Hostname: page-component-cd9895bd7-jkksz Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-12-22T16:38:12.191Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Africa's Lame Ducks: Second-Term Presidents and the Rule of Law

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  05 April 2023

Giovanni Carbone
Affiliation:
Department of Social and Political Sciences, Università degli Studi di Milano, Milan, Italy
Andrea Cassani*
Affiliation:
Department of Social and Political Sciences, Università degli Studi di Milano, Milan, Italy
*
*Corresponding author. Email: [email protected]
Rights & Permissions [Opens in a new window]

Abstract

The vast majority of sub-Saharan countries have adopted constitutional clauses establishing that elected presidents cannot serve more than two mandates. While an extensive literature has examined why African leaders comply with or else try to manipulate term limits, the policy implications of the latter remain unexplored. Existing studies of other world regions suggest that setting a maximum number of terms presidents can serve tends to make them ‘lame ducks’ during their final mandate. We reconsider this argument, and posit and demonstrate empirically that constitutional limits can actually induce positive effects on second-term presidents' actions compared to their first terms. More specifically, the absence of electoral pressures, the concern for their post-presidential future and legacy-building motivations may lead to improvements in the rule of law, especially regarding the functioning of the judiciary. This article represents the first empirical investigation of the performance of Africa's second-term lame-duck presidents.

Type
Article
Creative Commons
Creative Common License - CCCreative Common License - BY
This is an Open Access article, distributed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution licence (http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/), which permits unrestricted re-use, distribution and reproduction, provided the original article is properly cited.
Copyright
Copyright © The Author(s), 2023. Published by Cambridge University Press on behalf of Government and Opposition Limited

The politics of presidential term limits in Africa as well as in other world regions has attracted growing scholarly attention (Baturo and Elgie Reference Baturo, Elgie, Baturo and Elgie2019; Grauvogel and Heyl Reference Grauvogel and Heyl2020; Heyl and Llanos Reference Heyl and Llanos2022, to name a few recent collections). Much of this literature, however, focused almost exclusively on the role such executive constraints play with regard to political and democratization struggles, including, in particular, their frequent manipulation or attempted manipulation (Dulani Reference Dulani2011; Maboudi et al. Reference Maboudi, Nadi and Eisenstadt2021; McKie Reference McKie2019; Posner and Young Reference Posner, Young and Cheeseman2018; Reyntjens Reference Reyntjens2020; Tull and Simons Reference Tull and Simons2017; Versteeg et al. Reference Versteeg2020; see Suzuki Reference Suzuki, Baturo and Elgie2019 for a notable exception).

The questions that have been largely dodged are how and to what extent the regular functioning of term limits shapes African presidents' behaviours, priorities and policy decisions. Do presidential term limits have implications that reach further than preventing national rulers from overstaying in office? How, if ever, do they affect officeholders' governing behaviour and choices? Limiting a leader's time in office may be only part of the story.

To start filling this gap, we build on the idea borrowed from studies on other world regions (Besley and Case Reference Besley and Case1995; Johnson and Crain Reference Johnson and Crain2004) that governing with the prospect of running for re-election can be very different from governing without such a prospect. Hence, a leader's performance during the first mandate may deviate significantly from his/her second mandate. However, we differ from previous studies in one important respect. While much of the existing literature tends to highlight a ‘lame-duck’ syndrome and to associate incumbents' non-renewable terms with negative policy outcomes, especially in the fiscal sector, we argue that term limits can also have positive consequences on second-term presidents' behaviour.

We contend, in particular, that second-term lame-duck presidents face three specific incentives whose interplay can lead to improvements in the rule of law. Such incentives stem from: the absence of direct pressures to manipulate the rules in order to ease re-election; a personal interest in a more impartial and accessible judiciary apparatus that will help shelter former presidents once they become ordinary citizens and possibly political adversaries of the new rulers; and a legacy-building and reputational motivation. For these reasons, we should observe an improvement in African presidents' rule-of-law performance during their final term in office compared to their first term.

This article offers the first empirical comparative analysis of the performance of Africa's term-limited presidents. An opening section offers a brief overview of the debate on the politics of term limits in Africa. The next section looks at the existing literature on other world regions to introduce the policymaking implications of term limits with regard to the conduct of first- as opposed to second-term presidents. We then develop our theoretical argument about how term limits can lead to rule-of-law improvements in Africa and, in a further section, we offer a systematic picture of term limits and their application (or lack thereof) across the sub-Saharan region. Finally, we present the findings of a statistical investigation covering the 1990–2020 period. The analysis confirms that the rule-of-law performance of African term-limited presidents improves during the second term, especially regarding the judiciary.

Time's up

African rulers have long held their position with no end in sight. In the post-independence politics of the 1960s through the 1980s, many of them hung on somewhat indefinitely (Carbone and Pellegata Reference Carbone and Pellegata2020). When an end to personal rule came, it was often unforeseen and abrupt, caused by either a military coup, or else natural or accidental death. Politics and policies in post-independence Africa were hardly ever affected by the clear prospect of an end to a ruler's spell in power.

With the 1990s transitions to multiparty politics came new or reformed constitutions, which in the vast majority of cases envisaged formal tenure limitations for African presidents (McKie Reference McKie2017). The politics of term limits in Africa has attracted substantial scholarly attention during the past two decades. Research has followed two main directions. First, a debate has emerged about the desirability of such institutional constraints, which remains disputed. The arguments in favour of term limits see them as helpful tools in advancing democracy in a region whose vulnerability to rulers' overstaying in office has been widely demonstrated (Jackson and Rosberg Reference Jackson and Rosberg1982). By forcing leadership change, term limits put into effect the principle that nobody should stay in power for too long, a notion African citizens widely support (Dulani Reference Dulani2015; McKie and Carlson Reference McKie and Carlson2022).

Moreover, term limits regularize a succession mechanism and timeframe. In this regard, while they could merely produce succession between leaders belonging to the same party without hindering or interrupting the latter's political hegemony, in practice they make opposition victories more likely by reducing the so-called ‘incumbency advantage’ (Baturo Reference Baturo2022; Cheeseman Reference Cheeseman2010; Maltz Reference Maltz2007; Venice Commission 2018). Government alternation, in turn, can be instrumental both in democratic consolidation (Huntington Reference Huntington1991) – or, short of it, in ‘liberalizing electoral outcomes’ (Howard and Roessler Reference Howard and Roessler2006) – as well as in broadening support for the political system (Bratton Reference Bratton2004; Moehler and Lindberg Reference Moehler and Lindberg2009).

Limited tenure, however, can hardly be claimed to be a requisite of democracy. The simple fact that parliamentary regimes typically allow an unlimited stay in office for prime ministers, as long as they enjoy legislative support, is a powerful reminder. Moreover, opposition victories can result from electoral manipulation too and the democratic commitment of opposition leaders should not be naively taken for granted (Wahman Reference Wahman2014). The very arguments for term limits can be turned upside down, as limiting re-election arguably limits voters' choices too (Corrales and Penfold Reference Corrales and Penfold2014) and risks dissolving actual and perceived political accountability (De Palma Reference De Palma1994).

A second research strand examines what African leaders do when they reach term limits and, more specifically, their decisions to comply with or else try to remove or bypass legal restrictions. Indeed, the introduction of limited tenure by no means guaranteed the institutional and democratic progress of African polities. Term limits have been a key target for Africa's contemporary would-be autocrats who tried, and quite often managed, to cling on to power (Reyntjens Reference Reyntjens2020). Scholars investigated the motives that could either elicit or discourage African leaders' attempts to manipulate term limits (Posner and Young Reference Posner, Young and Cheeseman2018), the strategies adopted (Tull and Simons Reference Tull and Simons2017) and the factors affecting the probability of success (Cassani Reference Cassani2020; Dulani Reference Dulani2011; Hartmann Reference Hartmann2022; see also Baturo Reference Baturo2014; McKie Reference McKie2019).

While the politics of term limits in Africa has been at the centre of a lively scholarly debate, the consequences of the functioning of such limits on African presidents' broader behaviour, priorities and policy decisions have remained largely uncharted territory. A recent influential work on the politics of term limits across the globe (Baturo and Elgie Reference Baturo, Elgie, Baturo and Elgie2019), for example, delves into issues related to democratization but devotes only a conclusive chapter to the above issues (Suzuki Reference Suzuki, Baturo and Elgie2019). By shaping rulers' time horizons, however, term limits can significantly affect the way they act in their first and renewable term as opposed to their second and final mandate, which in turn can have major implications not only for understanding African political processes but also for development trajectories on the continent (Carbone and Pellegata Reference Carbone and Pellegata2020).

The lame-duck syndrome

Besides supposedly preventing national rulers from overstaying in office, do presidential term limits also shape African presidents' behaviours, priorities and policy decisions? Reflections about the impact of setting a maximum number of mandates for elected power-holders start from the problem John Carey pointed out with regard to lawmakers' term limits: since ‘legislators’ primary motivation is re-election … where re-election is impossible … the electoral connection is severed’ (Reference Carey1998: 3–5). The reasoning fully applies to elections for the executive too. By severing the electoral connection, term limits can make presidents' behaviour significantly different during renewable and non-renewable mandates.

A prevailing view, in particular, is that presidents who cannot be elected again are essentially weaker than presidents facing another election. The expression ‘lame duck’ is said to have been originally used for Calvin Coolidge, who was in the US White House for the better part of the 1920s. It refers to outgoing politicians. Its belittling meaning employs the image of a hesitant and uncertain conduct to convey a sense of precariousness and powerlessness. In its political substance, the expression implies a limited room for manoeuvre leaders have in their last mandate, and, relatedly, their own reduced incentives for manoeuvring.

Everybody – legislators, technocrats, lobbyists, businessmen, ordinary people – will be fully aware of the approaching expiration date, after which the outgoing president will lose whatever control he/she exerted on policies, resources, appointments and the like. Any of the chief executive's political agendas or promises would now appear somewhat less plausible, if anything, due to time constraints. This will in turn hurt and reduce political support – including legislative support – for ongoing or new initiatives, which will likely decline. The last phase of a presidency will thus be an uphill struggle, and one a departing president may not even care to embark on, or would not want to undertake with any extra burden.

Principal–agent models of politics, and particularly reputation models, have been used to formalize the argument (Canes-Wrone and Shotts Reference Canes-Wrone and Shotts2004). The strength of the incentives that elections, including re-elections, generate for politicians and their implications for policymaking are well documented (Meltzer and Richard Reference Meltzer and Richard1981), especially when democratic and non-democratic regimes are compared (Lake and Baum Reference Lake and Baum2001, among several others). Accordingly, incumbents who can run for office again are somewhat concerned with meeting voters' interests and demands, in order to cultivate consensus in view of the next election. On the contrary, non-re-electable presidents may place less value on, and thus less effort in, reputation-building, as removing the prospect of re-election implies disconnecting or softening the accountability link between elected and voters.

In a pioneering empirical work, Timothy Besley and Anne Case (Reference Besley and Case1995, Reference Besley and Case2003) show that, while US state governors tend to keep taxes and spending low during a first term, ostensibly to strengthen their reputation in view of re-election, the reduced pressures for fiscal restraint when they can no longer stand for re-election leads to tax and spending increases, especially for Democrats. Similarly, James Alt et al. (Reference Alt, Bueno de Mesquita and Rose2011) exploit the existence of different term-limit rules across US states to show that the performance of governors eligible for re-election is more in line with voters' preferences than the performance of non-re-electable incumbents.Footnote 1 Joseph M. Johnson and W. Mark Crain (Reference Johnson and Crain2004) extend this reasoning by looking at 48 democratic countries. They similarly observe that tenure limitations affect fiscal outcomes, particularly by raising fiscal volatility, spending and taxes during final mandates. In turn, Chiara Dalle Nogare and Roberto Ricciuti (Reference Dalle Nogare and Ricciuti2011) find that chief executives who are not term-limited invest more than term-limited ones in social services and welfare.

The economic policy impact of term limits has been studied with regard to local administrators too. Alain de Janvry et al. (Reference De Janvry, Finan and Sadoulet2012) apply the distinction between first-termers and second-/last-termers to assess the impact of electoral incentives on the performance of Brazilian mayors in implementing a federal programme of cash transfers aimed at reducing school dropout rates. While the programme was essentially successful across the country, municipalities governed by first-term, re-electable mayors performed significantly better than those under non-re-electable ones.

From a partly different angle, some studies posit that, as outgoing leaders approach the moment they will leave office, they begin to think of their tomorrow. In general, leaders with shorter time horizons may be more inclined to secure personal wealth by predating public and private resources (Olson Reference Olson1993). Accordingly, outgoing leaders may want to put aside material assets as well as giving specific favours that will pay off at a later stage, without having to care about the risk of being sanctioned by voters (Suzuki Reference Suzuki, Baturo and Elgie2019). Claudio Ferraz and Frederico Finan (Reference Ferraz and Finan2011), for instance, find second-termers in Brazilian municipalities to be less inclined to restrain corruption, compared to first-termers who can still run for election.

To summarize, most existing studies – a majority of them focusing on advanced democracies – associate incumbents' non-renewable terms with negative behavioural and policy outcomes. Term limits themselves, it appears, come with their own limits. Taking this further, Johnson and Crain (Reference Johnson and Crain2004: 86) question why newly democratized countries in developing areas such as Africa would want to adopt such constitutional arrangements, given their economic costs.

The good side of being lame

While much of the existing literature tends to highlight the lame-duck syndrome, we argue that term limits do not necessarily shape the behaviours, priorities and policy decisions of African leaders in a negative way; thus, they need not be counterproductive to the development of African countries.

In particular, we identify in the rule of law an aspect of governance that is both crucial for the continent's development, and one in which term limits could actually trigger virtuous rather than detrimental cycles. Admittedly, ‘rule of law’ is a contested concept (Møller and Skaaning Reference Møller and Skaaning2014), broadly referring to the supremacy of the law and the principle that no one – crucially, including the government – is legibus solutus, and requiring that laws are enforced in a transparent, independent, predictable, impartial and equal way (O'Donnell Reference O'Donnell2004). So defined, the quality of the rule of law in a country is affected by multiple factors, such as the functioning of the judiciary, the pervasiveness of corruption and the efficiency of the public administration (Coppedge et al. Reference Coppedge2021).

We focus on the functioning of the judiciary and, notably, on its independence and accessibility as well as on the extent to which the government complies with its decisions. Through a more thorough examination of the literature, we single out three main interrelated reasons why African presidents may behave in ways that could strengthen these rule-of-law dimensions during their last term in office. We refer to these mechanisms as electoral restraint, judicial insurance and legacy-making.

First, when moving from an initial renewable mandate to a conclusive one, electoral incentives essentially die out. Leaders whose survival in office depends on winning a forthcoming national vote may be prepared to go a long distance in trumping the rule of law and interfering with the judiciary to their own advantage in order to ensure the most favourable conditions for them to retain power. This may include deepening clientelist practices to widen and consolidate support (Cheeseman Reference Cheeseman2010; Ginsburg et al. Reference Ginsburg, Melton and Elkins2011; Maltz Reference Maltz2007), limiting opposition rights to skew competition in their favour (Levitsky and Way Reference Levitsky and Way2010) and repressing dissent through force (Ritter Reference Ritter2014). Many such practices are extensively documented by the literature on electoral manipulation and the so-called ‘incumbency advantage’ (Cheeseman Reference Cheeseman2010; Levitsky and Way Reference Levitsky and Way2010; Maltz Reference Maltz2007).

Presidents who know they will no longer run for office and are on their way out, on the contrary, are less likely to engage in similar behaviours. For instance, Toke Aidt and Julia Shvets (Reference Aidt and Shvets2012) find that US state lawmakers who can no longer stand for re-election prove less inclined to misuse public spending. In a rare analysis of an African country (Tanzania), moreover, Anne Kjaer notices that ‘leaders in their second term … do not have to follow appointment strategies that secure their long-term tenure of office’ (Reference Kjaer2004: 408; see also Dionne Reference Dionne2011). More generally, un-re-electable presidents will be comparatively less concerned with actively shaping the surrounding administrative and political environment. Thus, whether purposely or not, they are more likely to abstain from hindering or damaging what respect for laws and legal institutions their country can enforce.

Second, term limits may also offer reasons for outgoing incumbents who will soon return to private life to govern with moderation and to reinforce state institutions (Baturo Reference Baturo2014). Africa is a continent where risks of assassination, incarceration and exile for former presidents have traditionally been high (Goldsmith Reference Goldsmith2001). Mauritania's president, Mohamed Ould Abdel Aziz, who, despite picking his own successor, was jailed in 2021, a mere two years after leaving office, is only a recent case in point. Risks are raised by the fact that ‘open seat polls’ – that is, votes not contested by an incumbent chief executive – often result in opposition victories (Baturo Reference Baturo2022; Cheeseman Reference Cheeseman2010), and that opposition leaders are not necessarily ‘democratic’ (Wahman Reference Wahman2014).

Hence, we expect second-term presidents to be willing to make sure that the situation ‘out there’ will be reasonably safe for them, and that the next power-holders, who might be political enemies, will not have a free hand should they want to turn against their predecessors. The approaching possibility of a government turnover (and, relatedly, of a reversal of fortunes) may thus incentivize incumbents to buttress legal norms and due process, to reduce the room for future arbitrariness and ensure more benign conditions for a post-presidential future. One way incumbent rulers can make such support real is by voluntarily tying their own hands (Hirschl Reference Hirschl2004) and subjecting themselves to existing rules and institutions, thus contributing to better legitimize and strengthen them, in an effort not only to establish a pattern of behavioural conduct for their successors (Howell and Mayer Reference Howell and Mayer2005), but also to insure against hostile political rivals who might gain office.

Third, second-term presidents will be increasingly concerned with building and leaving a positive legacy. Genevieve Kehoe (Reference Kehoe2014), for instance, questions the notion that second-term presidents become unproductive policymakers. She argues that, freed from concerns about political survival, most of them actually refocus on leaving something behind when they walk out. She refers to this as a ‘terminal logic behaviour’, resulting in frequent recourse to ‘presidential proactive powers’, notably decrees that in recent US experience took the form of executive orders, proclamations and memoranda. Focusing on the last 100 days of a presidency, William Howell and Kenneth Mayer similarly point out that ‘outgoing presidents have every reason to strike out on their own’ with ‘last-minute presidential actions’ (Reference Howell and Mayer2005: 534).

The will to leave a positive legacy might lead second-term presidents towards linking their name to the adoption of specific signature initiatives or landmark policies (Kjaer and Therkildsen Reference Kjaer and Therkildsen2012), such as the building of major national infrastructures, the resolution of enduring domestic conflicts or humanitarian crises, the striking of international deals for peace or regional cooperation (Potter Reference Potter2016), and the like. Yet they might also want to leave a lasting mark by associating their name with a time of overall progress for their country. Achieving a significant international reputation may similarly motivate second-term leaders, in view of gaining post-presidency positions in multilateral organizations or private foundations, accessing perks such as consultancy jobs or foreign funding (Fruhstorfer and Hudson Reference Fruhstorfer and Hudson2022) and obtaining recognitions such as international prizes and awards.

We may thus expect them also to make an extra effort to improve governance by strengthening justice and the institutions dispensing it. During his second term, for example, Kenya's president Mwai Kibaki pushed his chief justice to reform the judiciary while increasing almost sixfold the budget for the sector: ‘I think he actually appointed me to bring about change based on the role I had played in constitution making. He wanted an outsider …. There was this thing, after my appointment: I was always introduced [by the president] to foreign dignitaries as “the man who will change the judiciary”.’Footnote 2

To summarize: we contend that Africa's second-term lame-duck presidents face three specific incentives whose interaction can lead to improvements in the rule of law. Such incentive-based mechanisms stem from: (1) the absence of direct pressures for the incumbent to manipulate the rules and interfere with the judiciary so as to ease re-election (electoral restraint); (2) a growing personal interest in strengthening the impartiality and accessibility of the justice system, which will help shelter former presidents once they become ordinary citizens and possibly political adversaries of the new rulers (judicial insurance); and (3) building one's personal reputation by leaving behind some relevant achievements (legacy-making).

The interplay of these three mechanisms leads us to expect term limits to induce positive rule-of-law developments during second-term presidencies, compared to first-term ones. More specifically, we derive the following hypotheses.

Hypotheses: Moving from first renewable terms to second final terms (and thus approaching the time to leave office), Africa's term-limited presidents become:

Hypothesis 1: more compliant with the judiciary;

Hypothesis 2: less likely to interfere with the judiciary;

Hypothesis 3: more likely to promote improvements in the accessibility of the judicial system.

No doubt, counter-arguments can be made against the reasoning behind our hypotheses. One may contend, for example, that the expectation of being succeeded by a close ally makes a more malleable rule of law an attractive scenario for post-presidential illicit gains. Yet we believe that, particularly in Africa's often politically volatile contexts, the prospect of exiting office is bound to raise significant worries about how future power-holders will actually behave, possibly driven by a concern to constrain their influential predecessors too. Even the likes of Angola's João Lourenço and Botswana's Mokgweetsi Masisi, who both supposedly stood for political continuity, clashed with those who had handed office to them. We consider this to be a pre-eminent concern for presidents approaching the end of their mandates.

Similarly, it may be claimed that assuming presidents want to build and leave a legacy is essentially based on speculation, if not wishful thinking. We contend, however, that so long as such reasoning very frequently plays a role not only in the rhetoric of presidents themselves – Namibia's Hage Geingob or Kenya's Uhuru Kenyatta are good cases in point – but, most importantly, in external observers' recurrent interpretations of their actions (Amuta Reference Amuta2021; Nossiter Reference Nossiter2020; Tantoh Reference Tantoh2019), the argument we make is well rooted in existing insights.

A reverse-causality objection may also be raised, based on the reasonable suspicion that lame ducks are themselves the product of a country's existing rule of law. This is a serious concern that we will tackle directly in our empirical analysis. For now, we simply observe that, in recent years, a number of African presidents appeared to choose to step down in poor rule-of-law performing countries such as Liberia, Sierra Leone, Mauritania, Niger and Burundi (if certainly not without controversies in the latter case): arguably, theirs was hardly a response to a well-established and respected legal framework.

Who are (and who are not) Africa's lame ducks?

We want to investigate empirically whether African presidents have a better rule-of-law performance when their mandate is no longer renewable, as opposed to when presidents face the prospect of re-election. To test our hypotheses, we collect data on 180 leaders who held office in sub-Saharan Africa's 49 countries between 1990 and 2020, using the Africa Leadership Change (ALC) dataset (Carbone and Pellegata Reference Carbone and Pellegata2020), and we single out the directly elected, term-limited presidents who completed all the legally allowed mandates and then duly stepped down.

Overall, 40 out of 49 sub-Saharan states have thus far adopted constitutional term limits for their heads of government. Most of these countries have presidential or semi-presidential governments. Botswana and South Africa – two of the six parliamentary systems in the region – are exceptions in that they apply term limits to their indirectly elected executive presidencies. The remaining countries include four non-electoral regimes (Eritrea, eSwatini, Somalia, South Sudan), three parliamentary systems (Ethiopia, Lesotho, Mauritius) and a semi-presidential system with a term-limited head of state in which the executive is controlled by the prime minister (Cape Verde), and Gambia.

Sub-Saharan term limits mostly prescribe that a president cannot serve more than two mandates overall. Botswana sets a maximum of ten years in office, in line with the parliamentary nature of its government and the five-year mandate of each legislature. The constitutions of Equatorial Guinea, Guinea-Bissau, Mozambique and São Tomé and Príncipe establish a two-term limit but explicitly envisage the possibility for a leader to run for further non-consecutive terms. Uncommon arrangements have been in place for several years in both the Seychelles (a three-term limit until 2017) and the Comoros (a four-year rotating presidency between the three main islands during 2001–2018).

Since 1990, 41 directly elected presidents from 30 sub-Saharan countries completed the legally allowed executive mandates. Some leaders reached term limits more than once – Sam Nujoma (Namibia) and Pierre Nkurunziza (Burundi), for instance, reached them twice, while Blaise Compaoré (Burkina Faso) did so three times. Overall, term limits were reached on 45 different occasions.Footnote 3

As anticipated, attempts to either remove or bypass term limits have been relatively common. Leaders stepped down in due time in 21 cases. In the remaining 24 cases, they attempted to hold on to power, in various ways (for a typology, Cassani Reference Cassani2020). A majority of would-be overstayers were successful, the most recent case being Alassane Ouattara in Côte d'Ivoire. However, the list of aspiring overstayers also includes a number of presidents who were ultimately prevented from retaining power due to a military intervention (as with Burkina Faso's Compaoré, Niger's Mamadou Tandja and most recently Guinea's Alpha Condé), civil society and parliament's resistance (Bakili Muluzi in Malawi, Frederick Chiluba in Zambia, Olusegun Obasanjo in Nigeria, Joseph Kabila in Congo-DRC) or a defeat at the polls (Senegal's Abdou Diouf and Abdoulaye Wade).

These raw data offer quite a disheartening picture of Africa's term-limit politics – more often than not, elected presidents showed little respect for the constitutions of their countries – and may lead to questioning the point of investigating the implications of term limits, that is, whether and how a formal institutional arrangement that has thus far proved highly malleable shapes the behaviour of political actors that so frequently engaged in its manipulation. Figure 1 shows, however, that there is another part of the story. By tracing the cumulative record of term limits' respect, manipulation and failed manipulation throughout the last three decades, the graph draws our attention to a point that is rarely acknowledged.

Figure 1. Term-Limit Compliance and Manipulation in Sub-Saharan Africa

Notes: Each line tracks the cumulative number of episodes of term-limit manipulation, failed manipulation and compliance, respectively. Data are from the Africa Executive Term Limits dataset (Cassani Reference Cassani2021).

Respect for term limits is becoming increasingly frequent in the continent, especially since the mid-2010s. Since 2017, for instance, presidents stepped down voluntarily in five out of eight cases in which term limits expired, and in two of the remaining three cases they were eventually forced out of office.Footnote 4 These trends suggest the time is ripe for exploring the implications of the regular functioning of these constitutional provisions – in terms of rule of law, as we do, as well as in other policy sectors.

Table 1 groups Africa's term-limited rulers according to whether they abided by constitutional norms, overstayed in office, or tried to do so but failed. ‘Law-abiders’ represent those African presidents who actually became lame ducks during their second and final terms, and whose rule-of-law performance is examined in the next section.

Table 1. African Term-Limited Presidents: Law-Abiders, Successful Overstayers and Failed Overstayers

Notes: The country and year in which term limits were either respected or challenged are in parentheses. Data are from the Africa Executive Term Limits dataset (Cassani Reference Cassani2021).

Even a cursory look at the first column of Table 1 shows that compliance with term limits covers a rather heterogeneous group of countries and political leaders. In some countries respect for term limits is becoming routine, whereas Liberia and Mauritania have only recently first confronted term-limit expiration. Among the former group, respect for term limits is consolidating in countries quite different from each other from a political viewpoint: from Ghana, Sierra Leone and São Tomé and Príncipé – three of the relatively few African democracies – to Mozambique and Tanzania – electoral autocracies that are de facto hegemonized by a long-ruling party – to Benin and Kenya – two hybrid regimes. Moreover, presidents stepped down in countries that previously experienced term-limit violations, such as Namibia, Niger and Burundi, and in unstable countries such as Mali.

Besides term-limited presidents – be they law-abiders, successful overstayers or failed ones – during the past three decades sub-Saharan Africa has been home to several other kinds of political leaders. These include ‘unlimited’ presidents, directly elected under a constitution without term limits, such as Yahya Jammeh in Gambia, but also Maaouya Ould Sid'Ahmed Taya in Mauritania, who was in power when term limits were not yet adopted, and Faure Gnassingbé in Togo, who became president when term limits were no longer in place. Moreover, there are ‘parliamentary’ leaders elected or otherwise entrusted by a country's national assembly,Footnote 5 as well as ‘unelected’ leaders. The latter encompass rulers of countries that never transitioned to full electoral politics, rulers who served before their countries introduced elections (e.g. Sani Abacha in Nigeria), as well as rulers who grabbed power by the gun in countries that had already adopted electoral politics (e.g. Azali Assoumani in the Comoros).

African presidents and the rule of law: An empirical analysis

As a reminder, we expect African presidents in their final term to become more compliant with the judiciary (H1), less likely to interfere with the judiciary (H2) and more likely to improve the accessibility of the judicial system (H3), than in their previous term. To test our hypotheses, we conduct time-series cross-sectional regressions, adopting country-years as our units of analysis (1990–2020). Hereafter, we detail how we build and employ our variables and we present the analysis and the findings.

Dependent variable: measuring the rule of law

Concerning the dependent variable, we use the Rule of Law Index from the Varieties of Democracy dataset (V-Dem, Coppedge et al. Reference Coppedge2021), and we disaggregate it to analyse separately the indicators that are most relevant to our argument and hypotheses, namely: Executive compliance with the judiciary, Judiciary independence and Access to justice.

For clarity, the first two indicators, which reflect the relationship between the executive and the judiciary, refer to courts other than the constitutional (or high) court, which helps us avoid endogeneity concerns raised by the fact that our analysis focuses on presidents respecting constitutional term limits. In turn, the third indicator measures the extent to which citizens can bring cases before the courts without risks to their personal safety, receive a fair trial and seek redress when public authorities violate their rights.

Independent variable: varieties of African leaders

We create a series of leader identifiers representing our main independent variables. The two most important leader identifiers are First term and Lame duck dummy variables that identify and distinguish African term-limited presidents who served two full terms and then stepped down with no attempt to hang on to office (i.e. presidents classified as ‘law-abiders’ in Table 1). These indicators take value 1 when these presidents are serving the first and the second/final mandates, respectively.

A third key leader identifier singles out the remaining term-limited presidents listed in Table 1, that is, Africa's Overstayers, both successful and failed ones. Three other leader identifiers distinguish Unlimited presidents, Parliamentary leaders and Unelected leaders. A final, residual (and thus more heterogeneous) category of Incomplete presidencies includes leaders who, as of 2020, never reached the end of their first term, ruled for one term only, or started but did not complete their final term. Earlier terminations are mostly explained by coups d’état (e.g. Marc Ravalomanana in Madagascar), resignations (e.g. Charles Taylor in Liberia), natural deaths (e.g. Levy Mwanawasa in Zambia) and electoral defeats (e.g. Nicéphore Soglo in Benin). This residual group also comprises interim leaders who only held the chief executive office for short periods (e.g. Joyce Banda in Malawi) and heads of transitional governments (e.g. Catherine Samba Panza in the Central African Republic).Footnote 6

While we are mainly interested in term-limited law-abiders and in seizing differences (if any) between the rule-of-law performance of Lame duck and First term presidents, we conduct the analysis within the broader comparative context of all African leaders. The exclusion of the remaining types of leaders would imply a significant loss of variance and information. For instance, it is useful to analyse Overstayers separately, as term-limit manipulation has been a relatively frequent practice south of the Sahara, and one highly consequential regarding the rule of law, typically requiring an incumbent to interfere with the judiciary to change the rules and/or to exploit legal loopholes. In turn, we do not expect Unlimited presidents to modify their behaviour depending on whether they are in their first or subsequent mandates. Moreover, we consider Parliamentary mandates to be inherently distinct from terms in presidential systems, due to the different reach and source of the executive power. Finally, sub-Saharan Unelected power-holders have historically ruled with few institutional constraints, and for this reason they are better examined separately from elected leaders.

Control variables

We consider several control variables that may influence the relationship under examination. Following Jørgen Møller and Svend-Erik Skaaning (Reference Møller and Skaaning2014), we account for the economic determinants of the rule of law. Modernization theory, for instance, links economic development with public pressure for individual rights and fair treatment by public authorities. We measure economic development both as gross domestic product (GDP) per capita levels (logged) and as GDP annual growth rates.

According to the ‘resource curse’ theory, however, an economy heavily reliant on natural resource revenues, which we measure as a percentage of GDP, short circuits the connection between citizens and the state. Moreover, we include an indicator of development aid (official development assistance, ODA, as a percentage of gross national income, GNI) to control for the emphasis that international cooperation programmes place on the rule of law (Carothers Reference Carothers1998). Economic data are from the World Bank's World Development Indicators.

To reduce the risk of omitting factors influencing both the dependent and the main independent variables, we also consider several political features which may affect both a country's rule-of-law performance and the respect of term limits, and thus also determine the lame-duck status of an African leader. First, we use the V-Dem Polyarchy Index, as countries scoring high in electoral democracy tend also to have a stronger rule of law (Maravall and Przeworski Reference Maravall and Przeworski2003) and to respect term limits (Reyntjens Reference Reyntjens2020). Hegemonic parties too, however, might be interested in preserving term limits as an internal succession mechanism (Ezrow Reference Ezrow, Baturo and Elgie2019). Hence, we measure the consecutive years the same party has remained in power and check whether this interferes with the relationships we want to highlight.

Finally, we control for executive corruption using V-Dem data – as corrupted incumbents may either try to escape term limits (Baturo Reference Baturo2014), pack the judiciary with loyalists to protect themselves from future investigations, or both – and we create three dichotomous and time-invariant indicators signalling former single-party regimes (Hartmann Reference Hartmann2022), former British colonies and countries whose constitutions envisage the possibility of running for additional non-consecutive terms.

Analysis and findings

As a starting point, since this is the first comparative investigation into the rule-of-law implications of term limits south of the Sahara, we want to gain a sense of the broad picture. Accordingly, Figure 2 uses the comprehensive Rule of Law Index to summarize differences in the average rule-of-law performance of different types of African rulers.

Figure 2. African Political Leaders and the Rule of Law

Notes: The vertical bars represent the average rule-of-law performance of different types of African political leaders. Rule-of-law performance is estimated using the V-Dem Rule of Law Index, an interval scale which ranges from 0 to 1. We omit from the analysis the residual Incomplete leader category.

The graph vividly shows a major rule-of-law divide between a group of unelected, unlimited and overstaying presidents and another group of term-limited presidents and parliamentary prime ministers. While the latter outperform any other types of leaders, Figure 2 confirms that moving from the first renewable term to the second and final term corresponds, on average, to an improvement in terms of rule of law. Prima facie, African presidents display a better rule-of-law performance when they become lame ducks, and a positive effect of term limits on the rule of law does seem to exist.

A closer look at the data reveals that second-term improvements were recorded under presidencies as diverse (in terms of level of democracy, colonial and authoritarian legacies, leader's background, and level of development) as those of, among others, Benin's Thomas Boni Yayi, Mozambique's Joachim Chissano, Kenya's Mway Kibaki, Sierra Leone's Ernest Bai Koroma and Ghana's Jerry Rawlings. Unsurprisingly, however, we also found deviant cases that do not conform to the abovementioned pattern, that is, countries where the rule of law actually worsened during a president's second term – such as Mauritania under Mohamed Ould Abdel Aziz and Niger under Mahamadou Issoufou – or else remained persistently low, as with Pierre Nkurunziza in Burundi.

As a second step – and a more cogent test – we conduct time-series cross-sectional regression to determine whether the term-limit effect previously detected holds true even when a larger set of factors that are likely to influence a country's rule of law are considered. In this case, we focus on the three more specific Executive compliance with the judiciary, Judiciary independence and Access to justice dependent variables. For each indicator, we run a series of regression models. In all the analyses, we compute robust standard errors and we include independent variables that are one-year lagged with respect to the dependent variable, as well as year fixed effects.

We start from a simple model testing only the leader identifiers, namely, Lame duck, Overstayer, Unlimited, Parliamentary, Unelected, plus the residual Incomplete. First term leaders represent the reference category omitted from the regression model. Subsequently, we add stepwise economic, political and time-invariant control variables. Next, we drop from the model specification the time-invariant variables and we run other models adding alternatively country and leader fixed effects to control for any country-specific and leader-specific characteristics that may influence the relationship under examination, respectively.Footnote 7

Finally, we conduct another robustness test to address endogeneity concerns. To be sure, our research design envisages several strategies to account for this potential bias. On one hand, our Lame duck and First term identifiers only apply to African term-limited presidents that served two full terms and no more (De Janvry et al. Reference De Janvry, Finan and Sadoulet2012), while also considering other types of political leaders separately (including overstaying presidents). On the other hand, as discussed, control variables (as well as leader fixed effects) have been selected to reduce the risk of omitting from the regression analysis key variables that may determine both a country's rule-of-law performance and African presidents' propensity to respect term limits and thus to become lame ducks.

As a further strategy, we use instrumental variables and a two-stage least squares estimator to reassess the term-limit effect. Valid instruments must be relevant – that is, good predictors of the allegedly endogenous independent variable (X) – and they must influence the dependent variable (Y) only through their effect on X (net of any controls).

To select our instruments, we mainly rely on the ‘incumbency advantage’ theory, which has a relatively strong explanatory power in Africa's electoral politics (Cheeseman Reference Cheeseman2010). In short, the theory suggests that sitting presidents tend to be stronger candidates at the polls and that it is easier to be confirmed in office than to be elected for the first time. Building on this idea, we use the winner's vote share and the margin of majority relative to the second-ranked candidate in first-round presidential elections to predict if African term-limited presidents are serving their first or second mandate. Exploring the data confirms that these variables are relatively good predictors of lame-duck status. At the same time, we do not expect electoral performance to directly influence the quality of the rule of law in the subsequent years.Footnote 8 As a further instrument we use a president's age. Given the use of election data, estimating the instrumental variable models de facto requires excluding Unelected rulers from the analysis.

Tables 2–4 present the findings. Each table reports the same above-described battery of tests for a different rule-of-law indicator – Executive compliance with judiciary, Judiciary independence, Access to justice, respectively. In line with our argument and expectations, the overall evidence shows that respect for the rule of law tends to be higher during a term-limited president's second mandate, compared to first mandates. More specifically, the government is more compliant with the judiciary's decisions (Table 2 – H1), the latter acts more independently (Table 3 – H2) and citizens enjoy better access to justice (Table 4 – H3) during last non-renewable terms as opposed to first terms.

Table 2. African Leaders and Executive Compliance with Judiciary (H1)

Notes: *** p < 0.01, ** p < 0.05, * p < 0.10. All predictors lagged one year. Robust standard errors clustered by country in parentheses. Model 7 is based on instrumental variable regression (two-stage least square estimator). The dependent variable is measured using the model estimates version of the V-Dem indicator Compliance with judiciary, as suggested in the V-Dem Codebook.

Table 3. African Leaders and Judiciary Independence (H2)

Notes: *** p < 0.01, ** p < 0.05, * p < 0.10. All predictors lagged one year. Robust standard errors clustered by country in parentheses. Model 7 is based on instrumental variable regression (two-stage least square estimator). The dependent variable is measured using the model estimates version of the V-Dem indicator Judiciary Independence, as suggested in the V-Dem Codebook.

Table 4. African Leaders and Access to Justice (H3)

Notes: *** p < 0.01, ** p < 0.05, * p < 0.10. All predictors lagged one year. Robust standard errors clustered by country in parentheses. Model 7 is based on instrumental variable regression (two-stage least square estimator). The dependent variable is measured using the V-Dem index Access to Justice, which ranges from 0 to 1.

The results appear statistically significant at the 95% confidence level or higher, and robust to the several replication tests that we run and the several strategies we used to address endogeneity concerns. In only two cases, we obtained a weaker statistical significance (90%), namely, Model 6 in Table 3 and Model 1 in Table 4.

We did not find systematic and sufficiently strong (from a statistical viewpoint) evidence regarding the other categories of leader, with the exception of African overstayers, whose rule-of-law performance is unsurprisingly negative, especially regarding compliance with judiciary and judiciary independence. In turn, the regression analysis does not confirm the apparently superior rule-of-law performance of parliamentary prime ministers suggested by Figure 2. As for our control variables, we find democracy and, to a weaker degree, one-party legacies and a past as British colony to have positive effects. Moreover, both the level and the pace of economic development show some evidence of a positive association. Conversely, corruption negatively influences all the examined indicators.

Conclusion

In no world region are lame ducks a native species. Africa was no exception, as post-independent politics long did without any precise timeframe for leaders to rotate in office. Things changed in the 1990s with the decision to couple the return to multipartyism with the introduction of directly elected, time-bound presidential tenures. From then on, an increasing number of sub-Saharan countries experienced incumbent presidents holding office for second mandates due to be their last term.

Non-re-electability has potential implications that go beyond the original goal of avoiding immovable leaders and favouring executive rotation. It can alter some key underlying political dynamics, shape the behaviour of leaders (as well as of other players) and generate distinctive development outcomes. Despite the vast attention gained by executive term limits in the sub-Saharan region over recent years, and the existence of an international literature pointing to the specificity of non-renewable spells in office, whether lame-duck presidencies have something special in Africa too had never been explored.

In this article, we thus ventured into this new research avenue by examining the broader impact on the rule of law of constitutional provisions that only allow African presidents two mandates in office. Our evidence shows that second terms are indeed different from first terms when we look at progress made along several indicators regarding the judiciary, in particular.

The results of this first empirical investigation of the performance of Africa's second-term lame-duck presidents represent an innovative contribution. Most importantly, our research challenges the view that setting limits to candidates' re-electability risks breaking the electoral connection and thus impeding accountability, ultimately generating disappointing government performances. In the rule-of-law field, African presidents on their way out actually appear to be essentially better than presidents who are to run for office again.

At the same time, with regard to the mechanisms we theorized, one should acknowledge that, while legacy-making dynamics may conceivably feature in any political system, the electoral restraint and judicial insurance incentives are more likely to emerge where state institutions are not fully consolidated – as is the case in much of Africa. This would admittedly limit the generalizability of our empirical results, as they might likely apply to other developing areas, but less so to the more fully institutionalized polities of advanced economies.

Our investigation of the policy and development implications of Africa's presidential term limits represents a starting point, as many related questions still lie ahead. Is Africa entirely immune from the lame-duck syndrome previously detected in other world regions? Or do second terms prove detrimental in this continent too, when we shift attention to other policy areas? Are African overstayers who justified manipulation of term limits by claiming that development demands continuity ultimately right? And, when the exercise of power remains authoritarian but embedded in institutions rather than fully personalized (Meng Reference Meng2020), how does a maximum number of mandates interact with other types of constraints in shaping behaviours and policies? Further research will help expand our understanding of these and related issues by examining how tenure restrictions affect different social, economic and governance outcomes in the region.

Footnotes

1 Smart and Sturm (Reference Smart and Sturm2013) offer an alternative theoretical argument according to which a two-term limit system is nonetheless preferable to a single- or no term limit system, as the former triggers a combination of selection and truthfulness effects.

2 Willy Mutunga, former chief justice of Kenya (author interview, 22 October 2019). Cf. Gainer Reference Gainer2016.

3 Other presidents left office by resigning before the expected end of their mandates, including Seychelles' France-Albert René and James Michel, and South Africa's Thabo Mbeki and Jacob Zuma.

4 It is also true that during the same period the likes of Paul Biya, Denis Sassou-Nguesso, Ismail Omar Guelleh and Yoweri Museveni started their fourth and then fifth consecutive terms, having scrapped term limits several years ago already.

5 Most of these leaders hold the title of prime minister, but the category also comprehends Botswana and South Africa's term-limited indirectly elected executive presidents.

6 The Incomplete residual category also includes presidents who ruled in Comoros between 2001 and 2018. These leaders only served one term each, due to the rotating presidency principle between the three main islands.

7 Concerning individual fixed effects, see for instance Ferraz and Finan (Reference Ferraz and Finan2011), Aidt and Shvets (Reference Aidt and Shvets2012), De Janvry et al. (Reference De Janvry, Finan and Sadoulet2012), Geys and Mause (Reference Geys and Mause2016), Dalle Nogare and Kauder (Reference Dalle Nogare and Kauder2017).

8 Correlation between our measures of electoral performance and the selected rule of law indicators in subsequent years (t + 1, t + 2, etc.) is always below −0.12 and progressively weaker.

References

Aidt, TS and Shvets, J (2012) Distributive Politics and Electoral Incentives: Evidence from Seven US State Legislatures. American Economic Journal: Economic Policy 4(3), 129. https://doi.org/10.1257/pol.4.3.1.Google Scholar
Alt, J, Bueno de Mesquita, E and Rose, S (2011) Disentangling Accountability and Competence in Elections: Evidence from U.S. Term Limits. Journal of Politics 73(1), 171186. https://doi.org/10.1017/S0022381610000940.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Amuta, C (2021) Mr. President, It's the Legacy Moment. This Day, 24 January, Lagos.Google Scholar
Baturo, A (2014) Democracy, Dictatorship, and Term Limits. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Baturo, A (2022) When Incumbents Do Not Run: Presidential Succession and Democratization. Democratization 29(1), 7492. https://doi.org/10.1080/13510347.2021.1957837.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Baturo, A and Elgie, R (2019) Presidential Term Limits. In Baturo, A and Elgie, R (eds), The Politics of Presidential Term Limits. Oxford: Oxford University Press, pp. 117.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Besley, T and Case, A (1995) Does Electoral Accountability Affect Economic Policy Choices? Evidence from Gubernatorial Term Limits. Quarterly Journal of Economics 110(3), 760797. https://doi.org/10.2307/2946699.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Besley, T and Case, A (2003) Political Institutions and Policy Choices: Evidence from the United States. Journal of Economic Literature 41(1), 773. https://doi.org/10.1257/002205103321544693.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bratton, M (2004) The ‘Alternation Effect’ in Africa. Journal of Democracy 15(4), 147158. https://doi.org/10.1353/jod.2004.0059.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Canes-Wrone, B and Shotts, KW (2004) The Conditional Nature of Presidential Responsiveness to Public Opinion. American Journal of Political Science 48(4), 690706. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.0092-5853.2004.00096.x.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Carbone, G and Pellegata, A (2020) Political Leadership in Africa: Leaders and Development South of the Sahara. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Carey, JM (1998) Term Limits and Legislative Representation. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Carothers, T (1998) The Rule of Law Revival. Foreign Affairs 77, 95106. https://doi.org/10.2307/20048791.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cassani, A (2020) Autocratisation by Term Limits Manipulation in Sub-Saharan Africa. Africa Spectrum 55(3), 228250. https://doi.org/10.1177/0002039720964218.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cassani, A (2021) Law-Abiders, Lame Ducks, and Over-Stayers: The Africa Executive Term Limits (AETL) Dataset. European Political Science 20(3), 543555. https://doi.org/10.1057/s41304-020-00291-w.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cheeseman, N (2010) African Elections as Vehicles for Change. Journal of Democracy 21(4), 139153. https://doi.org/10.1353/jod.2010.0019.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Coppedge, M et al. (2021) V-Dem Codebook v11.1. Varieties of Democracy (V-Dem) Project. https://doi.org/10.23696/vdemds21.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Corrales, J and Penfold, M (2014) Manipulating Term Limits in Latin America. Journal of Democracy 25(4), 157168. https://doi.org/10.1353/jod.2014.0066.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dalle Nogare, C and Kauder, B (2017) Term Limits for Mayors and Intergovernmental Grants: Evidence from Italian Cities. Regional Science and Urban Economics 64, 111. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.regsciurbeco.2017.01.004.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dalle Nogare, C and Ricciuti, R (2011) Do Term Limits Affect Fiscal Policy Choices? European Journal of Political Economy 27(4), 681692. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.ejpoleco.2011.06.006.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
De Janvry, A, Finan, F and Sadoulet, E (2012) Local Electoral Incentives and Decentralized Program Performance. Review of Economics and Statistics 94(3), 672685. https://doi.org/10.1162/REST_a_00182.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
De Palma, A (1994) Do Term Limits Work? Ask Mexico. New York Times, 4 December.Google Scholar
Dionne, K (2011) The Role of Executive Time Horizons in State Response to AIDS in Africa. Comparative Political Studies 44(1), 5577. https://doi.org/10.1177/0010414010381074.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dulani, B (2011) Personal Rule and Presidential Term Limits in Africa. PhD dissertation, Michigan State University.Google Scholar
Dulani, B (2015) African Publics Strongly Support Term Limits, Resist Leaders’ Efforts to Extend Their Tenure. Afrobarometer Dispatch 30, 112.Google Scholar
Ezrow, N (2019) Term Limits and Succession in Dictatorships. In Baturo, A and Elgie, R (eds), The Politics of Presidential Term Limits. Oxford: Oxford University Press, pp. 269287.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ferraz, C and Finan, F (2011) Electoral Accountability and Corruption: Evidence from the Audits of Local Governments. American Economic Review 101, 12741311. https://doi.org/10.1257/aer.101.4.1274.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fruhstorfer, A and Hudson, A (2022) Costs and Benefits of Accepting Presidential Term Limits: ‘Should I Stay or Should I Go?’. Democratization 29(1), 93112. https://doi.org/10.1080/13510347.2021.1960314.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gainer, M (2016) How Kenya Cleaned Up Its Courts. Foreign Policy (July).Google Scholar
Geys, B and Mause, K (2016) The Limits of Electoral Control: Evidence from Last-Term Politicians. Legislative Studies Quarterly 41(4), 873898. http://dx.doi.org/10.1111/lsq.2016.41.issue-4.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ginsburg, T, Melton, J and Elkins, Z (2011) On the Evasion of Executive Term Limits. William and Mary Law Review 52(6), 18071872.Google Scholar
Goldsmith, A (2001) Risk, Rule and Reason: Leadership in Africa. Public Administration and Development 21(2), 7787. https://doi.org/10.1002/pad.157.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Grauvogel, J and Heyl, C (2020) The Study of Term Limits in Sub-Saharan Africa: Lessons on Democratisation and Autocratisation. Africa Spectrum 55(3), 215227. https://doi.org/10.1177/0002039720987696.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hartmann, C (2022) Authoritarian Origins of Term Limit Trajectories in Africa. Democratization 29(1), 5773. https://doi.org/10.1080/13510347.2021.1992387.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Heyl, C and Llanos, M (2022) Contested, Violated but Persistent: Presidential Term Limits in Latin America and Sub-Saharan Africa. Democratization 29(1), 117. https://doi.org/10.1080/13510347.2021.1997991.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hirschl, R (2004) The Political Origins of the New Constitutionalism. Indiana Journal of Global Legal Studies 11(1), 71108.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Howard, M and Roessler, P (2006) Liberalizing Electoral Outcomes in Competitive Authoritarian Regimes. American Journal of Political Science 50(2), 365381. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1540-5907.2006.00189.x.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Howell, WG and Mayer, KR (2005) The Last One Hundred Days. Presidential Studies Quarterly 35(3), 533553. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1741-5705.2005.00263.x.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Huntington, S (1991) The Third Wave: Democratization in the Late Twentieth Century. Norman: University of Oklahoma Press.Google Scholar
Jackson, R and Rosberg, C (1982) Personal Rule in Black Africa: Prince, Autocrat, Prophet, Tyrant. Berkeley: University of California Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Johnson, J and Crain, M (2004) Effects of Term Limits on Fiscal Performance: Evidence from Democratic Nations. Public Choice 119(1/2), 7390. https://doi.org/10.1023/B:PUCH.0000024183.74743.13.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kehoe, G (2014) Presidents and Terminal Logic Behavior: Term Limits and Executive Action in the United States, Brazil, and Argentina. College Station, TX: A&M University Press.Google Scholar
Kjaer, AM (2004) Old Brooms Can Sweep Too! An Overview of Rulers and Public Sector Reforms in Uganda, Tanzania and Kenya. Journal of Modern African Studies 42(3), 389413. https://doi.org/10.1017/S0022278X04000242.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kjaer, AM and Therkildsen, O (2012) Elections and Landmark Policies in Tanzania and Uganda. Democratization 20(4), 592614. https://doi.org/10.1080/13510347.2012.659019.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lake, D and Baum, M (2001) The Invisible Hand of Democracy: Political Control and the Provision of Public Services. Comparative Political Studies 34(6), 587621. https://doi.org/10.1177/0010414001034006001.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Levitsky, S and Way, L (2010) Competitive Authoritarianism: Hybrid Regimes after the Cold War. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Maboudi, T, Nadi, G and Eisenstadt, T (2021) Render Unto Caesar Just a Little Bit Longer: The Relationship between Constitutional Reforms and Executive Survival. Government and Opposition: An International Journal of Comparative Politics, published online, November, 1–22, https://doi.org/10.1017/gov.2021.53.Google Scholar
Maltz, G (2007) The Case for Presidential Term Limits. Journal of Democracy 18(1), 128142. https://doi.org/10.1353/jod.2007.0010.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Maravall, J and Przeworski, A (eds) (2003) Democracy and the Rule of Law. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
McKie, K (2017) The Politics of Institutional Choice across Sub-Saharan Africa: Presidential Term Limits. Studies in Comparative International Development 52(4), 436456. https://doi.org/10.1007/s12116-017-9252-z.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
McKie, K (2019) Presidential Term Limit Contravention: Abolish, Extend, Fail, or Respect? Comparative Political Studies 52(10), 15001534. https://doi.org/10.1177/0010414019830737.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
McKie, K and Carlson, E (2022) Do Contravention Attempts Affect Public Support for Presidential Term Limits? Evidence from Sub-Saharan Africa. Democratization 29(1), 133153. https://doi.org/10.1080/13510347.2021.1980874.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Meltzer, A and Richard, S (1981) A Rational Theory of the Size of Government. Journal of Political Economy 89(5), 914927. https://doi.org/10.1086/261013.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Meng, A (2020) Constraining Dictatorship: From Personalized Rule to Institutionalized Regimes. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Moehler, D and Lindberg, S (2009) Narrowing the Legitimacy Gap: Turnovers as a Cause of Democratic Consolidation. Journal of Politics 71(4), 14481466. https://doi.org/10.1017/S0022381609990120.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Møller, J and Skaaning, SE (2014) The Rule of Law: Definitions, Measures, Patterns and Causes. Houndmills: Palgrave Macmillan.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Nossiter, A (2020) Jerry Rawlings, from Coup-Plotter to Ghanaian Statesman, Dies at 73. New York Times, 12 November.Google Scholar
O'Donnell, G (2004) The Quality of Democracy: Why the Rule of Law Matters. Journal of Democracy 15(4), 3246. https://doi.org/10.1353/jod.2004.0076.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Olson, M (1993) Dictatorship, Democracy, and Development. American Political Science Review 87(3), 567576. https://doi.org/10.2307/2938736.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Posner, D and Young, D (2018) Term Limits: Leadership, Political Competition, and the Transfer of Power. In Cheeseman, N (ed.), Institutions and Democracy in Africa. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, pp. 260277.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Potter, P (2016) Lame-Duck Foreign Policy. Presidential Studies Quarterly 46(4), 849867. https://doi.org/10.1111/psq.12322.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Reyntjens, F (2020) Respecting and Circumventing Presidential Term Limits in Sub-Saharan Africa: A Comparative Survey. African Affairs 119(475), 275295. https://doi.org/10.1093/afraf/adz029.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ritter, EH (2014) Policy Disputes, Political Survival, and the Onset and Severity of State Repression. Journal of Conflict Resolution 58(1), 143168. https://doi.org/10.1177/0022002712468724.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Smart, M and Sturm, D (2013) Term Limits and Electoral Accountability. Journal of Public Economics 107, 93102. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jpubeco.2013.08.011.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Suzuki, A (2019) Effects of Presidential Term Limits. In Baturo, A and Elgie, R (eds), The Politics of Presidential Term Limits. Oxford: Oxford University Press, pp. 585605.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Tantoh, M (2019) Africa: Niger's President Will Make History at the End of His Term. AllAfrica, 10 October.Google Scholar
Tull, D and Simons, C (2017) The Institutionalisation of Power Revisited: Presidential Term Limits in Africa. Africa Spectrum 52(2), 79102. https://doi.org/10.1177/000203971705200204.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Venice Commission (2018) Report on Term Limits. Adopted by the Venice Commission at its 114th Plenary Session, Venice, 16–17 March.Google Scholar
Versteeg, M et al. (2020) The Law and Politics of Presidential Term Limit Evasion. Columbia Law Review 120(1), 173248.Google Scholar
Wahman, M (2014) Democratization and Electoral Turnover in Sub-Saharan Africa and Beyond. Democratization 21(2), 220243. https://doi.org/10.1080/13510347.2012.732572.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Figure 0

Figure 1. Term-Limit Compliance and Manipulation in Sub-Saharan AfricaNotes: Each line tracks the cumulative number of episodes of term-limit manipulation, failed manipulation and compliance, respectively. Data are from the Africa Executive Term Limits dataset (Cassani 2021).

Figure 1

Table 1. African Term-Limited Presidents: Law-Abiders, Successful Overstayers and Failed Overstayers

Figure 2

Figure 2. African Political Leaders and the Rule of LawNotes: The vertical bars represent the average rule-of-law performance of different types of African political leaders. Rule-of-law performance is estimated using the V-Dem Rule of Law Index, an interval scale which ranges from 0 to 1. We omit from the analysis the residual Incomplete leader category.

Figure 3

Table 2. African Leaders and Executive Compliance with Judiciary (H1)

Figure 4

Table 3. African Leaders and Judiciary Independence (H2)

Figure 5

Table 4. African Leaders and Access to Justice (H3)