new}$ and $X_t^{old}$ smaller than 1e-7. I also tested with various choices of T from 50 to 400 to ensure that the choice of T = 200 does not affect the accuracy of the solution.

B. Upper bound $\bar{\xi }$ and wage elasticity of investment

In contrast, I show the PE wage elasticity of aggregate investment is not sensitive to $\bar{\xi }$ . Since changes in wage is not directly (but indirect) changes in the costs of and the returns to capital. the wage elasticity of aggregate investment is not sensitive to $\bar{\xi }$ at all.

How to measure the wage elasticity? The partial equilibrium wage elasticity of aggregate investment is defined by how aggregate investment, as yielded by the collective decisions of all heterogeneous firms, responds to an unexpected wage shockFootnote 7. For instance, -5 means when firms face an unexpected wage cut of 1%, the partial equilibrium aggregate investment increases by 5%.

The exact numerical exercise in this subsection is to have the economy start at steady-state, hit by a one-time unexpected drop in wage at the first period to generate the wage series $\{w_t\}_{t=0}^T=\{w^*, w^*+\Delta w, ..., w^*\}$ . I then feed the steady-state stochastic discount factor series $\{\Lambda _t\}_{t=0}^T=\left\{\frac{1}{1+r^*}\right\}$ and the wage series $\{w_t\}_{t=0}^T$ into the partial equilibrium transaction and solve for the aggregate investment series $\{I_t\}_{t=0}^T$ . The partial equilibrium wage elasticity is then calculated as $\partial log I_t/\partial r_t$ at time $t=1$ . More specifically, I choose $\Delta w = -1\%*w^*$ , therefore, a $\partial log I_1/\partial w_1=-5$ means such a one-time 1% unexpected drop in wage boosts 5% aggregate investment increment.

In Figure 5, I plot the model’s wage elasticity against the choice of $\bar{\xi }$ from 0.025 to 1. From the figure we could first tell that wage elasticity of aggregate investment is not sensitive to changes in the upper bound of the nonconvex adjustment costs. Second, aggregate investment is not as sensitive to changes in wage than to changes in real interest rate.

Figure 5. PE wage elasticity over $\bar{\xi }$ . Note: In the benchmark model, the uniform distribution starts from 0 to an upper bound: $\xi _{jt}\sim U[0,\bar{\xi }]$ . The red dash line is the PE interest rate elasticity of investment in the data which is about −5.

Footnotes

*

I would like to thank George Alessandria, Yan Bai, Roman Merga, Narayana Kocherlakota, Christian Wolf, Joseph Zeira, and audiences at the University of Rochester for helpful comments and discussions. I am also grateful to an anonymous referee whose comments and suggestions have largely improved this note. All errors are my own.

1 Consider the dynamics of aggregate investment model, general equilibrium feedbacks and monetary policy are directly reflected in real interest rate changes and investment stimulus policies are isomorphic to such changes through the marginal prices of capital.

2 This unconstrained intensive margin is usually constrained by a quadratic adjustment cost in recent literature. To keep this note dedicated to disciplining the mean and the variance, I leave out the quadratic adjustment cost.

3 Spike rate is defined as the proportion of investment rate larger than 20% in a quarter.

4 To make the results more intuitive, I only include the nonconvex fixed cost and did not include the quadratic adjustment cost which usually serves to constrain extreme investment behaviors. As a result, the model cannot exactly match all the micro-investment moments as in Zwick and Mahon (Reference Zwick and Mahon2017).

5 By partial equilibrium, I assume the firms do not take consideration of wage changes as a feedback loop from household decisions. This is consistent with the reduced form estimation from the partial equilibrium perspective.

6 In contrast, I show the PE wage elasticity of aggregate investment over $\bar{\xi }$ in the appendix. Since changes in wage are not directly (but indirect) changes in the costs of and the returns to capital. the wage elasticity of aggregate investment is not sensitive to $\bar{\xi }$ at all.

7 By partial equilibrium, I assume the firms not taking consideration of real interest rate changes as a feedback loop from household decisions. This is consistent with the reduced form estimation from the partial equilibrium perspective.

References

Boppart, T., Krusell, P. and Mitman, K. (2018) Exploiting MIT shocks in heterogeneous-agent economies: The impulse response as a numerical derivative. Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control 89(2), 6892.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fang, M. (2020). Lumpy investment, fluctuations in volatility and monetary policy. SSRN Working Paper, Available at SSRN 3543513.Google Scholar
Khan, A. and Thomas, J. K. (2008) Idiosyncratic shocks and the role of nonconvexities in plant and aggregate investment dynamics. Econometrica 76(2), 395436.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Koby, Y. and Wolf, C. K. (2020) Aggregation in heterogeneous-firm economies: A sufficient statistics approach, Working Paper.Google Scholar
Winberry, T. (2021) Lumpy investment, business cycles, and stimulus policy. American Economic Review 111(1), 364396.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Young, E. R. (2010) Solving the incomplete markets model with aggregate uncertainty using the Krusell–Smith algorithm and non-stochastic simulations. Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control 34(1), 3641.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Zwick, E. and Mahon, J. (2017) Tax policy and heterogeneous investment behavior. American Economic Review 107(1), 217248.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Figure 0

Figure 1. PE interest elasticity over $\bar{\xi }$. Note: In the benchmark model, the uniform distribution starts from 0 to an upper bound: $\xi _{jt}\sim U[0,\bar{\xi }]$. It bundles the mean and the variance by $\bar{\xi }$: $\mu _{\xi }=\sqrt{3}\sigma _{\xi }=\bar{\xi }/2$. Therefore, increasing $\bar{\xi }$ increases both $\mu _{\xi }$ and $\sigma _{\xi }$ simultaneously.

Figure 1

Figure 2. PE interest elasticity over $\mu _{\xi }$ and $\sigma _{\xi }$. Note: The variance-fixed model fixes the variance by choosing $\sigma ^*_{\xi }=\bar{\xi }/\sqrt{12}$ and the mean-fixed model fixes the mean by choosing $\mu ^*_{\xi }=\bar{\xi }/2$. The two models are identical along both vertical dotted lines when $\mu _{\xi }=0.3$ and $\sigma _{\xi }\simeq 0.17$.

Figure 2

Table 1. A decomposition of the interest elasticity

Figure 3

Figure 3. Distributions of the extensive margin and the intensive margin. Note: This figure shows the distribution of firms’ investment decisions at both the extensive margin and intensive margin conditional on their productivity and capital stock. Since the intensive margin distributions are not much changed across models, I only plot these for the Bundled model. We could decompose firms’ investment decisions in two steps. Take the Bundled model for example; for firms at Productivity Grid 40 and Capital Grid 30, between 15% and 30% of these firms, according to the extensive margin rules in panel (b), would invest positively by 10% to 20%, according to the intensive margin rules in panel (a), and for firms at Productivity Grid 10 and Capital Grid 35, between 45% and 60% of these firms, according to panel (b), would disinvest, according to panel (a). Aggregate investment of the economy is, therefore, an integration of the extensive margin multiplying the intensive margin over the entire distribution.

Figure 4

Figure 4. GE impulse responses to TFP shocks. Note: The economy starts at steady-state $t=0$ is hit by an unexpected aggregate productivity shock with persistence $\rho =0.8$: $\left\{A_t\right\}_{t=0}^T=\left\{A^*, A^* + a, A^* + \rho a, A^* + \rho ^2 a, ..., A^*\right\}$. Scenarios $\{$Small Boom, Small Recession, Large Boom, Large Recession$\}$ for all three models have a corresponding TFP shocks $\{a\} = \{+5\%, -5\%, +10\%, -10\%\}$, respectively. The impulse responses relative to the steady-state are absolute value in percentages $\left\{100\% \times \left|\frac{I_t - I^*}{I*}\right|\right\}_{t=1}^T$.