Hostname: page-component-586b7cd67f-dlnhk Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-11-23T15:27:07.148Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Debating International Keynesianism: The Sense of the Acceptable and the Neoliberal Turn at the OECD

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  14 June 2019

Rights & Permissions [Opens in a new window]

Abstract

Published in 1977 by the OECD in a context of widespread stagflation, the McCracken report has become emblematic of the “neoliberal turn” in international economic cooperation. This study undermines this shared teleological interpretation by revisiting the sense of what was acceptable among the actors mobilized in its writing, and the structural uncertainty into which they were plunged by their attempt to anticipate the economic and political future. Rather than an uncontested victory of neoliberalism, the sociogenetics of this bureaucratic text uncover the coping strategies of the “international Keynesianism” inherited from Bretton Woods and the plausibility structures of this space situated at the confluence of the political, bureaucratic, and academic fields. The dynamic of production is analyzed as a situational logic through which the Secretariat of the OECD was exposed to polymorphic external rationales and resources that collided with and were measured against one another. The report form allowed for this confrontation of informational, bureaucratic, and political capital, in a way objectifying their differential value or exchange rate for the participants. The socially structured expectations of what was feasible, costly, or risky are traced throughout the collective process of composition based on four key moments: the commissioning of the report, the establishment of its framework, the constitution of the group, and the crystallization of the report. The article thus proposes another way of investigating the nature of “turns.”

Type
Keynesianism
Copyright
© Éditions EHESS 2019 

The list of reports that punctuate the history of national or international public action is probably infinite. In this ocean float a few totems—including the Beveridge, Ohlin, Khrushchev, Radcliffe, Rueff-Armand, Meadows, Delors, Maekawa, and Stiglitz reports. Each in its own way, these reports marked their era by proposing a diagnosis and drawing up lines of action. The McCracken report, which is the focus of this article, is often seen as the symptom, the telltale sign, or the trigger of the neoliberal turn at the Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development (OECD) and, by extension, in Western economic cooperation.Footnote 1 Published in 1977, in a situation of stagflation (characterized by sluggish growth and high inflation) perceived as unprecedented and disconcerting in its magnitude, the McCracken report is generally considered a testament to the emergence of a new economic orthodoxy that marked the end or the weakening of the Bretton Woods regime. It is also seen as prefiguring the “Great Moderation”Footnote 2 that began in the mid-1980s, as well as certain elements of what came to be termed, in the 1990s, the “Washington Consensus.”Footnote 3 This interpretative reflex, whose methodological stakes transcend the neoliberal turn examined here, must be considered more closely before proposing a sociogenetic alternative capable of grasping the social dynamics—political, academic, and bureaucratic—that molded both the writing of the report and this reputedly critical economic and political juncture.

Backed by “neo-orthodox economics,” the “disciplinary state” would drive away the welfare state and its policies of active demand-side management by making control of inflation the primary macroeconomic objective, at the cost of high and persistent levels of unemployment.Footnote 4 This was the analysis proposed in 1978 by Robert Keohane, a rising star within the discipline of international relations in the United States, in an exceptionally long review article that has since fixed academic readings of the report in terms of the “neoliberal turn.”Footnote 5 Yet these interpretations rarely specify what they subsume under the term “neoliberal.” The British political scientist Stephen Gill at least has the merit of pointing out that this report—like another published in 1979 by the Trilateral CommissionFootnote 6—unambiguously advocated:

the need for tight control of national money supplies, cuts or restraint in government expenditures, and attempts to stop the rise in real wages. This would serve to reverse the downward trend in profits (and upward trend in real wages) which had taken place between 1968 and 1974, as well as to attack inflation. … The report also acknowledged that the costs of such a set of policies would be much higher, potentially permanent, levels of unemployment, and therefore the major capitalist states (mainly those in Europe) would have to jettison commitment to one of the central pillars of the postwar welfarist consensus. The changes involved an attack on wage indexation, and a general offensive designed to “liberalise” labour markets.Footnote 7

Quintessential in its neoliberal orthodoxy, the report thus took part in the “war against inflation” of the 1970s and testified to a durable shift in perceptions and methods at the OECD.

The participation of the chair of the expert group, Paul Winston McCracken, in the Mont Pelerin Society,Footnote 8 and his role as adviser to President Ronald Reagan a few years later,Footnote 9 have further reinforced this connection with neoliberalism. The McCracken report is overwhelmingly read in a particular way: certain aspects are selected and linked to the neoliberal victory, while others, nonetheless significant, are consistently excluded because they fit poorly with this scenario. For example, an important representative of the Chicago school—with “New Classical” tendencies—saw the report as a neo-Keynesian threat to his doctrine,Footnote 10 while the OECD was denounced by monetarists as a hotbed of Keynesianists.Footnote 11 Others, at the opposite end of the theoretical and political spectrum, considered the report as a doomed Keynesian proclamation or a failure of application, similar to the Humphrey-Hawkins Full Employment Act voted by the United States Congress in 1978.Footnote 12 Moreover, some sections of the report reaffirm the validity of conventional economic analysis,Footnote 13 or the possibility of Keynesian economic cooperation in terms of equilibrating the balance of payments and reviving global demand, both incompatible with the supply-side strategies of the 1980s.Footnote 14

From the moment of its publication, the interpretation of the report was in reality plurivocal, the picture less black and white, the “turn” more sinuous.Footnote 15 The subsequent success of neoliberalism has “unilateralized” our understanding of the document and the historical moment in which it was inscribed and which it contributes to depicting. This success also distracts us from the uncertainty, or even disarray, which characterized the situation for certain actors, as well as the continuities, compromises, and strategic retreats, the game of wait-and-see and positions that were more strident but which ultimately lost out. Integrating these into our analysis makes the report appear as a suspended moment in time, an instant when history seemed to hesitate in a longer chronology of the turn. But these remarks imply asking a question that has rarely preoccupied disciples of the “turn”: How did it take place? How did an intergovernmental organization, founded on the professed neutrality of its economic expertise—and whose most typical bureaucratic expression lay in the reports that it published on an almost daily basisFootnote 16—effect a political and economic transformation of such magnitude in the space of one such report? The rare attempts to answer this question make it possible to identify other impasses and issues at stake in the investigation.

Some, in the style of the (neo)realist school of international relations, consider that the report incontestably affirmed both the dominance of the United States within the OECD and, at the same time, the congenital heteronomy of this type of intergovernmental organization.Footnote 17 Specifying none of the concrete forms taken by this domination, this first explanation pays little heed to the attribution of the label “neoliberal” to the administration of Jimmy Carter, elected more than six months before the publication of the report. This administration had no declared monetarist in its ranks, let alone any “Reaganomist” or “supply-sider.” From its inauguration until 1979, it defended an international Keynesian approach, known as the “locomotive” strategy; during the 1976 presidential campaign, Senator Carter had denounced the Gerald Ford administration’s use of “the evil of unemployment to fight inflation.”Footnote 18 If the report marks the neoliberal turn and the dominance of the United States, this possible discrepancy with the new administration—and, by the same token, the relative independence of the OECD—deserves attention.

The second explanation, of a cognitivist type, parallels the official history and considers that “little by little, with frequent reversals and back-sliding, [the economists at the OECD] came to the conclusion that their Keynesian presuppositions were, if not wrong, inappropriate to a new economic environment.”Footnote 19 In this account, the accumulation of anomalies and empirical refutations of the Keynesian paradigm gradually brought it into doubt and eventually threw it off course; it would succumb to the test of reality. This intellectualist explanation validates the iconoclastic claim of monetarism against Keynesianism during this period. At the same time, it flows into the self-presentation strategy of an “expert” organization like the OECD, much more concerned than a standard bureaucracy with laying claim to a register of scientific legitimacy in which rational argument, the validation of hypotheses, and the rules of evidence were supposed to ensure consensus. This explanation converges with currents of research that seek to rehabilitate the role of ideas and learning in the analysis of public action, but which pay little or no attention to the social bases that constitute this “test of reality” or “disavowal by the facts.”Footnote 20 “Economic reality” and its causalities need interpreters.

The third, neo-Marxist explanation points to the new global alliance between governments and the business community, and takes the McCracken report as its resounding expression. This reconfiguration is said to have emerged to the detriment of the previous social-democratic alliance (incorporating New Deal industrialists in the United States), its foundations laid “by a collective effort of ideological revision undertaken through various unofficial agencies—the Trilateral Commission, the Bilderberg conferences, the Club of Rome, and other less prestigious forums—and then endorsed through more official consensus-making agencies like the OECD.”Footnote 21 This intentionalist and “sequentialist” explanation lacks empirical support concerning the action and articulation of the different agencies, whether official or not; it leaves little room for contingency, the unexpected effects of action, and the convergence of specific and contradictory interests.

What these explanations have in common is that they remain entirely subordinated to the “report” as a form, construing the institution or group as a homogeneous author and the document as a finished product, an opus operatum delivered over to interpretation.Footnote 22 Anything that relates to the “work in progress,” or to a modus operandi that stretched over three years, is left in the shadows: almost nothing has been written about who commissioned the report, the heterogeneous composition of the expert group, the role of the OECD Secretariat, the part played by government delegates and journalists, and so on.Footnote 23 Nor is much known about its most striking organizational properties. Internally designated as a “high-level” report, it engaged actors with a high political, bureaucratic, or academic capital and sought to mark an event on political and journalistic agendas. Also designated as a “horizontal” report, it strove for a transversal or intersectoral approach to the problems in question (unemployment, inflation, growth) by making usually compartmentalized sectors of the OECD work together.

To examine the dynamics of its production is to take administrative prose seriously in terms of the “reality of intellectual practices, forms of thought and ordering of the world, [and] bureaucratic routines”Footnote 24 of which it is composed. What is more, this method approaches the report as a social form linking or excluding a whole series of actors and universes in its fabrication, and through which international economic cooperation is deployed.Footnote 25 To what extent does this sociogenetic approach allow us to discuss concrete evidence—including what happened during the course of events—regarding these theses on the breakdown of the former social-democratic consensus, the weaknesses of Keynesianism, or US hegemony? How far does it enable us to exit the binary schema postulated by the notion of a turn, with the victory of one camp over another? Is one of the characteristics of the situation studied here not also to produce “labeling” struggles that polarize actors into homogeneous camps designated by “-isms” which are supposed to function as markers of shared belief (monetarism, Keynesianism, socialism, neoliberalism)?Footnote 26

This report, like many others, is not only a document to be read; it is a theater of political, bureaucratic, and academic operations that are there to be reconstructed. In its aims, this present article is closer to a vivisection than an autopsy. It puts the causal imagery of the turn on standby, controls its effects on the investigation, and is attentive to one of the key characteristics of the situation: the uncertainty about the economic future, coupled with the uncertainty felt by certain actors as to the analytical and prescriptive Keynesian frame and its pliability, as well as the uncertainty regarding the very role of international economic organizations. The usual anticipatory references are jammed, the political, economic, and social future is less easily decipherable, the previous operational solutions are questioned, and forms of de-objectification of the established are engaged.

Unaware of the the final version of the report, which the participants were yet to produce, and of the neoliberal outcome of events, which some sought to combat, this situation of structural uncertainty contrasts with the retrospective certainty of the neoliberal turn. The investigative approach adopted here uses a non-teleological perspective to grasp in action the “sense of the acceptable”—both individual and collective—of the actors involved in the collective writing of the report, a sense that, “by encouraging one to take account of the probable value of discourse during the process of production, determines corrections and all forms of self-censorship—the concessions one makes to a social world by accepting to make oneself acceptable in it.”Footnote 27 Tracing the sociogenetics of the report captures the interpretative and prescriptive struggles and makeshift solutions involved in a differentiated work of anticipating the acceptable, in a constant signposting of the social supports from which the key ideas proposed could benefit, or in a search for “plausibility structures.”Footnote 28 The dynamics of its production are analyzed as a situational logic through which the OECD Secretariat found itself exposed to issues and polymorphous external resources that collided and were measured against one another within this space. In the eyes of the participants, the use of the “report” form made the international power relations—whether political, bureaucratic, or academic—possible and objective. In what follows, the socially structured expectations of what was feasible, costly, or risky—that evanescent “causality of the probable”—are tracked through the process of collective composition based on four key moments: the commissioning of the report, the establishment of its framework, the constitution of the group, and the report’s crystallization.

In the Grip of the US Field of Power

The Internationalization Strategies of the Department of State and the Treasury in the Face of the Oil Crisis

The McCracken report was initially entitled the “Kissinger Growth Study.” Then secretary of state to the Ford administration (an office he had previously held under Richard Nixon), in May 1975 Henry Kissinger commissioned a comprehensive study on the slowdown in economic growth from the OECD Council, the executive body that brought together the foreign and finance ministers of the member countries. “In the midst of a recession, the most serious since the Great Depression of the thirties,” Kissinger set the objective of studying how to “return to sustained economic growth” through cooperative means, reinvoking the first goal assigned to the OECD in its founding convention of December 14, 1960. He also warned that “continuing inflation that destroys growth will be the arbiter of social priorities.”Footnote 29 This commission formed the second part of the US Department of State’s strategy to enroll the OECD in its objectives. The first had involved the management of the oil crisis, with the setting up of the International Energy Agency (IEA) at the OECD in 1974. The OECD Secretariat had distinguished itself as a forecaster from early 1973, in particular vis-à-vis the International Monetary Fund (IMF), by predicting the effects of a sharp rise in fuel prices on the economies of member countries.

Reacting to the devaluations of the dollar since Nixon had suspended its convertibility into gold in 1971, oil exporters—whose contracts are denominated in dollars—wished to maintain their margins by raising the price per barrel. In October 1973, using the US government’s support for the Israeli army against the Egyptian-Syrian coalition during the Yom Kippur War as a pretext, the countries of the Organization of the Petroleum Exporting Countries (OPEC) decreed an embargo on supplies to the United States, and then to Europe. Prices quadrupled between October 1973 and January 1974. In the OECD area, the inflation rate rose to an average of 15% in the spring of 1974, and to more than 30% in Japan and the United Kingdom. Interest rates reached 12% over the same period, while industrial production fell by 13% and the number of unemployed reached 15 million in 1975, or 5.5% of the civilian labor force, a postwar record. All these data for the period, produced by the OECD itself, objectified the “crisis” and construed it as an international problem.

In September 1974, to prepare for the visit of the OECD secretary-general, Emile van Lennep, to Washington, the head of the permanent mission of the United States to the OECD reported to Kissinger’s cabinet their discussions on how the organization could “be best used and adapted to meet US objectives in [the] current situation.” A veritable “acid test for international cooperation among Western industrialized countries,” the international macroeconomic situation could be broken down into three components: the energy question, the inflation/recession duo, and the monetary and financial question.Footnote 30 Van Lennep welcomed the future capacity of IEA member countries to move capital throughout the OECD area, enabling them to strengthen their negotiating position with OPEC member countries. In this respect, the Working Party 3 (WP3) of the OECD Economic Policy Committee (EPC)—bringing together the finance ministers from the Group of Ten (G10)Footnote 31—could, according to van Lennep, be further mobilized to raise funds on the financial markets and from the oil-producing countries, and to lend them—via the Bank for International Settlements (BIS)—to the OECD member countries most affected by price increases.

This international project for the public and negotiated recycling of petrodollars in order to curb inflationary pressures was similar to the one operating through the channels of the IMF, conceived in January 1974 by its new director-general, Johannes Witteveen, and supported by the Trilateral Commission—though this project could also be applied to developing countries. For some of the senior officials concerned, this involvement of international bodies in the definition of diagnostics and cooperative financial solutions represented the very pinnacle of their activity.Footnote 32 At the same time, for the United States the IEA represented a means to circumvent the rule of unanimity prevailing in the OECD’s Oil Committee and at the IMF, which allowed some countries, particularly France, the right to veto foreign policy concerning the oil-producing countries.Footnote 33 Nevertheless, the IEA’s International Financial Support Fund remained largely inoperative, while the Witteveen Fund was reduced by the US Treasury, and access to it limited to countries that did not introduce (or tighten) capital controls.Footnote 34

Securing the US Congress’s final agreement to such support funds in a period of acute budgetary deficit seemed beyond reach. Above all, the stated goal of Treasury secretary William SimonFootnote 35 was to maintain control over petrodollars, especially Saudi ones, as much as to reshuffle the cards of the international financial system, from the already fragile Bretton Woods system of public oversight toward a system based on financial markets flooded by petrodollars. As Eric Helleiner noted, “in a deregulated system, the relative size of the US economy, the continuing prominence of the dollar and US financial institutions, and the attractiveness of US financial markets all gave the United States indirect power via market pressure to, as Strange put it, ‘change the range of choices open to others.’”Footnote 36 The French government in particular fueled this growth in the financial industry by financing a growing share of its public debt and the disequilibria in its balance of payments at a low cost on private capital markets where liquidities were abundant. When it came to the question of intentionality and, more especially, the sole control of US decision-makers over the reemergence of global finance, it was therefore necessary to integrate other lines of action, whether governmental or not. Though the intention was not to bring down the whole Bretton Woods system, these measures nonetheless contributed to this outcome for different reasons and in an uncoordinated way.Footnote 37

On energy, monetary, and financial issues, the Department of State seemed no match for the Treasury, including in the secret bilateral transactions conducted with the Saudi government. Van Lennep advocated updating the remit of the OECD’s EPC—especially its informal bureau, restricted to the Big Seven,Footnote 38 which “would build on practice initiated during McCracken’s tenure as chairman of the CEA [Council of Economic Advisers, under President Nixon]”—or giving the OECD the role of supporting the Group of Five (G5), a meeting restricted to finance ministers and, from 1975, heads of state.Footnote 39 In doing so, he evoked the international coteries of financial bureaucracies to which diplomats, such as those of the Department of State, were relegated, circles with which he was well acquainted after his time representing the Netherlands as head of its Treasury. When Kissinger, for his part, supported the proposal of Labour chancellor of the exchequer Dennis Healey to increase the prerogatives and resources of the IMF during the British bond crisis of 1976,Footnote 40 he was opposing the Treasury, which championed the rigorous conditions of IMF loans: tightly controlled monetary growth and a drastic reduction in public spending.Footnote 41 The draft of Kissinger’s speech on growth at the OECD, which was leaked to the members of the US Economic Policy Board, made up of the Treasury, the Federal Reserve (FED), and the CEA of President Ford, aroused irritation.Footnote 42 The economic and financial sector of the US bureaucracy, in particular the Treasury, defended its international turf, or, better still, its internationalization strategies.Footnote 43

The Instrument that Derailed the General Theory

Kissinger left his post in January 1977, before receiving the report he had likely commissioned to counterbalance the Treasury’s international initiatives. The OECD Secretariat had not taken the initiative to convene a reflection group on the global stakes of economic growth. For Stephen Marris, the right-hand man of the OECD secretary-general during this period, the reason was simple: the OECD economists did not have anything new to offer regarding the international macroeconomic situation of “stagflation.” The presentation he delivered to his colleagues during a closed seminar organized at the OECD in 1983, on the occasion of his more or less precipitated departure, is interesting. Kissinger’s commission had obliged the Secretariat to break its own rules for the first time:

the classical rule in the use of expert groups is that you must have a clear idea of what you hope to propagate. You choose a group of people that you think are capable of swallowing it. You then produce a report that, with a little bit of luck, will have a big impact on opinion. Now we did not know what idea we wanted to produce.Footnote 44

In addition to this frustrated sense of organizational practice, imperceptible in the internal legal documents, Marris offered a retrospective explanation of the forces at work:

it was written at the precise point of inflection between the Keynesian and the new neo-classical consensus. And being a heterogeneous group it was absolutely inevitable that we tried to straddle the two schools, and of course being in that situation it is fairly inevitable that we fell in the middle and that we were viciously attacked from both sides.Footnote 45

The hardening opposition between these currents crystallized around one of the central instruments of postwar macroeconomic policy used in most OECD member countries: the Phillips curve.Footnote 46 Its academic and political prestige had been lent by the US economists Robert Solow and Paul Samuelson, both leading figures of the Keynesian-neoclassical synthesis—Samuelson had received the Swedish National Bank’s Prize in Economic Sciences in Memory of Alfred Nobel, dubbed the “Nobel Prize for Economics,” in 1970 for his work on the Keynesian theory of the cycle. The Phillips curve was considered to show that if unemployment increases, inflation slows, while if unemployment falls, inflation rises.Footnote 47 Accordingly, the political compromise advocated in the United States lay between full employment, defined as unemployment at around 4%, and price stability, defined as inflation at around 2–3%. The expansive budgetary policy pursued by the Kennedy and Johnson administrations, particularly from 1964 onward, had seemed to confirm the possibility of such “fine tuning,” according to the lexicon then in use. But the simultaneous growth of inflation and unemployment, from the mid-1960s in the United Kingdom and the 1970s in the United States, appeared to call this delicate balance into question.

Stagflation preceded the oil crisis and, as a term, does not emanate from the academy, even though it was lent legitimacy by Samuelson’s use of it in the press in 1973.Footnote 48 It resulted from a position adopted in the British political field in 1965,Footnote 49 one that neither managed nor sought to question disinflationary approaches to income control, which were associated with Keynesianism and which at this time deliberately neglected monetary policy.Footnote 50 Stagflation did not automatically discredit Keynesianism. Interpreters were needed to successfully blame it for the “crisis.” Carried by a new generation of economists trained in neoclassical synthesis, the attacks against the Phillips curve redoubled in the American academic sphere. It served as a positioning lever to contest the whole Keynesian model in its Americanized form: mathematized, technocratized, and laced with a fierce anticommunism and antisocialism. Solow acknowledged post festum that there was, however, “little that is specifically Keynesian about [the Phillips curve], either historically or analytically.”Footnote 51 One of the little-noticed paradoxes of the political consecration of US Keynesianism during the 1960s is that it was almost contemporaneous with the academic consecration of its main competitor, gradually assembled under the label “monetarism,” with Milton Friedman at its helm.Footnote 52 Chairman of the American Economic Association in 1967, Friedman’s inaugural address indicted the Phillips curve even before stagflation hit the United States.Footnote 53 In 1976, during the writing of the McCracken report, he returned to this theme in the lecture he delivered when awarded his “Nobel Prize,” criticizing economists’ widespread support for the Phillips curve.Footnote 54

In each case, Friedman set himself up as a prophet and iconoclast, ridiculing a Keynesian orthodoxy created for the occasion. He took aim at policies designed to combat unemployment through budgetary or monetary stimulus, which would supposedly produce “adaptive expectations” among economic actors and in the medium term return unemployment to its “natural” level—beyond which it was considered voluntary—and inflation to a higher level. He argued that economic actors, especially wage earners, are only temporarily victims of the “monetary illusion” caused by inflation: they will seek to replenish their savings and thus reduce their consumption, which will ultimately affect the level of economic activity. The objective of full employment thus becomes too expensive and leads to a situation marked by the twin evils of inflation and unemployment, jeopardizing the Keynesian model as simplified in the Phillips curve. These critiques—which monopolized academic debates on expectationsFootnote 55 even though their radicality was quickly surpassed by that of the “New Classicists” of the Chicago school and their short-term “rational expectations” (the vertical Phillips curve)Footnote 56—tended to undermine ab initio any active demand-management policy using budgetary and ultimately monetary stimulus, as well as, more broadly, the macroeconomic interventionism associated rightly or wrongly with the work of John Maynard Keynes.Footnote 57

To address the issue of unemployment, the rational expectations model suggested on the one hand politically neutralizing intervention into monetary policy by setting rules for the stable growth of the money supply, and, on the other, focusing solely on the “imperfections of the labor market,” its “lack of flexibility,” or its “structural rigidities.”Footnote 58 This last theme, which was later grouped under the label “supply-side policy,” is dealt with marginally in the McCracken report, taking up only four to six pages out of nearly 400 (in contrast to the Jobs Study of 1994, which focused on this point). Yet this was enough to immediately attract criticism from the social wing of the OECD and Keohane in his review.Footnote 59 As for monetary matters, the report gave more room to the role of price expectations in the determination of interest rates, but remained circumspect about setting fixed rules for monetary growth, though it did consider that this could be a means to improve the regulation of demand. On this point, the OECD economists intended to refine their traditional Keynesian strategy.

The Keynesian Bet on Absorbing Monetarism

These economic knowledges were also state knowledges, part of a “literature of power”Footnote 60 that held the layman at arm’s length and centered on an essentially American world of acquaintance and competition. In a technical annex to the report entitled “The Expectation-Augmented Phillips Curve,” the economists of the OECD SecretariatFootnote 61 disputed the Friedmanian critique and the restrictive policy it implied, theorizing the expectations of economic actors faced with the implementation of a “restrictive government policy.” Its effect would be to “discourage investment and production, and hence lead ultimately to lower employment.”Footnote 62 It would thus bring the economy into an equilibrium where the factors of production were underemployed, and in return justify counter-cyclical action.Footnote 63 The body of the report signals, in this respect, that “insufficient public expenditure can also have adverse effects on growth and welfare and, via frustrated expectations, on inflation.”Footnote 64

Marris summarized the contribution that the information provided by the Secretariat had, in his view, made to the report: “it invented one of the most sophisticated versions of fine-tuning”Footnote 65 vis-à-vis the concept of the “narrow path” (fig. 1), a delicate route to recovery involving an unstable equilibrium between inflationary expectations and faltering demand.

You couldn’t go too fast, but you couldn’t go too slowly either, else there would be an [inflationary] spiral. … There was always a battle over whether the goal was a zero deficit, or whether, as Keynesians like me said, when there is a deficit in private savings in economies, then there may be a position of equilibrium, either a surplus or a budget deficit that balances the structural deficit in the private sector.Footnote 66

We had by then got a model in which we said if you are below potential output you mustn’t try and get back to it too fast because there is a kind of speed limit in going up, but you mustn’t stay away from it too long because then you will get negative effects on investment, on motivation and on productivity and it will be harder and harder to get back.Footnote 67

Source: OECD Observer, 87 (1977), 15. The hatched area corresponds to a “corridor of local stability,” within which “the natural processes of recovery might keep the system moving towards the target region … in the face of continuing shocks and perturbations” (McCracken et al., Towards Full Employment, 321)

Figure 1. The “narrow path of growth”

Source: OECD Observer, 87 (1977), 10. Clockwise from bottom left: Guido Carli, Robert Marjolin, Paul McCracken, Robin Matthews, Herbert Giersch, Ryūtarō Komiya, Atilla Karaosmanoğlu, Assar Lindbeck.

Figure 2. The staging of a closed group

Figure 3. Theoretical schema of the spatial positioning within the McCracken group

The difficulty of this strategy lay in the paradox—stated by Marris in 1970 in a more confidential OECD report—that linked the growth of inflationary expectations to the success of Keynesian economic policy: “once people began to correctly anticipate the consequences of government actions then the government’s actions would become themselves incapable of producing the desired result.”Footnote 68 In other words, the policy’s success removed any fear of a global recession from people’s minds and fueled inflationary behavior (overinvestment, price agreements, wage demands, etc.).Footnote 69 To restore price stability and maintain employment, the OECD recommended that governments eliminate “excess demand” and “be prepared where necessary to accept a temporary reduction in the rate of activity until there are signs that better price stability has been achieved.”Footnote 70 But the electoral risks of such a disinflationary policy were deemed too high.Footnote 71 To break inflationary expectations, the challenge was “how to convince people to behave as though a serious recession could happen without actually having to have one.”Footnote 72 The hope was that economic agents “would be so impressed by our determination to adopt these [anti-inflationist] policies that behavior would change without [our] actually having to administer the lesson.”Footnote 73

This was a deliberate Keynesian strategy to inflect expectations without having to act, very different from the methods of monetarists and New Classicists. This orthodox Keynesian strategy, which could not be acknowledged publicly if it was to produce effects, was largely overshadowed before being vanquished by these outsiders a few years later. As Marris observed, it had been “simplified in the pure form of monetarism when those wretched rational expectations people got into the game” with the unique solution of reducing the rate of monetary growth and letting unemployment rise.Footnote 74 Active demand-management policies were now caught in a vise between a risky and unutterable Keynesian position and an adverse and openly stated monetarist position—and this situation reinforced the central place of inflation and expectations as problems of economic policy.

Some self-declared Keynesians agreed with the OECD Economics Department’s strategy to recreate the fear of a real recession, including the former chair of the CEA under Lyndon Johnson, Arthur Okun (who held the position from 1968 to 1969 and was succeeded by McCracken),Footnote 75 and the British Labour foreign secretary Anthony Crosland, who evoked the specter of recession and the failed arbitration between inflation and unemployment at his party congress in 1976.Footnote 76 The Swedish economist Gunnar Myrdal, who won the “Nobel Prize” in 1974 for his contribution to the theory of money (the same year as Friedrich Hayek), was also of this view, but stressed the institutional and societal factors of inflation and argued for the internationalization of the welfare state.Footnote 77 However, inside the OECD economists close to European social democracy and trade unionism, who also professed a form of Keynesianism, disputed this strategy. Gösta Rehn, head of the Directorate for Manpower and Social Affairs (MSA) from 1962 to 1973, and a leading figure, alongside Rudolf Meidner, of the Wicksellian Swedish postwar model linking fiscal policies, growth of real wages, employment policies, and state intervention, considered this strategy to be too politically risky because it would “be widely interpreted as an official recommendation for increasing levels of unemployment.”Footnote 78 Rehn’s fears were later confirmed: there had indeed been a shift from a disinflationary strategy to an anti-welfare policy.

What was at stake in this internal struggle at the OECD between the Economics Department and the Directorate for Social Affairs, respectively embodied by Marris and Rehn, was the definition of international Keynesianism employed by the organization. These struggles continued with the publication of the McCracken report seven years later. At a seminar of the social and trade union wing of the OECD, Rehn, now head of the Institute for Social Research at Stockholm University, judged that the report signaled the abandonment of full employment as a goal and depoliticized the issue of inflation by examining neither those responsible (in particular multinational firms) nor the redistributive conflicts of which inflation is the monetary expression.Footnote 79 In contrast, Rehn advocated disinflationary policies backed by an active employment policy, ruling out neither the creation of public jobs nor public intervention in business strategies. Meanwhile, the new British head of the Directorate for Social Affairs, James Ronald Gass, summoned to explain himself before the members of the McCracken group, attacked the report for its “total negligence of the social partners, unions, etc.” Underlining the degree of asymmetry and the impotence of the social wing of the OECD, his criticism, as for other reports, was expressed “in verse, quite poetically”: “it was a means of combat; there was such a dominance of macroeconomic thought.”Footnote 80

While there is no doubt that the center of gravity behind the commissioning of the McCracken report lay in the United States, the overall structure of the expert group cannot be reduced to one of unified, unilateral, and undisputed dominance. To the contrary, it lay at the frictional interface of the political, bureaucratic, and academic fields, themselves shot through by more or less conspicuous fault lines (Republicans versus Democrats, Department of State versus the Treasury, Keynesian-neoclassical synthesis versus monetarists). The dominant economic sectors at the OECD (Marris and, through him, the OECD Economics Department) took a position in relation to US debates, thus contributing to their internationalization. The asymmetry of such an internationalization can be measured in the proposed renewal of Keynesianism, which excluded or understated other Keynesian and institutionalist currents, whether Swedish, British, French, or otherwise. Some of these divisions emerged in the initial negotiations over how the report should be framed, while others appeared later on. The report form allowed for this confrontation of informational, bureaucratic, and political capital—in a sense, it objectified their differential value or exchange rate for the participants.

Bargaining over the Framing of the Report

A Secretariat Out of Step with Paul McCracken

To set up “the group of distinguished economists dealing with growth issues,” the agreement of the restricted bureau of the EPC—in which the “major countries” of the OECD were represented by their finance ministries—was immediately sought. The German delegation reacted coolly to the initiative. Its representative, Hans Tietmeyer, deputy secretary of state to the Ministry of Finance, head of the German delegation to the EPC until 1982, and future chairman of the Bundesbank, insisted that the study should focus on the issue of inflation and on “practical problems rather than embarking on futuristic, theoretical model-building along [the] lines of [the] Club of Rome.”Footnote 81 A think tank with a focus on forecasting, bringing together academics, senior business executives, and national and international officials, the Club of Rome had been created in 1968 in the corridors of the OECD (principally by the head of the Directorate for Science and Technology, Alexander King). It had attracted media and political attention through its far-reaching reports of 1972Footnote 82 and 1974Footnote 83 on the negative effects of industrialization, the environmental limits of the prevailing productivism, and the need for global cooperation to reduce (inter)national inequalities in the distribution of wealth and health. After supporting the initiative in its early stages, the OECD secretary-general, under pressure from the OECD Economics Department and the EPC, now officially considered there to be no conflict between economic growth and the protection of well-being and the environment, a position that is echoed in the report. In this respect, Kissinger’s commissioning of the report reinstated economic growth as the focus of political objectives.

The directors of the main OECD departments attended the first preparatory meeting held at its headquarters a few weeks later, as did McCracken. One of the four deputy secretaries-general, the seconded inspector-general of finances Gérard Eldin,Footnote 84 who chaired the meeting, stated that the group wished to offer governments solutions “to regain control of the economy.” The deck of economic policy cards was to be reshuffled: “What rate of growth should be aimed for? … To what extent does the market system still work? … What new instruments are needed nationally and internationally?”Footnote 85 The OECD Secretariat relayed government questions in a multilateral context in which the organization’s “vertical” divisions into sectoral departments or directorates (economics, industry, social affairs, science, etc.) seemed occasionally to be lifted in favor of a “horizontal” discussion pooling documentary resources and objects of inquiry.Footnote 86 But this could not mask the objective hierarchy between the departments in terms of staff, budget, and information capital, especially when it came to statistics. The organizational protocol was another reminder of this hierarchy, in that it foregrounded the Economics Department and the issues associated with it to the detriment of other elements, especially the “social” issues that for the OECD economists posed a problem of quantification and were not always fully integrated into the debates.

Unsurprisingly, all of the participants saw the group as an opportunity to overcome the bureaucratic constraints that usually weighed upon OECD working committees incorporating government delegations. Moreover, the group’s work was not “to duplicate [that] of the Secretariat,” which was “more rigorous [and] should not use any particular model.” It could be “similar to the Rey group, re-examining the economy from a long-term perspective but without a precise time horizon.”Footnote 87 Despite commitments made on the future autonomy of the group and a comfortable provisional budget,Footnote 88 however, the range of questions and mere logistics of the undertaking meant that the Secretariat would play an important role in both the provision of information and the drafting of the report. The timetable was certainly tight: an interim report was to be submitted to the meeting of ministers at the OECD Council in June 1976; only five or six one-week meetings were scheduled, during which the group could meet alone, with the Secretariat, or with external actors. Marris and his collaborators were the key figures in the drafting process.

McCracken intervened little during the first meeting, simply clarifying that the group should not limit itself to the analysis of “economic factors [but] must examine a very difficult problem facing policymakers, namely the fact that confidence for addressing the economic situation has evaporated.” In short, it would have to deal with factors that he himself seemed to judge extra-economic.Footnote 89 Two days later, however, the letter he sent to the OECD secretary-general cut short these more abstract discussions and stated that the aim was a necessary adaptation of Keynesian analytical tools. McCracken no longer had any qualms in stating that “the conventional wisdom of the Keynesian tradition does not seem to be adequate as new economic forces produce unanticipated, fundamental, persisting disequilibria in the industrial world’s economies.” These disequilibria were not limited to the “discontinuous jump in oil prices or short crop yields.” McCracken went on to negotiate the composition of his group: “I would assume that there would be a general sympathy for favoring primary reliance on the market system for organizing economic activity rather than for the state organized economic systems.”Footnote 90 The scope of acceptable profiles was restricted to a non-interventionist way of thinking: the socialization of markets through (para)state authorities was rejected a priori.Footnote 91 By thus bringing into play his own participation in the group, McCracken negotiated with van Lennep every step of the way. This proximity and self-assurance could be traced back to the economist’s exceptional career path.

A Chairman of Syntheses

McCracken was born in 1915 into a Republican family of Iowa farmers, with an uncle who was an economics teacher. His youth was marked by the Great Depression, to which he attributed his interest in economics: “We didn’t have to read GNP statistics, which of course did not exist; the problems were all around us.”Footnote 92 After graduating from William Penn College in Oskaloosa in 1937, he gained a place at Harvard University and graduated with a Master’s in Economics in 1942. He was immediately recruited to the Department of Commerce, where from 1942 to 1943 he officiated in a market economy organized for war. From 1943 to 1948 he worked at the Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis as a financial economist and then as director of research, at the same time completing his doctorate at Harvard. He subsequently moved to the Ross School of Business at the University of Michigan, where he remained until his retirement.

Cofounder, in 1952, of the American Enterprise Institute (AEI)—a conservative think tank whose legitimacy was initially fragile, but which provided contingents to Republican administrations, and which Friedman joined in 1956—McCracken was part of the Republican intellectual establishment in economic matters. As chair of the CEA under Nixon from 1969 to 1971, he took part in the WP3 meetings at the OECD,Footnote 93 where he met van Lennep, who chaired the working group in his role as representative of the Dutch Ministry of Finance before being appointed OECD secretary-general in October 1969. Van Lennep had already consulted McCracken on the question of inflation before Kissinger’s request. Joint-conference rapporteur on this theme to the US government and to Congress, McCracken prepared parts of President Gerald Ford’s speech of May 8, 1974.Footnote 94 In response to van Lennep, he stated that “these distortions and displacement effects are highly specific [to national configurations]. It is not, in short, wages vs. profits, but one wage earner relative to another.”Footnote 95

At the CEA under Nixon, McCracken denounced the inflationary nature of the wage increases granted to workers in the automobile industry and was hostile to job-creation programs in the public sector.Footnote 96 At the same time, he extended unemployment benefits and exempted the poorest in society from federal income tax. Although in 1969 he had argued that in “our economic strategy there is no room for direct control over prices and wages[,] the market economy has its own morality that does not suffer waiting,”Footnote 97 in 1971 he resolved upon a new economic policy of wage freezes and price control, less out of doctrine than “pragmatism” or “realism,” as he liked to present it (including to himself).Footnote 98 This was an “enormous disappointment” to Friedman, for whom it falsified the “natural” fixation of prices necessary for the market to function properly.Footnote 99 On monetary issues, McCracken did not have much weight compared to the FED led by Arthur Burns (Friedman’s thesis supervisor), who had practiced an expansionist monetary policy since 1971. Yet, like Friedman, he wished to neutralize its effects on expectations by establishing a fixed growth rule.Footnote 100 He harbored strong reservations about the generalized floating of currencies (especially the deutsche mark), which he considered “too uncertain and risky.”Footnote 101

The divisive question of fixed or floating exchange rates reached right up to the Mont Pelerin Society itself,Footnote 102 where in 1972 McCracken took part in a meeting attended by Friedman, Irving Kristol, Gordon Tullock, Karl Popper, Gary Becker (“Nobel Prize” in 1992), Gottfried Haberler, and Herbert Giersch. The latter went on to join the McCracken group and succeeded James Buchanan (“Nobel Prize” in 1986) as chair of the Society in the 1980s.Footnote 103 McCracken does not seem to have participated in any of this international think tank’s subsequent meetings, but he did attend those of the Trilateral Commission, of which he had been a member since its creation in 1972. There he rubbed shoulders with John Kennedy’s chief economist, the Keynesian Walter Heller, Carter, the Democratic Governor of Georgia, and Alan Greenspan, the chairman of Ford’s CEA and, as such, a member of the OECD’s WP3—they were later joined by twenty-six members of the Carter administration. Upon leaving the CEA, McCracken joined the cohort of economists (including Friedman) appointed by the Wall Street Journal to produce a monthly editorial, to which he was a contributor for ten years.

Without construing the viva panel of his PhD thesis in economic trigonometry as a harbinger of his future career, its three members nevertheless represented a miniature version of the triptych that structured the field of US postwar economics at Harvard. Alvin Hansen, who had trained McCracken, was a leading Keynesian economist and a Democrat, whose key role in importing Keynes’s ideas into the United States meant that he was well positioned as an intercessor during the Bretton Woods negotiations. Joseph Schumpeter, an Austro-Hungarian who had migrated to the United States in the 1930s, was an elitist and liberal economist. Less well-known than Hansen at this point, he was the archetypal “conservative intellectual”Footnote 104 beset by pessimism as to the future of capitalism in the face of socialism. Finally, Gottfried Haberler, an economist of the Austrian school, had attended Ludwig von Mises’s private seminar in Vienna (the Mises-Kreis), and since 1934 at the League of Nations had developed a theory of the economic cycle and international trade opposed to that of Keynes. He also participated in the Mont Pelerin Society and the Cato Institute, before joining the IEA. McCracken’s originality was that, in a form of allodoxia, he could be perceived as belonging to all three poles at once.

From the report that now bears his name, he retained the expression “Non-accommodating monetary and fiscal policies”:

if you want to limit inflation, you just have to confront it frontally. Then, I remember the meeting in Paris with foreign [ministers] I guess … or finance ministers, and I had to make a report. I think it was almost the case, somebody says “well, it’s obvious!” There was almost a change in thinking [toward] a more realistic point of view.Footnote 105

Marked by a form of prudence, “gradualism,” or centrism far removed from the peremptory outbursts of Friedman, McCracken had not provoked any controversy in the spheres of academic macroeconomics, the intellectual side of business lobbying, or the senior echelons of the US economic administration. In 1975, he thus seemed to be the man of the moment at the OECD, embodying a point of convergence between opposing forces.Footnote 106 Although his interlocutors enjoyed imagining him in a certain way (“eclectic,” “right-wing Keynesian,” “Friedmanian”), McCracken above all brought sufficient bureaucratic, political, academic, and journalistic capital to the overarching—and exclusively American—structure to be allowed to develop a strand of the new global macroeconomic consensus at the OECD.

The Forced Extraversion of the Expert Group

Unexpected Guests: The US Congress, the Financial Times, the G6, and the IMF

Once McCracken’s intentions had been announced to the secretary-general, invitations were issued. The highest ranks of the OECD were tasked with activating this relational capital: the secretary-general and the director of the Economics Department invited Giersch, Guido Carli, and Raymond Barre during the summer of 1975. In a continuation of existing asymmetries, the Directorates for Social Affairs and Science and Technology were excluded from this intermediation. The letters sent out mention neither Kissinger’s commission nor McCracken’s political desiderata concerning the necessary “adaptation” of Keynesianism and the adherence of the invited economists to “market-oriented” positions. This letter-writing campaign was accompanied by meetings. Charles Wootton, the OECD’s American assistant secretary-general, organized a lunch “to allow Prof. McCracken and the Secretariat to discuss matters with a senior representative of the Congressional Joint Economic Committee, who had heard talk of the group’s establishment and wanted to be kept informed.”Footnote 107 This type of meeting gave certain senior OECD officials first-hand knowledge of the perceptions, expectations, and conflicts within US economic institutions. The archives suggest that the US Congressman was the only one to receive this kind of attention, at the moment when the bill on full employment presented by the left wing of the Democratic Party was being reintroduced.

Two years later, this bill led to the Humphrey-Hawkins Act. This set out a new mandate for the FED, which was now obliged to justify its strategy to Congress in terms of the same objectives as the future McCracken report: full employment (defined as unemployment at 4–4.5%) and price stability.Footnote 108 It was also during this period that the House Banking Committee of the House of Representatives, chaired by Henry Reuss, played a decisive role in blocking international monetary matters by opposing any multilateral adjustment measure that would restrict the United States. The United States enjoyed an unparalleled monetary privilege under the floating exchange rate system, in which the distribution of adjustment costs between countries with a balance of payments surplus, and those with a deficit, was decided by the fluctuations of the currency markets. To ward off speculative attacks on the franc and financial instability, the French Treasury (represented by Jacques de Larosière) campaigned against the US Treasury (represented by Edwin Yeo) for a return to a (Bretton Woods-type) fixed exchange rate system authorizing multilateral monetary adjustments (multilateralism of payments), in which the OECD’s WP3 had hitherto played an important role.

Thus not all political and bureaucratic fields carried the same weight when it came to structuring the calculations and expectations of the probable made by the OECD agents and McCracken. The same was true of the journalistic fields. As soon as the group’s composition was almost stabilized, the press had to be contacted. Yet the working title of the report—“Policies for non-inflationary economic growth”—remained too dull, and the alternatives unconvincing.Footnote 109 A leak precipitated the planned “public relations” program. Although not all the prospective members had given their agreement, and no official communiqué had been issued, an article in the Financial Times penned by Samuel Brittan, a prominent editorialist and future supporter of Thatcherism, unveiled the creation and composition of the group.Footnote 110 At the OECD, the reactions were ambivalent. While the assigned objectives and PR success were not disputed, the article dampened any element of surprise.Footnote 111 More seriously, since its confidentiality had disintegrated just as the group’s composition was being finalized, it was now extremely costly for the Secretariat to exclude any of the members mentioned in the article. The leak weighed heavily in the internal negotiations.

The Financial Times article evoked the parallel launch of a group led by the secretary of state of the German Ministry of Finance, Karl Otto Pöhl (future chairman of the Bundesbank from 1980 to 1991), which also featured Raymond Barre, tasked with preparing the first summit of the G5 heads of state. This meeting was held in Rambouillet in November 1975 (as the G6, because the Italian government was ultimately invited), and, despite van Lennep’s insistence, did not include the OECD. In their discussions, the heads of state advocated more cautious circumstantial stimulus policies at the risk of higher unemployment rates, following the principle of “prudence in expansion.” While an economic recovery had been taking shape since 1975, in June 1976 the OECD Council took up the same theme—and the concept of the “narrow path” developed by the Secretariat seems to have been its direct technical translation. Rambouillet also made concrete the results of the bilateral negotiations between France and the United States concerning the international monetary system. This was manifested the same year by an amendment to article 4 of the IMF statutes—via the signature of the Jamaica Accords—stipulating not a return to fixed exchange rates, but the transition to the “stable floating exchange rate system” desired by the US Treasury. On the one hand, states were authorized to intervene on foreign exchange markets to prevent “disorderly” market conditions; on the other, they were prohibited from introducing competitive devaluations. The IMF now exercised a “firm surveillance” over member states’ exchange rate policies, obliging them to provide all necessary macroeconomic information.Footnote 112

Ties with Economic Bureaucracies and the Business Community

A few weeks after the Financial Times episode, it was decided that McCracken alone was authorized, “for political reasons,” to meet the press.Footnote 113 The idea was to establish a principle of inaccessibility and homogeneity, so as to prevent dissonant voices. Male and multinational, the group’s members were presented in the OECD’s press releases as experienced men; their academic degrees, exclusively in economics, were highlighted so as to underline both their intellectual competence and their academic disinterestedness. The main member countries of the OECD were represented in the group and when, in January 1976, Barre was appointed minister for Foreign Trade, he was replaced at short notice by another Frenchman, Robert Marjolin.Footnote 114 The same rule applied when Miyohei Shinohara was succeeded by Ryūtarō Komiya.Footnote 115 With the exception of Robin Matthews,Footnote 116 the group’s members had all accumulated social and bureaucratic capital on the international stage: of the nine, six had spent time at the OECD (or the OEEC), three at the European Economic Community (EEC), three at the World Bank, one at the United Nations (UN), and another at the IMF. At the national level, government agencies involved in supporting decision-making and the production of studies were overrepresented, with seven out of nine members involved in organizations such as the French Planning Commissariat, the British Social Science Research Council, the German Committee of the Economic Council, the US CEA, and so on.

This “intellectual” bureaucratic capital based on technical and political expertise (of the adviser-to-the-prince type) was far removed from the bureaucratic capital founded on seniority within an administration and the exercise of managerial functions. Economics-related government departments (foreign trade, industry, the economy) and central banks (FED, Bank of Sweden, Bank of Italy, Bank of France) were also overrepresented. By contrast, no member of the group had pursued a career, or even part of one, in a “social” ministry or an international organization dedicated to “social” matters, such as the International Labour Organization (ILO) or the UN’s Economic and Social Council (ECOSOC). None, moreover, had run for parliamentary office. With the exception of Matthews and Komiya, the “purest” academics and the most Keynesian members of the group, all had held government positions. These were recalled in the press files without specifying the political orientation of the—mostly right-wing—governments in which they had served, thus depoliticizing them as “wise men” and giving precedence to the official character of their function. Professional experiences in the private sector or in the representation of business interests were also omitted. For example, there is no mention of McCracken being a member of the board of directors of the IEA, or that Carli,Footnote 117 governor of the Bank of Italy from 1960 to 1975, had become chairman of the main confederation of Italian employers, Confindustria, in 1976.

Nor is there much that reveals the economists’ theoretical allegiances, an omission that once again presented the economic disciplines as a united front to the outside world. To the contrary, however, at the 1983 closed seminar of the OECD mentioned above, MarrisFootnote 118 described:

an extraordinary heterogeneous group of people ranging from dyed-in-the-wool Keynesians like Matthews [to] maverick supply siders like GierschFootnote 119 and eclectics like LindbeckFootnote 120 and McCracken, who although in certain senses was a Keynesian, was under very heavy pressure from monetarists at home. … So inevitably we got a sort of committee document result.Footnote 121

The academic qualifications and official functions of the members, combined with their various nationalities, implied the group’s independence and overarching vision, and participated in this construction of meta-partisan attributes. This was the price of expert utterance, that is, the establishment of an asymmetrical configuration pitting scholar against layman, pedagogue against pupil.Footnote 122 These varied but homogeneous trajectories inscribed the group and the institution in tacit and incorporated forms of interdependence that cannot be reduced to interactions alone. And although the director of the Economics Department, John Fay, considered that the group should maintain a distance from the “social partners”Footnote 123 represented at the OECD by the Business and Industry Advisory Committee (BIAC) and the Trade Union Advisory Committee (TUAC), the nature of the group and its initial stances suggest that in reality they were much closer to the business community than the unions.

The Conflictual Crystallization of the Report: From the Probable to the Probative

An Anxious Public Scribe Faced with a Highly Divided Group

In its framework paper on the economic crisis, the Secretariat evoked a wide range of factors: access to raw materials, the weakening of the propensity to invest, the Vietnam War, but also “the distribution of basic income between labour and capital; income differentials between different groups of workers; non-wage demands of households, such as social security, health insurance, and even such aspirations as ‘participation,’ ‘quality of life’ and yet others.”Footnote 124 Though it distinguishes “different schools of thought (which are not necessarily mutually exclusive),” no particular author or academic label (Keynesianism, monetarism, etc.) is cited. The analysis does not focus on the growth of the money supply, the oil crisis, or the labor market’s lack of flexibility. Rather, the note calls for a “thoroughly new approach” in order to place more emphasis “on the qualitative rather than quantitative aspects”: assistance to marginalized groups, incentives to retire, and a reduction in working time. It is possible to surmise from this note the ongoing research that was being conducted into social indicators.Footnote 125

Invited to put forward their own opinions on the situation, the members of the expert group did not explore this idea in more depth. Indeed, the group seems to have been far more closed in the scope of its questioning than the Secretariat. No one wished to reduce the economic situation to the inflation of fuel prices, though some openly identified calls to share wealth, the power of trade unions, and post-May 1968 political mobilization as its main causes. Giersch and Lindbeck thus ruefully accepted the abandonment of full employment and “oversold” demand-management policies. They targeted the growth of the welfare state and advocated from the outset the removal of “employment guarantees to groups of workers who abide [by] wage guidelines; norms for monetary policy, etc.”Footnote 126 These judgments directly echoed the themes of the “ungovernability” of Western societies and the “excess of democracy,” voiced the same year at the Trilateral Commission:

it becomes difficult if not impossible for democratic governments to curtail spending, increase taxes, and control prices and wages. In this sense, inflation is the economic disease of democracies. … The effective operation of a democratic political system usually requires some measure of apathy and non-involvement on the part of some individuals and groups.Footnote 127

Marris raised concerns, in his internal memo to the secretary-general, that the group was “a bit too traditional and conservative.”

Other divisions arose within the group, which were only partially aligned with the Keynesian/New Classical opposition evoked retrospectively by Marris. One thing they had in common however was that they never called into question the econometric and statistical apparatus used by the OECD SecretariatFootnote 128 —for example, the comparability of inflation and unemployment rates—thus reinforcing its key role at the informational level. Atilla KaraosmanoğluFootnote 129 harshly criticized the pre-report for its lack of attention to developing countries, even though he failed, it seems, “to provide drafts himself.”Footnote 130 He nevertheless succeeded in having his critique appended to the final report. In it he states that he does not share “the degree of faith expressed by the majority of the Group in the working of the market.” He points to a factor that he considered largely underestimated, especially when compared to the emphasis placed on the “inflationary wage demands of organised labour”: the “possible destabilizing effects in the behaviour of big international firms.”Footnote 131

On this point, the main text of the report welcomes the OECD Council’s adoption in 1976 of the “Guidelines for Multinational Enterprises” prepared by the Committee on International Investment and Multinational Enterprises (CIME). Established in 1975 at the initiative of the United States, this committee advocated the self-regulation of the sector and sought to counter the draft regulation introduced in 1972 by the Group of 77 (G77) at the UN and the ILO, following the International Telephone and Telegraph (ITT) scandal in Chile. Although the report recognizes that “some companies have abused their political power in small countries,” it immediately states its opposition to the “unjustifiable expropriations” embarked on by some governments.Footnote 132 Karaosmanoğlu called for binding international regulation of the sector, as did many trade unionists and social-democratic, socialist, and communist economists.Footnote 133 As their financial operations become more international, the big firms were able to escape the regulation inherited from Bretton Woods by turning to the deregulated Euromarket of the City of London. A de facto alliance in favor of international financial liberalization established itself between these firms and the financial sector.

Likewise divided on the degree of independence to be granted to the central banks, the group was split even further concerning the scale of the desired recovery and especially its international coordination: “expansionists” such as Marjolin, partly supported by Matthews, Karaosmanoğlu, and Komiya, pitted themselves against the supporters of a moderate recovery: McCracken, Giersch, and Lindbeck.Footnote 134 While their respective countries each had a balance of payments surplus and domestic economic recovery would, to their mind, lead to new inflationary pressures, Giersch and Komiya opposed the coordinated recovery package put forward in the report, again in an appended critique that implicitly referred to West Germany and Japan.Footnote 135 Komiya, for example, stated that “one should not request any [country] to deviate from its optimal recovery strategy in order to take the lead in the worldwide demand expansion or contraction.”Footnote 136 Giving free rein to his ethos as an international senior official (which would precipitate his downfall a few years later), Marris complained to the secretary-general of the general conformism of the group due to the lack of “competence” and “astonishingly nationalistic” views of its members on “nearly all the issues discussed.”Footnote 137

Marris also expressed his apprehension: the overall draft made sense, but its reception was becoming problematic following the election of a Democrat in the United States, especially on the question of economic recovery. He did not rule out the possibility that the report might be “rejected by the new administration” at the June 1977 Council of Ministers. The head of the Office of Forecasting and Evaluation within the cabinet of the OECD secretary-general nevertheless cast doubt on the political nature of such a rejection by the United States, as well as on Marris’s ability to reconcile opposites in the final drafting of the report:

If Schultze and Blumenthal reject this report and take what appears to be a more “expansionist” position at the Ministerial (and given the dissension in the ranks of the McCracken group … that would not be too surprising), I think it will be because of some honest differences in their understanding from that of Professor McCracken of how the modern economy functions. These differences … centre around determinants of investment and the role of expectations. … I simply wish to temper your optimism about the possibility of bridging this gap with felicitous compromise language.Footnote 138

McCracken contacted the new chair of the CEA, Charles Schultze, and planned to meet the undersecretaries of state for Economic Affairs (Richard Cooper) and Monetary Affairs (Anthony Solomon), or even the secretary of the Treasury (Michael Blumenthal) in Washington. His aptitude as a mediator could now be used to make last minute adjustments and thus protect the OECD. To the contrary, however, these meetings revealed a difference in opinion on the global recovery plan that McCracken clearly intended to have included in the report. This discrepancy placed the Secretariat in a bind and entailed further corrections.

The Last Redrafts, or the Bandwagon Effect

Van Lennep was concerned for the OECD due to the “politically very sensitive” nature of the problem. The Secretariat was out on a limb and any denial of authorship would be to no avail: the report would be read as an “OECD report” even without its official stamp.Footnote 139 Consequently, “the conclusions and recommendations [and] even the language [had] to be seen in this light.”Footnote 140 What some readers would take as a mass of stylistic tangles and meaningless constructions in fact betrayed a preemptive defusing of the report’s reception through efforts made to reshape its presentation under duress.Footnote 141 The long meeting held at the OECD in January 1977 between the secretary-general and the new US vice president Walter Mondale, accompanied by the undersecretary of state for Economic Affairs and his assistant, Fred Bergsten—repeated in March of the same year in Washington—simply accentuated the enlistment of the OECD in the US strategy to convince the German and Japanese governments to partake in a joint expansion effort.Footnote 142 Though initially it had been necessary for the Secretariat to associate itself with the group, as the deadline approached every effort was made to create distance and thereby protect it from the fallout through a process of redrafting. This institutional anxiety reflects one of the fundamental contradictions of the OECD when it is held up as an “expert”: its role is to diagnose, innovate, and prescribe, but it works in fear of the main governments that support it, first and foremost the United States, without which its “expertise” might well be reduced to just one political stance among others.Footnote 143

During the 1970s, the issue of a “global demand regulation policy” was not reserved to the McCracken group. The volumes of Economic Outlook published by the OECD in 1976, a declaration by the European Council in favor of a concerted action plan in March 1977,Footnote 144 the preparatory documents for the OECD ministerial-level meeting of June 1977,Footnote 145 a tripartite report by the Brookings Institution published the same year (in which McCracken participated alongside Okun on behalf of the United States),Footnote 146 all pushed the United States, Japan, and Germany in the same direction: to act as the “locomotives” of the global economy through concerted recovery policies, in accordance with the wishes of the Carter administration. But this administration suffered a failure at the London G7 summit in May 1977 against German chancellor Helmut Schmidt and Japanese prime minister Takeo Fukuda.

Upon receipt of the McCracken report at the OECD’s “Ministerial” in June, the US secretary of the Treasury remained insistent: “We can succeed in achieving sustained non-inflationary growth … if both surplus and deficit countries allow exchange rates to play their appropriate role in the adjustment process.”Footnote 147 His statement at a press conference was understood in France and Germany as announcing an imminent devaluation of the dollar.Footnote 148 A further devaluation would have prompted the OPEC to raise the price of a barrel of oil and therefore intensify inflation at the global level, at a time when the United States was working to avert such an energy price hike. Following the example of the Nixon and Ford administrations, and despite its declarations in favor of human rights and international cooperation, the Carter administration secured the stability of US oil supplies and the purchase of US Treasury bonds with King Khalid bin Abdulaziz of Saudi Arabia and the Shah of Iran (at least for a few more months).Footnote 149

US pressure on Japan in favor of expansionist policies continued in September 1977 at the IMF and in November at the EPC of the OECD. In December, Japan finally committed to 7% growth for 1978. The United States then turned its attention to Germany. Schmidt wished to hold a G7 summit in Bonn in July 1978, and Carter made his participation conditional upon specific commitments regarding growth and energy policy.Footnote 150 Although, for domestic tactical reasons, Schmidt was waiting for the summit to impose his policy of demand stimulation—especially in the face of the Bundesbank and his finance ministry—the deal was settled with the US government as early as April 1978: an agreement on a recovery package equivalent to 1% of German GDP. However the Bonn summit, like that held in London, did not address monetary questions—these were supposedly in the hands of the central banks, which were now more independent and compensated for this budgetary relaxation with monetary restriction.

In its final version, the McCracken report unsurprisingly declares itself “against going back to a formal pegging of exchange rates” and notes the “increased reliance on private lenders for official financing purposes.”Footnote 151 The limits to the creation of reserves for states were set more “by the private market’s judgment of the credit-worthiness of individual countries than by official multilateral evaluation of the policies being followed and the needs of the system as a whole. The international monetary system has taken on some of the characteristics of a domestic credit system without a central bank.” In this respect, the most worrying aspect was not “the increase in international liquidity as such” but “the extremely uneven accumulation of debt within and outside the OECD area.” However, no proposal was made to restrict, direct, or rebalance the activities of international capital markets, whose expansion was now almost limitless. On the contrary, it was stated that “compartmentalisation of financial markets should be reduced,” as should “institutional obstacles to the issue of indexed bonds” (government bonds included).Footnote 152 As Marris lamented, the report did not innovate in these areas and said “nothing at all on the institutional and practical aspects of international economic co-operation.”Footnote 153 One of the leading figures involved in the writing of the report was thus its first critic: nondecision in these circumstances equated to taking a real stand.

Following the US—and overall transpartisan—position, endorsed by the Jamaica Accords of January 1976 on floating exchange rates and the development of the financial industry, the McCracken report supported de facto a system of international monetary and financial coordination effected through the market, very different from Bretton Woods. No proposal was put forward based on Keynes’s or Robert Triffin’s notion of an international clearing union that would have a currency independent of states (the Bancor project)—an idea that remained inadmissible in the eyes of the US Congress.Footnote 154 Nor did it address James Tobin’s idea for a tax on short-term financial transactions (already evoked by Keynes in 1930)Footnote 155 to replace the capital controls that were now considered impracticable, especially after the British bond crisis of 1976.Footnote 156 There was no push toward a fiscal and monetary federalism on a regional scale in order to reduce the dependence of developing countries,Footnote 157 or of European countries against the dollar, as advocated in the MacDougall report issued in 1977 by the European Commission.Footnote 158 Also unmentioned was the Franco-German tandem with the European Monetary System after the Bonn summit in 1978, as well as the European Monetary Fund project, distinct from the IMF, attempted the same year by Schmidt before being withdrawn in the face of US opposition.Footnote 159 The dollar, ultimately, was never in competition.

The locomotive strategy produced the intended effects on the recovery of global demand but fed, entirely unintentionally, into the inflationary dynamics linked to the second oil crisis at the end of 1978. To bring down inflation in the United States, the new chairman of the FED (and Nixon’s former assistant secretary to the Treasury), Paul Volcker, appointed in the summer of 1979 by Carter, raised the reference rates from 11% to 20%, leading to a recession and the US unemployment rate rising to 10%. Inflation fell from almost 15% in 1980 to 3% in 1983. Ironically, this success in the fight against inflation at the expense of unemployment signaled, in a way, the continued relevance of the Phillips curve.

Though it might seem a very narrow point of entry, focusing on the collective writing of this report makes it possible to unravel a complex web of “macro” social relations through which the actors navigated in order to add weight to their objectification of economic reality. Via the study of a writing act that could be described as collusive,Footnote 160 this sociohistory of expertise and economic ideas complicates any cognitivist determinism: even in a milieu reputed for its high degree of technical competence, the plausibility, and more especially the validation, of an idea, particularly on economic policy, depends on much more than its relation to an unequivocal reality. It is a question of those charged with interpreting this reality, of their selection or conscription, as well as the social support (actual or anticipated) afforded to these individuals, their ideas, their plans, and the causalities they recognize as valid, invalidated, or confirmed. US domination was instantiated in the commissioning of the report, the appointment of the chair, the negotiations on how the report should be framed, the organization of side meetings, the leaks to the press, the expected reception of the text, and its final reworking. Nevertheless, the (neo)realist and (neo-)Marxist analyses that content themselves with statist synecdoche should be countered: this was not a question of the unilateral domination of one strategic actor over a homogeneous international organization, but rather of the socially differentiated domination of a specific field of power over an institutionalized—and itself differentiated—sector of the international sphere.

The US hold over the dominant sectors of the OECD (the secretary-general and his cabinet, the Economics Department) operated through a series of expectations and informal meetings that never cast doubt upon the integrity of the report as a whole. For the OECD Secretariat, if these transactions involved compromises and strategic monitoring, they never needed to be justified internally: taken as practical, self-evident facts, they were part of the order of things, of the smooth running of the group of experts and of the organization itself. Although it does not rule them out a priori, this influence cannot be reduced to shared ideological motives or explicit instructions issued from Washington to the group or the secretary-general’s office. Knowing the “US position,” namely that of the Treasury, the FED, the CEA, or even the White House, was of prime importance for senior OECD officials in their deciphering of the probable and their estimation of the doable; they were the vehicles of institutional heteronomy. It was a question of the survival of the report and the credibility of the institution behind it, an institution whose funding depended primarily on the US administration. The risk of marginalization was all the greater as this type of organization found itself increasingly circumvented by ad hoc multilateral meetings of heads of state (such as the G7), and challenged in its prerogatives of monetary and financial regulation by the reemergence of international capital markets.

This complex but graspable social structuration, which shaped the governmental knowledge of the economy presented in the report in terms of its production and circulation, was marked by an international and asymmetrical confluence of the bureaucratic, political, academic, and even journalistic and business fields. This confluence was made possible and rendered particularly observable by a form of “desectorization”Footnote 161 within the space of the OECD as an organization, which played out through this report. The meetings between the various OECD directorates (which were ordinarily compartmentalized and whose hierarchical relations continued to favor the economics sector), the use of press leaks to influence the composition of the group, and the Secretariat’s monitoring of developments in other theaters of international operations such as the IMF or the G7, were all manifestations of this desectorization, which affected the action of the OECD Secretariat and its calculations of the probable.

(Inter)organizational dynamics prohibited transgressions and imposed a rather dull symbolic dramaturgy of reassurance. With its representation of points of view that seem to be in opposition or to cancel one another out, the report defines only a midway, cautious position of continuity, a sort of toothing stone for future constructions. The McCracken report remains wedded to the positions of Keynesian (neoclassical) synthesis without letting go of its central goal—full employment—but does so by integrating the fight against inflation to an unprecedented degree. The title selected in extremis—“Towards Full Employment and Price Stability”—reflects this point of argumentative equilibrium that traversed the expert group, the Secretariat, the US government, and its German and Japanese counterparts. Alongside the political alternations that took place in the United Kingdom, the United States, and Germany in tandem with the second oil crisis and its effects, the McCracken report is understood as one of the foundation stones of the neoliberal edifice. Yet there was nothing in the report that authorized an exclusively conservative appraisal of budgetary and monetary policies, as advocated by the Reaganist supply-siders. Recovery policies, especially concerted ones, continued to be promoted, but only if they were situated within narrower margins. Nor was there anything to favor a new Bretton Woods that would have hindered the rise of international private industrial and financial operators, or to push for a redefinition of the well-being of nations in the manner of the Club of Rome. But had this ever been on the OECD’s agenda at this level of exposure?

What is implicitly striking in this structure is the distancing of the institutions of representative and social democracy. With the exception of a lunch with a representative of the US Congress, none of the participants had ever held, even remotely, a parliamentary mandate. This exclusion reflects the technocratic internationalization of the postwar period—indeed, this had been concretized early on in the OECD’s relationship with the Council of Europe, which failed to control its activities. Trade unions, meanwhile, appear markedly diminished, if not dismissed, in terms of defining the ways out of the crisis. This is also true of the OECD’s Directorate for Manpower and Social Affairs—reputedly close to the unions at this point—as well as Ministries of Labor and international tripartite organizations dedicated to “social” matters, such as the ILO and the UN’s Economic and Social Council. There is nothing to suggest that this structural asymmetry between the “economic” and the “social,” which also manifested itself in the asymmetric mobilization of government knowledge between neoclassical synthesis and everything else (law, political science, sociology, history, institutional economics), was a novelty.

The Keynesian configuration seems to have been shot through by the same divide, but within it the economic and financial sectors of states and international organizations incorporated, even despite themselves, the development of social rights into their economic policy, delineating a form of re-embedding of economic liberalism.Footnote 162 The clash with the communist bloc, the discrediting of business elites, and postwar social and trade union mobilizations—as well as the productive and financial structure of firms that were still largely confined to national territories, and the financial architecture of Bretton Woods—undoubtedly formed its main conditions of possibility. If the McCracken report ultimately acted as an international sounding board for a Keynesian economic policy that was biased nationally and would face a difficult future (the Carter recovery package accepted in Bonn would be undermined by the second oil crisis)—in other words, if it functioned as an instrument for the universalization of a particularism—it cannot be reduced to this alone. Confident in their dominant position vis-à-vis monetarist outsiders and the New Classicists, senior economic officials at the OECD in fact thought that they could refine international Keynesianism. The shifts that operated in the margins can be read retrospectively as so many breaches that opened up the edifice to those (sometimes the same individuals) who would gradually be in a position—in the political, bureaucratic, and academic fields, both national and international—to knock it down altogether.

Footnotes

This article was translated from the French by Helen Tomlinson and edited by Chloe Morgan and Nicolas Barreyre.

References

1 McCracken, Paul et al., Towards Full Employment and Price Stability: A Report to the OECD by a Group of Independent Experts (Paris: OECD, 1977)Google Scholar.

2 In contrast to the postwar decades, this period was marked by low levels of inflation and a high unemployment rate. See Stock, James H. and Watson, Mark W., “Has the Business Cycle Changed and Why?National Bureau of Economic Research Macroeconomics Annual 17, no. 9127 (2002/2003): 159230Google Scholar.

3 Williamson, John, ed., “What Washington Means by Policy Reform,” in Latin American Adjustment: How Much Has Happened? ed. Williamson, John (Washington: Institute for International Economics, 1990), 520Google Scholar.

4 Keohane, Robert O., “Economics, Inflation, and the Role of the State: Political Implications of the McCracken Report,” World Politics 31, no. 1 (1978): 108–28CrossRefGoogle Scholar, here pp. 119 and 122.

5 McNamara, Kathleen R., The Currency of Ideas: Monetary Politics in the European Union (Ithaca: Cornell University Press, 1998), 147 Google Scholar; Gilpin, Robert, Global Political Economy: Understanding the International Economic Order (Princeton: Princeton University Press, 2001), 7172CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Mahon, Rianne and McBride, Stephen, eds., The OECD and Transnational Governance (Vancouver: University of British Columbia Press, 2008)Google Scholar, especially Mahon and McBride, “Introduction,” 3–22, here pp. 15–16, Robert Wolfe, “From Reconstructing Europe to Constructing Globalization: The OECD in Historical Perspective,” 25–42, here p. 35, and Tony Porter and Michael Webb, “The Role of the OECD in the Orchestration of Global Knowledge Networks,” 43–59, here p. 50; Woodward, Richard, The Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development (New York: Routledge, 2009), 28 CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Mahon, Rianne and McBride, Stephen, “Standardizing and Disseminating Knowledge: The Role of the OECD in Global Governance,” European Political Science Review 1, no. 1 (2009): 83101Google Scholar, here pp. 94–95; Ougaard, Morten, “The OECD’s Global Role: Agenda-Setting and Policy Diffusion,” in Mechanisms of OECD Governance: International Incentives for National Policy-Making? ed. Martens, Kerstin and Jakobi, Anja P. (Oxford: Oxford University Press, 2010), 2649CrossRefGoogle Scholar, here pp. 32–33; Carroll, Peter and Kellow, Aynsley, The OECD: A Study of Organisational Adaptation (Cheltenham: E. Elgar, 2011), 69 CrossRefGoogle Scholar. This reading was officially endorsed by the OECD Council: Final NAEC Synthesis: New Approaches to Economic Challenges (Paris: OECD, 2015), 54.

6 Pinder, John, Hosomi, Takashi, and Diebold, William, Industrial Policy and the International Economy: Report of the Trilateral Task Force on Industrial Policy to the Trilateral Commission (New York: Trilateral Commission, 1979)Google Scholar. This private association, bringing together around three hundred members from American, European, and Japanese economic, political, and academic fields, was cofounded in 1973 by David Rockefeller, who was also chair of Chase Manhattan Bank. In 1954 the Rockefeller heir was also one of the cofounders of the Bilderberg group, which unlike the Trilateral Commission published no documents.

7 Gill, Stephen, American Hegemony and the Trilateral Commission (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1991), 99100Google Scholar.

8 Schmelzer, Matthias, The Hegemony of Growth: The OECD and the Making of the Economic Growth Paradigm (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 2016), 322–24CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

9 Leimgruber, Matthieu, “The Embattled Standard-Bearer of Social Insurance and Its Challenger: The ILO, the OECD and the ‘Crisis of the Welfare State,’ 1975–1985,” in Globalizing Social Rights: The International Labour Organization and Beyond, ed. Kott, Sandrine and Droux, Joëlle (Basingstoke: Palgrave Macmillan, 2013), 293309CrossRefGoogle Scholar, here p. 300.

10 Lucas, Robert E. Jr., “Paul McCracken et al., ‘Towards Full Employment and Price Stability: A Report to the OECD by a Group of Independent Experts,’ June 1977: A Review,” Carnegie-Rochester Conference Series on Public Policy 11 (1979): 161–68CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

11 Fratianni, Michele and Pattison, John C., “The Economics of the OECD,” Carnegie-Rochester Conference Series on Public Policy 4 (1976): 75140CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Borner, Silvio, “Who Has the Right Policy Perspective, the OECD or Its Monetarist Critics?Kyklos 32, no. 1/2 (1979): 285306CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

12 Interview with François Chesnais, February 27, 2009; Pisani-Ferry, Jean, Plein emploi. Rapport du Conseil d’analyse économique (Paris: La Documentation française, 2000), 44 Google Scholar.

13 Maier, Charles S., “Inflation and Stagnation as Politics and History,” in The Politics of Inflation and Economic Stagnation: Theoretical Approaches and International Case Studies, ed. Lindberg, Leon N. and Maier, Charles S. (Washington: Brookings Institution, 1985), 324Google Scholar; Anthony Endres and Grant A. Fleming, “The Shaping of Research Agendas in International Economic Organizations: Illustrations from the World Bank, IMF and OECD,” Economics Department, University of Auckland, working paper no. 233 (2002), 25–30.

14 Marcussen, Martin, Ideas and Elites: The Social Construction of Economic and Monetary Union (Aalborg: Aalborg University Press, 2000), 3740Google Scholar; Samuel Beroud, “‘Positive Adjustments’: The Emergence of Supply-Side Economics in the OECD and G7, 1970–1983” (paper given at the conference “Warden of the West: The OECD and the Global Political Economy,” University of Zurich, 2015).

15 On the structuring of the report’s reception, see Gayon, Vincent, “Lieux neutres en lutte. Consolidation inter-champs et organisation multisectorielle internationale,” Cultures et conflits 108 (2017): 1543CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

16 As the OECD has no funding capacity (unlike, for example, the Bretton Woods organizations), such reports are part of the organization’s core business. Although bearing the “OECD” stamp, they do not all have the same status, ranging from the regular publications of the Secretariat (such as Economic Outlook or country-specific studies), to working papers by the institution’s economists or external consultants, and so-called “high-level” reports. The McCracken report belongs to the last category.

17 Clifton, Judith and Díaz-Fuentes, Daniel, “The OECD and Phases in the International Political Economy, 1961–2011,” Review of International Political Economy 18, no. 5 (2011): 552–69CrossRefGoogle Scholar, here p. 563.

18 Cited in Panitch, Leo and Gindin, Sam, The Making of Global Capitalism: The Political Economy of American Empire (London: Verso, 2012), 165 Google Scholar.

19 Sullivan, Scott, From War to Wealth: Fifty Years of Innovation (Paris: OECD, 1997), 55 Google Scholar.

20 Hall, Peter A., “Policy Paradigms, Social Learning, and the State: The Case of Economic Policymaking in Britain,” Comparative Politics 25, no. 3 (1993): 275–96CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

21 Cox, Robert W., Production, Power, and World Order: Social Forces in the Making of History (New York: Columbia University Press, 1987), 282–83Google Scholar. For a similar thesis excluding the international dimension, see Gourevitch, Peter, Politics in Hard Times: Comparative Responses to International Economic Crises (Ithaca: Cornell University Press, 1986), 181 sqGoogle Scholar. On the American case, see Cowie, Jefferson, Stayin’ Alive: The 1970s and the Last Days of the Working Class (New York: New Press, 2010)Google Scholar.

22 This aspect was not questioned by the sociology of international organizations initiated by Robert Cox while he was director of the International Institute for Labour Studies at the ILO from 1965 to 1971: Cox, Robert W. and Jacobson, Harold K., eds., The Anatomy of Influence: Decision Making in International Organization (New Haven: Yale University Press, 1973)Google Scholar.

23 The only archives to have been exploited until now are those of the OECD Council, the organization’s executive body (“C” series), which played a limited role during the drafting process. This article draws on a corpus of OECD archives specific to the McCracken report, as well as the archives of the US Department of State for the Nixon and Ford presidencies (the “Kissinger cables”) and the Carter presidency, partly published online by Wikileaks. Most of the documentation comprises correspondence and minutes of meetings classified as “confidential.” The investigation is also based on private or oral archives and interviews (conducted in French and in English).

24 Bourdieu, Pierre, Christin, Olivier, and Will, Pierre-Étienne, “Sur la science de l’État,” Actes de la recherche en sciences sociales 133 (2000): 311, here p. 6CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

25 On the development of this research method, based on the case of the Jobs Study of 1994, see Gayon, Vincent, “Un atelier d’écriture internationale : l’OCDE au travail. Éléments de sociologie de la forme ‘rapport,’” Sociologie du travail 51, no. 3 (2009): 324–42CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

26 Given the inter- or transnational aspect of Keynesianism that weighs on national configurations, this is another blind spot in Hall, Peter A., ed., The Political Power of Economic Ideas: Keynesianism across Nations (Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1989)Google Scholar.

27 Bourdieu, Pierre, Language and Symbolic Power, ed. Thompson, John B., trans. Raymond, Gino and Adamson, Matthew (Cambridge: Harvard University Press, 1991), 77 Google Scholar.

28 Berger, Peter L. and Luckmann, Thomas, The Social Construction of Reality: A Treatise in the Sociology of Knowledge (Garden City: Anchor Books, 1966), 174 Google Scholar sq.

29 Wikileaks, Public Library of US Diplomacy (hereafter “PLUSD”), secretary of state, “OECD Speech Draft (The Imperatives of Growth and Cooperation) for Secretary from Lord and Enders,” May 21, 1975.

30 Wikileaks, PLUSD, permanent mission of the United States at the OECD (hereafter “USOECD”) (William Turner) to the secretary of state, “New U.S. Foreign Policy Objectives and Adaptation of OECD to Serve Them; Van Lennep Visit to Washington,” September 27, 1974.

31 The G10 comprised Canada, France, Italy, Japan, the Netherlands, Sweden, Switzerland, the United Kingdom, the United States, and West Germany. Belgium was sometimes also included.

32 Interview with Stephen Marris, March 24, 2009.

33 Türk, Henning, “The Oil Crisis of 1973 as a Challenge to Multilateral Energy Cooperation among Western Industrialized Countries,” Historical Social Research 39, no. 4 (2014): 209–30Google Scholar; Gfeller, Aurélie Élisa, Building a European Identity: France, the United States, and the Oil Shock, 1973–1974 (New York: Berghahn Books, 2012), 114–41Google Scholar.

34 Spiro, David E., The Hidden Hand of American Hegemony: Petrodollar Recycling and International Markets (Ithaca: Cornell University Press, 1999)CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Cohen, Benjamin J., “When Giants Clash: The OECD Financial Support Fund and the IMF,” in Institutional Designs for a Complex World: Bargaining, Linkages, and Nesting, ed. Aggarwal, Vinod K. (Ithaca: Cornell University Press, 1998), 161–94Google Scholar.

35 There was no shortage of witty bons mots to describe Simon at the time. While some placed him “to the right of Genghis Khan,” others, such as the financial adviser to the French Embassy in May 1976, reported that Simon “considered the very existence of Adam Smith’s invisible hand an unjustifiable intrusion into market mechanisms.” Cited in Paul Lagneau-Ymonet, “Entre le marché et l’État, les agents de change. Une socio-histoire économique de l’intermédiation officielle à la bourse de Paris” (PhD diss., EHESS, 2008), 212. Simon became a millionaire in the 1980s as one of the pioneers of leveraged buyout (LBO). His bestselling paean to neoliberalism, A Time for Truth, was published by Reader’s Digest in 1978 and prefaced by Milton Friedman and Friedrich Hayek.

36 Helleiner, Eric, States and the Reemergence of Global Finance: From Bretton Woods to the 1990s (Ithaca: Cornell University Press, 1996), 114 Google Scholar, citing Susan Strange, Casino Capitalism (Oxford: Blackwell, 1986), 31.

37 Gayon, Vincent, “Finance globale et démocratie. Un regard de sociologie politique de l’économie internationale,” Interventions économiques. Papers in Political Economy 56 no. 3 (2016): 110Google Scholar. The temptation to seek the single factor responsible is as great as its results are incomplete, whether focused on the United States, Germany, or France. See, respectively, Panitch and Gindin, The Making of Global Capitalism; Germann, Julian, “German ‘Grand Strategy’ and the Rise of Neoliberalism,” International Studies Quarterly 58, no. 4 (2014): 706–16CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Abdelal, Rawi, Capital Rules: The Construction of Global Finance (Cambridge: Harvard University Press, 2007)Google Scholar.

38 This expression refers to Canada, France, Italy, Japan, the United Kingdom, the United States, and West Germany.

39 Wikileaks, PLUSD, USOECD to the secretary of state, “New U.S. Foreign Policy Objectives and Adaptation of OECD to Serve Them; Van Lennep Visit to Washington,” September 27, 1974. The G5 comprised France, Japan, the United Kingdom, the United States, and West Germany.

40 In 1976, the United Kingdom was no longer able to sell its public debt securities: sterling had lost a third of its value since 1974, and the inflation rate had reached 25%.

41 There was an analogous and sustained opposition between, on the one hand, the IMF and the OECD, and, on the other, the United States Treasury and the Department of State, a tension that had been palpable in the handling of the Marshall Plan. See Helleiner, States and the Reemergence of Global Finance, 64 and 121 sq.

42 Wikileaks, PLUSD, secretary of state, “OECD Speech Draft,” May 23, 1975.

43 On this underexplored topic, see Sarai, David, “US Structural Power and the Internationalization of the US Treasury,” in The American Empire and the Political Economy of Global Finance, ed. Panitch, Leo and Konings, Martijn (Basingstoke: Palgrave Macmillan, 2008), 7189Google Scholar.

44 Private archives of Stephen Marris, “My History of My Time at the OECD,” record of two seminars given by Marris to the OECD Secretariat on June 24 and 30, 1983.

45 Ibid.; Report of Discussion” [1983], in Economists in International Agencies: An Exploratory Study, ed. Coats, Alfred W. (New York: Praeger, 1986), 115–64Google Scholar, here p. 125; van Lennep, Emile, Working for the World Economy: A Personal History [1991], trans. Graafland, Anita (Amsterdam: Nibe, 1998), 260 Google Scholar.

46 In 1958, the New Zealand engineer and economist William Phillips identified an inverse relationship between wages and unemployment rates, which can be interpreted thus: if unemployment is low, entrepreneurs tend to raise wages to get the labor they need; conversely, when the unemployment rate is high, wages tend to stabilize, or even decline. See Phillips, A. William, “The Relationship between Unemployment and the Rate of Change of Money Wage Rates in the United Kingdom, 1861–1957,” Economica 25 (1958), 283–99Google Scholar.

47 The evolution of nominal wages was replaced by that of price indexes. See Samuelson, Paul A. and Solow, Robert M., “Analytical Aspects of Anti-Inflation Policy,” in “Problem of Achieving and Maintaining a Stable Price Level,” special report, American Economic Review 50, no. 2 (1960): 177–94Google Scholar; and, above all, Samuelson, Paul A., Economics: An Introductory Analysis (1948; repr. New York: McGraw-Hill, 1961)Google Scholar.

48 Paul Samuelson, “What’s Wrong?” Newsweek, March 19, 1973.

49 Iain Macleod, a member of the British Conservative Party, declared in a speech to the House of Commons: “We now have the worst of both worlds—not just inflation on the one side or stagnation on the other, but both of them together. We have a sort of ‘stagflation’ situation.” House of Commons Official Report, Hansard, November 17, 1965, vol. 720, cc1165.

50 Nelson, Edward and Nikolov, Kalin, “Monetary Policy and Stagflation in the UK” [2002], Journal of Money, Credit and Banking 36, no. 3 (2004): 293318CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

51 Solow, Robert M., “Down the Phillips Curve with Gun and Camera,” in Readings in Money, National Income, and Stabilization Policy, ed. Teigen, Ronald L. (Homewood: Irwin, 1978)Google Scholar. See Leeson, Robert, “Keynes and the ‘Keynesian’ Phillips Curve,” History of Political Economy 31, no. 3 (1999): 493509CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

52 By 1971, some were speaking of a monetarist counterrevolution. See Johnson, Harry G., “The Keynesian Revolution and the Monetarist Counter-Revolution,” American Economic Review 61, no. 2 (1971): 114Google Scholar.

53 Friedman, Milton, “The Role of Monetary Policy,” American Economic Review 58, no. 1 (1968): 117Google Scholar. The other initiator of the critique was the future neo-Keynesian Edmund S. Phelps (awarded the “Nobel Prize” in 2006). See Phelps, “Phillips Curves, Expectations of Inflation and Optimal Unemployment over Time,” Economica 34 (1967): 254–81CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

54 Friedman, Milton, “Nobel Lecture: Inflation and Unemployment,” Journal of Political Economy 85, no. 3 (1976/1977): 451–72CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Forder, James, “Friedman’s Nobel Lecture and the Phillips Curve Myth,” Journal of the History of Economic Thought 32, no. 3 (2010): 329–48CrossRefGoogle Scholar. Eminent authors of neoclassical synthesis were by no means outdone in this effort to throw Keynesianism into crisis and objectify it: Hicks, John R., The Crisis in Keynesian Economics (New York: Basic Books, 1974)Google Scholar.

55 Alternative (Keynesian, institutionalist, etc.) approaches to expectations, such as those pursued by Knut Wicksell, Michał Kalecki, Nicholas Kaldor, Don Patinkin, Gunnar Myrdal, Joan Robinson, and Hyman Minsky, among others, were ignored.

56 Sargent, Thomas J. (“Nobel Prize” in 2011), “Rational Expectations, the Real Rate of Interest, and the Natural Rate of Unemployment,” Brookings Papers on Economic Activity 2 (1973): 429–80Google Scholar (cited in the McCracken report).

57 Keynes, John Maynard, The General Theory of Employment, Interest and Money (London: Palgrave Macmillan, 1936)Google Scholar.

58 To ensure that these rules of stable growth were upheld, a brutal change in interest rates—what Friedman called the “surprise effect”—could be necessary. This strategic intervention was criticized by the “New Classicists” and “New Keynesians,” who wanted to reduce uncertainty, including when it came to action and instruments, in order to avoid errors of expectation. See Blanville, Benjamin (aka Bernard Nivollet), “Monétaristes et keynésiens. Au-delà des partis pris politiques, quelles divergences théoriques ?Critiques de l’économie politique 18, no. 1 (1982): 4567Google Scholar.

59 Interview with James R. Gass, March 9, 2009; Keohane, “Economics, Inflation.”

60 Dezalay, Yves and Garth, Bryant G., “Le ‘Washington Consensus.’ Contribution à une sociologie de l’hégémonie du néolibéralisme,” Actes de la recherche en sciences sociales 121 (1998): 322CrossRefGoogle Scholar, here p. 5.

61 Alongside Marris, the OECD Secretariat notably included Rodney Dobell, head of the Division of General Economic Issues at the Economics and Statistics Department, and Stephen Potter and Michael Keating, members of this division.

62 McCracken et al., Towards Full Employment, 275–76.

63 No mention is made of the work of Edmond Malinvaud or Jean-Pascal Benassy, who were theorizing economic disequilibrium at the same time, and who, on the basis of various configurations, distinguished between “regions” of Keynesian unemployment and “regions” of neoclassical unemployment: Malinvaud, Edmond, The Theory of Unemployment Reconsidered (Oxford: Blackwell, 1977)Google Scholar. The same year, Malinvaud was at the heart of a conference on employment organized by the OECD Directorate for Social Affairs at the initiative of the French Ministry of Labor.

64 McCracken et al., Towards Full Employment, 26.

65 Interview with Marris.

66 Interview with Marris, whose point of view converges with that of James R. Gass (interview cited above).

67 Marris, “My History.”

69 This analysis was notably shared by Hirschman, Albert O., “How the Keynesian Revolution Was Exported from the United States, and Other Comments,” in Hall, The Political Power of Economic Ideas, 347–59Google Scholar, here p. 355.

70 OECD, Inflation: The Present Problem; Report by the Secretary General (Paris: OECD, 1970), 10Google Scholar.

71 Goldthorpe, John H., “The Current Inflation: Towards a Sociological Account,” in The Political Economy of Inflation, ed. Hirsch, Fred and Goldthorpe, John H. (Cambridge: Harvard University Press, 1978), 186213Google Scholar.

72 OECD, Inflation: The Present Problem, 35.

73 Marris, “My History.”

74 Ibid. This highly disparaging appraisal, repeated in the writing of the report, no doubt explains why the abovementioned technical note does not refer to the work of the “pope” of this current of thinking, Robert Lucas Jr. (“Nobel Prize” in 1995). Upon receipt of the report, a forceful exchange of views ensued between Lucas and a colleague of Marris, with the latter accusing the former of “policy nihilism”: Dobell, Rodney, “Comments on Lucas and Korteweg on McCracken,” Carnegie Rochester Conference Series on Public Policy 11, no. 1 (1979): 177–86CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

75 Okun, Arthur M., Inflation: The Problems and Prospects before Us (Washington: Brookings Institution, 1970)Google Scholar.

76 Keegan, William and Pennant-Rae, Rupert, Who Runs the Economy? Control and Influence in British Economic Policy (London: Temple Smith, 1979), 101 Google Scholar.

77 Myrdal, Gunnar, Against the Stream: Critical Essays on Economics (London: Macmillan, 1973)CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

78 Interview with Gösta Rehn in 1990, cited in Korpi, Walter, “The Great Trough in Unemployment: A Long-Term View of Unemployment, Inflation, Strikes, and the Profit/Wage Ratio,” Politics and Society 30, no. 3 (2002): 365426CrossRefGoogle Scholar, here p. 393.

79 Rehn, Gösta, “Conclusions,” in OECD, Employment Policies, Incomes, and Growth in the Medium Term: Preparatory Documents and Conclusions of a Trade Union Seminar Convened by the OECD, Paris, 12th–14th October, 1977 (Paris: OECD, 1978)Google Scholar.

80 Interview with James R. Gass.

81 Wikileaks, PLUSD, USOECD to the secretary of state, “Discussion of Kissinger Proposal on Growth at EPC Restricted Session, June 16,” June 19, 1975.

82 Meadows, Donella H. et al., The Limits to Growth: A Report for the Club of Rome’s Project on the Predicament of Mankind (New York: Universe, 1972)Google Scholar. The McCracken report eventually forecast the same difficulties concerning energy (especially oil) supply by 1990.

83 Pestel, Eduard and Mesarović, Mihajlo, Mankind at the Turning Point: The Second Report to the Club of Rome (New York: Dutton, 1974)Google Scholar. On the relationship between the OECD and the Club of Rome, see Schmelzer, The Hegemony of Growth, 245 sq.

84 After leaving the OECD in 1980, Eldin became deputy governor of the French national mortgage bank, Crédit foncier de France.

85 Paris, OECD Archives, “Meeting with Mr. P. McCracken to Discuss the Kissinger Proposal for a Group of Economic Experts to Suggest Possible Strategies for the Achievement of Non-Inflationary Growth,” July 1, 1975.

86 The OECD Development Assistance Center, whose action focused on countries of the global South, was kept at a distance.

87 Paris, OECD Archives, “Meeting with Mr. P. McCracken to Discuss the Kissinger Proposal,” July 1, 1975. Titled “Policy Perspectives for International Trade and Economic Relations” (Paris: OECD, 1972), the Rey report introduced the expression “trade in services” (referred to as “invisibles”), and examined the increased international liberalization of these services within the framework of the negotiations of the GATT (General Agreement on Tariffs and Trade).

88 An initial estimate ranged between 400,000 and 500,000 francs (that is, between €275,000 and €340,000 at 2014 values), including financial allowances for six to seven experts and complementary studies: Wikileaks, PLUSD, USOECD to the Department of State, “Economic Growth Study by Independent Experts Group,” July 16, 1975.

89 Paris, OECD Archives, “Meeting with Mr. P. McCracken to Discuss the Kissinger Proposal for a Group of Economic Experts to Suggest Possible Strategies for the Achievement of Non-Inflationary Growth,” July 1, 1975. Some economists, like Kenneth Arrow (awarded the “Nobel Prize” in 1972), reintroduced this question into the neoclassical framework at the level of corporations. See Arrow, Kenneth J., The Limits of Organization (New York: W. W. Norton, 1974)Google Scholar.

90 Paris, OECD Archives, McCracken to van Lennep, July 3, 1975. This letter immediately became known to the United States mission: Wikileaks, PLUSD, USOECD to the secretary of state, “Growth Study by Economist Group,” July 9, 1975.

91 McCracken indicated his preferences from a list of names submitted to him by the Secretariat: Paris, OECD Archives, John D. Fay to the secretary-general, “Independent Experts Group on Growth without Inflation,” September 10, 1975.

92 McCracken, Paul W. (interviewed by Christopher DeMuth, chairman of the IEA), The Intellectual Portrait Series: A Conversation with Paul W. McCracken (Indianapolis: Liberty Fund, 2002)Google Scholar.

93 Yorba Linda, Richard Nixon Presidential Library (hereafter “Nixon Presidential Archives”), Council of Economic Advisers, boxes 3–8, Paul W. McCracken, “Meeting Files, 1968 (1969)–1971: OECD Economic Policy Committee Meetings.”

94 Ann Arbor, Gerald R. Ford Presidential Library, boxes 1–4, P. W. McCracken Files, “Conference on Inflation Subject File, 1974.”

95 Paris, OECD Archives, McCracken to van Lennep, May 26, 1975.

96 Mucciaroni, Gary, The Political Failure of Employment Policy, 1945–1982 (Pittsburgh: University of Pittsburgh Press, 1990), 86 Google Scholar.

97 Le Monde, August 20, 1969.

98 McCracken, The Intellectual Portrait Series.

99 Friedman, Milton, An Economist’s Protest: Columns in Political Economy (Glenn Ridge: T. Horton, 1972)Google Scholar, chap. 1 and 2.

100 In the promonetarist history of the critical relations between Friedman and the CEA, McCracken is never mentioned: Nelson, Edward and Schwartz, Anna J., “The Impact of Milton Friedman on Modern Monetary Economics: Setting the Record Straight on Paul Krugman’s ‘Who was Milton Friedman?’” [2007], Journal of Monetary Economics 55, no. 4 (2008): 835–56CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

101 Nixon Presidential Archives, Foreign Relations of the United States, 1969–1976, vol. 3, 2003, doc. 157, McCracken to Nixon, “International Monetary Reform,” June 2, 1971.

102 See Helleiner, States and the Reemergence of Global Finance, 116, n. 57 Google Scholar, which is notably based on Stigler, George J., Memoirs of an Unregulated Economist (New York: Basic Books, 1988)Google Scholar.

103 van Offelen, Jacques, Mont Pèlerin Society: Inventory of the General Meeting Files, 1947–1998 (Ghent: Liberaal Archief, 2004)Google Scholar.

104 Bourdieu, Pierre, “Field Effect and Forms of Conservatism,” in The Rules of Art: Genesis and Structure of the Literary Field [1992], trans. Emanuel, Susan (Stanford: Stanford University Press, 1996), 278–82Google Scholar; Passeron, Jean-Claude, “Présentation,” in Schumpeter, Joseph A., Impérialisme et classes sociales, trans. de Segonzac, Suzanne and Bresson, Pierre (1972; repr. Paris: Flammarion, 1984), 938Google Scholar.

105 McCracken, The Intellectual Portrait Series.

106 Thereafter he continually played the role of intermediary. A member of Reagan’s Economic Policy Advisory Board, he and John Galbraith coauthored a book juxtaposing their respective lectures on the administration’s economic strategy: Galbraith, John K. and McCracken, Paul W., Reaganomics: Meanings, Means, and Ends (New York: Free Press, 1983)Google Scholar.

107 Paris, OECD Archives, John D. Fay to the secretary-general, “Independent Experts Group on Growth without Inflation,” September 10, 1975.

108 Mucciaroni, The Political Failure, 93–104.

109 Paris, OECD Archives, John D. Fay to the secretary-general, “Independent Experts Group.”

110 Brittan, Samuel, “Two New Study Groups Aim to Improve West’s Economic Record,” Financial Times, September 29, 1975 Google Scholar.

111 Paris, OECD Archives, Francis Cassavetti to Gérard Eldin, “Announcement of McCracken Group on Growth,” September 29, 1975.

112 Pauly, Louis W., Who Elected the Bankers? Surveillance and Control in the World Economy (Ithaca: Cornell University Press, 1997), 103104Google Scholar, 108.

113 Paris, OECD Archives, Francis Cassavetti to Michel Dantin, “Publicity for First Meeting of McCracken Group,” November 5, 1975.

114 Hailing from a working-class background and the recipient of a Rockefeller scholarship at Yale, Marjolin was the first economist to defend a thesis on Keynes in France. Involved in the socialist group “Révolution constructive” in the 1930s, he was an adviser to prime minister Léon Blum and participated in the Walter Lippmann conference in 1938, alongside his friend Raymond Aron. During the Second World War, he became friendly with Lionel Robbins at the London School of Economics, a stronghold of postwar British anti-Keynesianism. Secretary-general of the Organisation for European Economic Co-operation (OEEC) from 1948 to 1955, he was a pro-European economist his entire life. Jean Monnet’s deputy on the Monnet Plan, he was actively involved in the drafting of the Treaty of Rome. Marjolin was subsequently a key figure in international monetary affairs in the 1960s and 1970s. After his departure from the European Commission in 1967, he sat on the board of directors of Royal Dutch Shell, the Chase Manhattan Bank, General Motors, and IBM. He was responsible for two wide-ranging reports: the first, published in 1968, advocated the liberalization of credit and banking rates (so that prices would reestablish their role in the allocation of funds), as well as a policy of internalizing the French economy in an international context (the Eurodollars market), making an independent monetary policy an illusion in the eyes of the group responsible for its redaction. The second report, produced in 1975 for the European Commission, identified the institutional implications of the economic and monetary union, in particular the creation of a currency, the European Currency Unit (ECU).

115 An economics professor at the University of Tokyo, and a specialist in international and monetary macroeconomics, Komiya was presented by the United States Embassy in Japan as a “pragmatic Keynesian,” like McCracken. In November 1974, he presented a report on inflation in Japan to the Brookings Institution. At this time he also represented his country in the UN’s study group on multinationals.

116 Matthews was Dean of Clare College in Cambridge at the time. He had previously been at Oxford, where he had succeeded John Hicks, who was awarded the “Nobel Prize” in 1972 and had contributed to integrating certain aspects of Keynesian theory into the neoclassical hypotheses of equilibrium. Matthews’s research focused on the theory of economic growth and full employment conditions in the United Kingdom. He was dubbed a “post-Keynesian” and conducted research with Frank Hahn, a critic of the New Classicists but also a theoretician of the general equilibrium integrating monetary factors.

117 In the 1980s, Carli became chairman of the main business lobby working with the EEC, the Union of Industrial and Employers’ Confederations of Europe (UNICE). He was chosen as Italy’s negotiator at Bretton Woods in 1944, and had always opposed the floating exchange rate system.

118 Not mentioned in the official list of the group’s members but thanked explicitly by McCracken in the final report, Marris played a central role in its redaction. Former director of the General Studies branch within the OECD’s Economics Department, he was promoted in April 1975 to special economic adviser to the OECD secretary-general, at the same grade as a department director but without the administrative constraints. Marris essentially spent his entire career at the OECD, with the exception of one year at the Brookings Institution in the early 1970s. Upon retiring, he spent a period of time at the Institute for International Economics, founded in 1981 by Fred Bergsten in Washington.

119 Former chairman of the Federal Committee of Economic Advisers in West Germany and the incumbent director of the Institute for the World Economy at Kiel University, Giersch chaired the Mont Pelerin Society from 1986 to 1988. The US Embassy in Bonn described him as a “staunch believer in the market economy,” who condemned the use of inflation by governments to reduce public sector debt at the expense of private savings. He advocated a de-indexing of wages and an indexing of financial assets. In 1975 he signed the (monetarist) All Saints’ Day Manifesto for European Monetary Union.

120 In 1971 Assar Lindbeck took over as director of the Institute for International Economic Studies at Stockholm University, founded in 1962 by Myrdal, and contributed to its neoclassical transformation. In The Political Economy of the New Left: An Outsider’s View (New York: Harper and Row, 1971), prefaced by Samuelson, he defended the neoclassical synthesis against the American “new radicals” who were calling it into question. He was also one of the founders of the “Nobel Prize” for economics, awarded to Myrdal in 1974 (who regretted accepting it shortly afterwards). During his participation in the McCracken group, Lindbeck published an article in the American Economic Review in which he attempted to situate himself equidistantly from Keynes and the Chicago school, while incorporating public choice theory into analyses of the political field: Lindbeck, “Stabilization Policy in Open Economies with Endogenous Politicians,” American Economic Review 66, no. 2 (1976): 119Google Scholar. His recommendations notably concerned the “depoliticization” of certain government agencies such as central banks, as well as the possibility to bypass parliaments in the implementation of discretionary economic policies. He very publicly quit the Swedish Social Democratic Party in 1982, in disagreement over the creation of a fund financed by a tax on company profits, which was to be used to buy shares in these same companies and to be managed by the unions. He was one of the theorists of the “insiders/outsiders” model in labor market analysis, a few aspects of which had already been raised in the report.

121 Marris, “My History.”

122 Gayon, Vincent and Lemoine, Benjamin, “Pédagogie économique,” Genèses 93, no. 4 (2013): 27CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

123 Paris, OECD Archives, John D. Fay to Thierry Monnier, “McCracken Group: Consultative Arrangements with BIAC and TUAC,” November 19, 1975.

124 Paris, OECD Archives, “Expert Group on Non-Inflationary Growth: Introductory Note by the Secretariat,” September 30, 1975.

125 For the first results, see Schmelzer, The Hegemony of Growth, 300–312.

126 Paris, OECD Archives, Stephen Marris to the secretary-general, “First Meeting of McCracken Group, 6th–7th November 1975,” November 18, 1975.

127 Crozier, Michel, Huntington, Samuel P., and Watanuki, Joji, The Crisis of Democracy: Report on the Governability of Democracies to the Trilateral Commission (New York: New York University Press, 1975), 30, 113, 164, and 114Google Scholar.

128 According to Dobell, “Comments on Lucas.”

129 The former deputy prime minister of Economic Affairs in the Turkish government, Karaosmanoğlu was the author of the country’s 1962 development plan. As incumbent director of development policy at the International Bank for Reconstruction and Development (IBRD), he was presented by the United States Embassy in Ankara as a “former socialist doctrinaire” with “statist” and “nationalist” inclinations who had “softened” during his time at the OECD and the IBRD.

130 Paris, OECD Archives, Marris, “McCracken Report,” February 3, 1977.

131 McCracken et al., Towards Full Employment, 249.

132 Ibid., 138.

133 For example, upon receipt of the Delors or Rehn report (OECD, Employment Policies, Incomes and Growth): see Block, Fred L., The Origins of International Economic Disorder: A Study of United States International Monetary Policy from World War II to the Present (Berkeley: University of California Press, 1977), 204 Google Scholar sq. For an informed synthesis, see Hajduk, Thomas, “A Code to Bind Them All: The Multinational Dilemma and the Endeavour for an International Code of Conduct,” in Multinationale Unternehmen und Institutionen im Wandel. Herausforderungen für Wirtschaft, Recht und Gesellschaft, ed. Brändli, Sandra, Schister, Roman, and Tamò, Aurelia (Bern: Stämpfli, 2013), 311–39Google Scholar.

134 Paris, OECD Archives, Marris to the secretary-general, “McCracken Group: Meeting of 4–5 February,” February 9, 1977.

135 McCracken et al., Towards Full Employment, 30. In his book on international economic cooperation at the time of triumphant Reaganism-Thatcherism, Marris highlights precisely this Keynesian passage, now rather buried: Marris, Stephen, Managing the World Economy: Will We Ever Learn? (Princeton: Princeton University, 1984), 6 Google Scholar.

136 McCracken et al., Towards Full Employment, 253.

137 Paris, OECD Archives, Marris to the secretary-general, “The Last Meeting of the McCracken Group, 7–8 April,” April 14, 1977.

138 Paris, OECD Archives, Wilfred Lewis to Marris, February 10, 1977 (emphasis in original).

139 These fears were confirmed by the ways that the report was later used and referenced in bibliographies.

140 Paris, OECD Archives, van Lennep to Marris, “McCracken Report,” February 25, 1977.

141 Le Monde, June 11, 1977.

142 Wikileaks, PLUSD, USOECD to the secretary of state, “Vice President Mondale’s Talk with OECD,” January 29, 1977. On the “global mission,” see Biven, W. Carl, Jimmy Carter’s Economy: Policy in an Age of Limits (Chapel Hill: University of North Carolina Press, 2002), 95121Google Scholar.

143 Gayon, Vincent, “Le crédit vacillant de l’expert. L’OCDE face au chômage dans les années 1990 et 2000, Cultures et conflits 75, no. 3 (2009): 5373CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

144 This plan was perceived as a Franco-German compromise: German budgetary recovery against monetary discipline in Europe. United States Embassy in Rome to the secretary of state, “European Council, March 25–26, 1977: Declaration on Growth, Inflation and Unemployment,” March 30, 1977.

145 Wikileaks, PLUSD, USOECD to the secretary of state, “Documentation for June 23–24 OECD Ministerial Meeting: Strategy for Sustained Expansion in the OECD,” June 3, 1977.

146 Tripartite report by sixteen economists from the European Community, Japan, and America, Economic Prospects and Politics in the Industrial Countries (Washington: Brookings Institution, 1977).

147 US Treasury press release, “Remarks by the Honorable Michael Blumenthal, Secretary of the Treasury of the United States at the Ministerial Meeting of OECD, Paris, France,” June 24, 1977, quoted in Biven, Jimmy Carter’s Economy, 118.

148 Incorrectly, according to Biven, Jimmy Carter’s Economy, 290, n. 77.

149 Spiro, The Hidden Hand, 148 sq.

150 Biven, Jimmy Carter’s Economy, 145–62; Putnam, Robert D. and Henning, Randall C., “The Bonn Summit of 1978: A Case Study in Coordination,” in Can Nations Agree? Issues in International Economic Cooperation, ed. Cooper, Richard N. et al. (Washington: Brookings Institution, 1989), 12140Google Scholar.

151 McCracken et al., Towards Full Employment, 31–32 and 129 sq.

152 Ibid., 29, 32, and 224 sq.

153 Paris, OECD Archives, Marris to the secretary-general, “The Last Meeting of the McCracken Group, 7–8 April,” April 14, 1977.

154 Triffin, Robert, Gold and the Dollar Crisis: The Future of Convertibility (New Haven: Yale University Press, 1961)Google Scholar. At the time this position was defended, among others and at the OECD, by Jacques Delors. See Delors, “Conclusions,” in OECD, Employment Policies, Incomes and Growth, 7–12.

155 Tobin, James, The New Economics One Decade Older (Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1974)Google Scholar; Tobin, “A Proposal for International Monetary Reform,” Eastern Economic Journal 4, no. 3/4 (1978): 1559Google Scholar.

156 Though capital controls existed on paper, as instruments provided for at Bretton Woods, critics believed that activating them would lead to the decline of London as a first-rate international financial center. Against the “alternative economic strategy” led by Tony Benn in the left wing of the Labour cabinet, in hindsight some viewed the government’s acceptance of the IMF package as the end of British Keynesian society even before the arrival of Margaret Thatcher. See Burk, Kathleen and Cairncross, Alec, Good-Bye, Great Britain: The 1976 IMF Crisis (New Haven: Yale University Press, 1992)Google Scholar, and Hickson, Kevin, The IMF Crisis of 1976 and British Politics (London: I. B. Tauris, 2005)CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

157 Hirsch, Fred and Doyle, Michael W., “Politicization in the World Economy: Necessary Conditions for an International Economic Order,” in Alternatives to Monetary Disorder, ed. Hirsch, Fred, Doyle, Michael W., and Morse, Edward L. (New York: McGraw-Hill, 1977)Google Scholar.

158 Commission of the European Communities, Report of a Study Group on the Role of Public Finances in European Integration (Brussels: April 1977).

159 Basosi, Duccio, “Principle or Power? Jimmy Carter’s Ambivalent Endorsement of the European Monetary System, 1977–1979,” Journal of Transatlantic Studies 8, no. 1 (2010): 618CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

160 Gayon, Vincent, “Écrire, prescrire, proscrire. Notes pour une sociogénétique de l’écrit bureaucratique,” Actes de la recherche en sciences socials 213 (2016): 84103CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

161 Dobry, Michel, “Ce dont sont faites les logiques de situation,” in L’atelier du politiste. Théories, actions, représentations, ed. Favre, Pierre, Fillieule, Olivier, and Jobard, Fabien (Paris: La Découverte, 2007), 119–48Google Scholar.

162 For an operationalization of this Polanyian scheme, see Gayon, Vincent and Lemoine, Benjamin, “Maintenir l’ordre économique. Politiques de désencastrement et de réencastrement de l’économie,” Politix. Revue des sciences sociales du politique 27, no. 1/105 (2014): 935Google Scholar.

Figure 0

Figure 1. The “narrow path of growth”

Source: OECD Observer, 87 (1977), 15. The hatched area corresponds to a “corridor of local stability,” within which “the natural processes of recovery might keep the system moving towards the target region … in the face of continuing shocks and perturbations” (McCracken et al., Towards Full Employment, 321)
Figure 1

Figure 2. The staging of a closed group

Source: OECD Observer, 87 (1977), 10. Clockwise from bottom left: Guido Carli, Robert Marjolin, Paul McCracken, Robin Matthews, Herbert Giersch, Ryūtarō Komiya, Atilla Karaosmanoğlu, Assar Lindbeck.
Figure 2

Figure 3. Theoretical schema of the spatial positioning within the McCracken group