Since the Unified Patent Court (UPC) and the UP system officially entered into force on 1 June 2023, European patent law is experiencing a procedural and substantial regime shift. Before, only the prosecution of European Patents (EP) at the European Patent Office (EPO) was harmonised through a centralised procedure granting a “bundle of patents,” designating various Member States. The post-grant litigation of European Patents, however, was exclusively dealt with by national law. This changed with the introduction of European patents with unitary effect, which are litigated within the UPC system. These exciting developments correspond with a trend of increasing harmonisation in the European Intellectual Property (IP) arena through various EU legal acts, which pertain to a broad range of other rights such as supplementary protection certificates (SPCs), regulatory exclusivities, trade secrets, trademarks, industrial designs and copyrights.
However, as the process leading up to the necessary national ratification of the Unified Patent Court Agreement (UPCA) has demonstrated, the speed, scope and degree of the much-coveted harmonisation is not straightforward, and there is still a patchwork of various interacting rights and national peculiarities that need to be carefully considered. Consequently, the UP system and alternative forms of protection do not only offer new promises and opportunities, but also persisting uncertainties, legal lacunae and perils that need to be navigated by all relevant stakeholders.
In that context, it is important to recall that patents do not offer the only pathway to protect technical solutions to technical problems through negative exclusionary rights for a limited period of time. Unless Inventors choose to keep their inventions secret or to rely on regulatory exclusivities, some jurisdictions still offer UM protection for (minor) inventions, also called “small patents,” “utility patents,” “innovation patents,” “second-tier patents” and “short-term patents.” In this chapter, we refer to this form of protection as utility models, or in short: UMs. Generally, the European Commission and IP offices stress that UMs are shorter, simpler, faster and cheaper protection methods compared to patents, but there are differences in how these features are implemented.Footnote 1 The differences between UMs and patents result in multidimensional sorting as economic agents choose within the IP menu in accordance with the specific differences in characteristics and outcomes of patents and UMs.Footnote 2 Strategic choices are complicated by the fact that various European and international jurisdictions display very different approaches with regard to UMs, that is, in terms of availability, procedure, scope, enforceability and how requirements are interpreted.Footnote 3 It is further important to note that UMs are also not directly covered by the UP system, and since earlier attempts towards a harmonised EU system for UMs have failed,Footnote 4 national rules and disparities remain applicable, despite their kinship to patents.
But how will the UPC interact with and affect the system for UM protection in Europe and vice-versa? This is an important question. It relates to both procedural dynamics and substantial effects in prosecution and litigation, which will, in turn, influence the stakeholder’s choices and the different IP strategies that these may pursue. Within the patent context, stakeholders will have to consider, amongst other things, which forum to seek for litigation and, more specifically, if it would be better to “opt out” from the UPC system and, if having done so, when to withdraw from the “opt out.”Footnote 5 On top of all this, they will have to consider if UMs should be part of their IP and innovation strategy, be it as a sole form of protection that is sought for a given jurisdiction from the start, or whether and when patent (applications) should be converted into UMs or branched off. This chapter attempts to shed some light on these issues, which are as relevant as they are elusive.
Specifically, it focuses on the delicate interplay between the new European Unitary Patent (UP) system and utility model (UM) protection. To set the stage and provide the necessary background, Section 17.1 will start out with a brief recap and overview of the relationship between the EU, the European Patent Convention (EPC),Footnote 6 and the UPCA. Section 17.2 will then elaborate on the differences among relevant jurisdictions with regard to the availability of UPs and UMs. This section will also deliver a brief description of the basic formal relationship between the EPC, the UPCA, the EU, UMs, the European Patent Office (EPO) and national granting authorities. Next, Sections 17.3–17.5 will explore how the changes brought about by the introduction of the UPC and UP into the existing patent-UM landscape may affect business strategies involving patents and UMs of businesses operating in Europe. Section 17.3 first examines the division of judicial competences now that the UPC has become operational, and Section 17.4 then scrutinizes the relationship between domestic courts and UPC divisions. This is followed by Section 17.5 which will start by digging deeper into the general reasons and strategic considerations that stakeholders might have for converting patents into UMs or for branching them off, and then considers the specific issues of how double patenting and the BOUM (“branched-off utility models”) strategies might be affected post-UPC, as well as the cost of a UP. This provides the basis for Section 17.6, vis-á-vis strategic choices, followed by concluding remarks pointing towards unresolved issues and areas for future research in Section 17.7.
17.1 The EU, the EPC and the UPCA
From a patent law perspective, it is noteworthy that today’s EU patent with unitary effect has been in the making since 1976.Footnote 7 Ever since the Treaty of RomeFootnote 8 entered into force in 1958, a project to establish an EU patent as a unitary right has been discussed. The EU Commission has published communications and reports and proposed several drafts for legislation for an EU patent.Footnote 9 Until 2023, the impact of EU law on patent law has been largely negligible.
The Treaty of Rome was silent on IPR issues, and simply stated in Article 295 (now Article 345 of the TFEU)Footnote 10 that it in no way prejudiced the rules of Member States governing the system of property ownership. However, the protection of IPRs was included in the original Treaty structure in a more indirect way. Article 36 of the Treaty (now Article 36 of the TFEU) did allow Member States to restrict the free movement of goods (one of the four major freedoms established by the Treaty of Rome) on specific grounds, which included “the protection of industrial and commercial property.” Nevertheless, the European Court of Justice (now Court of Justice of the European Union, CJEU) did not allow all restrictions on free movement rights to be justified by national IP rights, and already in its early case law it was distinguishing between the existence of a right (Article 345) and the exercise of a right, therefore interpreting Article 36 as covering only the “specific subject matter” of the right.Footnote 11 Accordingly, the CJEU interpreted the provision as a requirement of non-discrimination in the granting and protection of IPRs in the Community.Footnote 12 It developed the doctrine of regional exhaustion of rights by the lawful placing of a product on the market in the Community.Footnote 13 Without direct treaty authority, the CJEU thus managed to develop a set of rules on patent law on the way to a non-discriminatory trade law.
The furthest point so far, at the treaty level, is Article 118 of the TFEU adopted by the Lisbon Treaty in 2009. It states that the European Parliament and the Council shall provide measures for the creation of European IP rights to provide uniform protection throughout the Union. In addition to this, Article 262 of the TFEU provides for conferral of jurisdiction on the Court of Justice of the European Union in disputes relating to IP rights. So far, uniform protection has been established for trademarks and designs.Footnote 14 Somehow patent protection slipped through the net, probably to some degree due to the entering into force of the 1973 European Patent Convention (EPC 1973).Footnote 15 Due to the EPC, which established the European Patent Organisation (EPOrg) in 1973, EPs reside outside the EU, and the number of contracting states to the EPC has increased during the years. Today, it has 39 members.Footnote 16 All EU Member States are also members of the EPOrg and, since a UP will start out as an application for an EP, the EPO will continue as an important player in the European patent landscape.
In a way, the EPC was a compromise, as the political landscape at the time of the adoption of the EPC did not allow for a unitary European Community Patent. Consequently, it was decided to follow a different pathway. According to its preamble, the EPC is a special agreement within the meaning of Article 19 of the Paris ConventionFootnote 17 and a regional patent treaty pursuant to Article 45 of the Patent Cooperation Treaty (PCT).Footnote 18 Therefore, Article 1 of the EPC establishes a substantive and procedural European law for the grant of EPs as a “system of law, common to the Contracting States, for the grant of patents for invention” and it allows applicants either to obtain a bundle of patents designating various contracting states or to designate a single contracting state only.Footnote 19
As for UMs, the EU Commission’s endeavours to establish uniform UM protection have failed.Footnote 20 In March 2000, the Commission suspended its proposal due to difficulties in reaching consensus on its substance among Member States, and utility protection was abandoned in favour of unified patent protection.
By 1 June 2023 – 50 years after the foundation of the EPC and 65 years after the first attempt to adopt an EU patent – the “unitary patent package” entered into force and introduced a new concept, namely a “European patent with unitary effect” (UP), and the UPC emerged as the new patent judiciary for enforcement of EP with and without such unitary effect.Footnote 21 The unitary patent package consists of the UPCA,Footnote 22 the Unitary Patent Regulation (UPReg)Footnote 23 and the Translations Regulation (UPTReg).Footnote 24 The road to unitary patent protection was enabled in 2012 by enhanced cooperation, which is used when the EU as a whole cannot achieve the goals of cooperation in a particular field within a reasonable period. The outcome of this lack of coherence has been a rather atypical sort of EU harmonisation combining EU regulations, an international agreement – the UPCA – on the judiciary (in principle, the UPCA is placed outside the scope of the CJEU) with a granting authority – the EPO – disconnected from the EU. For contrast, the EU trademark and EU design right are genuine EU rights, granted by the EU Intellectual Property Office (EUIPO) and reviewed by its boards of appeal and the General Court and, on points of law, the CJEU.Footnote 25
The “new” UPs must be registered by the EPO and will be effective in the 18 Member States which take part in the enhanced cooperation in the creation of unitary patent protection enacted by UPReg and which have ratified the UPCA. Both the EP and UP are granted by the EPO under the rules of the EPC, and there are no changes to the pre-grant phase or the EPC’s substantive patent law in this regard. Only after the granting, the patent holder can request unitary effect, meaning uniform patent protection in 18 EU Member States.Footnote 26
Article 3(1) of the UPReg states that a European patent granted with the same set of claims in respect of all the participating Member States shall benefit from unitary effect in all participating Member States; and in Article 4, that the unitary patent is effective on the date of publication in the European Patent Bulletin; implying that the participating Member States shall ensure that a European patent is deemed not to have taken effect as a national patent in their territory on the date of publication; and in Article 5(2) that the scope of that right and its limitations shall be uniform in all participating Member States in which the patent has unitary effect.
As it follows from Article 3(b) of the UPCA, the agreement also applies to SPCs. According to Article 30, a SPC shall confer the same rights as conferred by the patent and shall be subject to the same limitations and the same obligations. In two 2023 proposals for regulations on unitary supplementary certificates for medicinal products and for plant protection products, the EUIPO was named as the central examination authority, and its opinion would be binding upon the national offices of the designated Member State which remains the granting authority. Because UPs are granted by the EPO, combined with the fact that the EP, UP and SPCs are closely linked, this may add to the confusion in the patent landscape.Footnote 27 This confusion may increase when considering UMs, for which some of the Member States that are part of the unitary patent area also provide protection in their national systems. This will be further explored in the next section.
17.2 Protecting UMs in (Some) EU Member States and the Tentative Beginning of the UPC Arrangement
This section starts out by providing a brief overview of the differences among relevant jurisdictions with regard to their participation in the UPC, and the availability of UPs and UMs. Next follows a brief description of the basic formal relationship between the EPO, UPs and UMs, as well as the interplay between the EPO, UMs and national granting authorities.
17.2.1 An Overview
As mentioned above, only 18 EU Member States are currently taking part in the UPC arrangement.Footnote 28 Only 11 UPC participating EU Member States provide for UM protection: Austria, Bulgaria, Denmark, Estonia, Finland, France, Germany, Italy, Portugal, Romania and Slovenia; whereas Greece, Hungary, Ireland and Slovakia are Member States that have signed but not yet ratified the UPCA, and UM protection can be obtained in these Member States. Also, Croatia, Poland and Spain are EU Member States with UM protection, but these Member States are not participating in the UPCA. Due to the gap and diversity in the EU Member States towards the UP and the UPC as such, and since all EU Member States (including those with UM protection) are also Members of the EPO, the future UM landscape is rather blurred.
These numbers are summarised in Table 17.1.
Table 17.1 European States and participation in European patent institutions
Organisation/system | Number of Member States | Number of Member States with UM protection |
---|---|---|
European Union | 27 | 18 |
Unified Patent Court Agreement (initial Signatory State) | 24 | 15 |
Unitary Patent Area (completed ratification UPCA) | 18 | 11 |
Non-participating Member States | 3 | 3 |
European Patent Organisation | 39 | 22 |
For inventors residing and/or operating in those EU Member States not yet part of the unitary patent area who can only obtain a EP, they may only opt for protection in the form of a bundle of national patents within and/or outside of the unitary patent area.
Despite the lack of coherence in the EU as to UM harmonisation and patent law harmonisation, some EU Member States, namely Germany, Spain, Italy, France and Poland are in the top 20 offices regarding the number of received UM applications, indicating a salience in the field of UM protection.Footnote 29 Thus, one cannot neglect the relevance of UM protection in the EU Member States.
17.2.2 The EPC, the UPReg, the UPCA and How They Relate to UMs
The EPOrg and the EU are two separate organisations, and so far EU legislation on substantive patent law has been minimal. However, the adoption of the first – and so far, the only – act on patentable subject matter in the EU, Directive 98/44/EC on biotechnological inventions (Biotech Directive),Footnote 30 has had an impact on the EPC. Its provisions on patentable subject matter were inserted into the Implementing Regulation of the EPC.Footnote 31 However, in the aftermath it was made clear that although the wording of the provisions is formulated similarly at different regulatory levels, their interpretations at the different levels are legally independent of each other.Footnote 32
The vulnerable point in European patent law is the increasingly mixed competences of the EPO and EU – now further confused by UPReg and the UPC. The UPReg is virtually deprived of substantive patent law,Footnote 33 whereas the UPCA’s Chapter V forms the basis for future UPC jurisprudence.Footnote 34 Furthermore, the UPC must apply Union law and respect its primacy, as well as cooperate with the CJEU in accordance with Article 267 of the TFEU. Since EU law is almost silent on substantive patent law, it is hard to picture future CJEU involvement on a frequent scale concerning substantive patent law. Altogether, the CJEU’s involvement seems rather limited, and the current frame is aimed at preventing the CJEU from becoming an appeal court for revocation and infringement while, at the same time, preserving its grip on Union law primacy. In other words, the UPC is a pretty isolated specialised court in European patent law. In this context, the UPC is likely to become a central policymaker in the future EU patent system despite its transnational character, as will be considered further in Section 17.5.Footnote 35
Presently, the centre stage of the European patent system is taken by the EPO and its Boards of Appeal as developers of substantive patent law. The EPO has considerable autonomy towards granting, but subsequently limited judicial control. It is therefore possible to narrow down this section to focus on the EPO/EPC and UPC/UPCA. The EP (39 contracting states) and the UP (18 EU Member States) are both granted by the EPO under the rules of the EPC.
The EPC is the legal source for the pre-grant and granting procedure, only as such on patents and not on UMs. In other words, the unitary patent system and UMs are not clearly related, especially since the latter is not an EU or EPC harmonised right and falls outside the scope and competence of the UPC as such. However, as the EPC preamble clearly refers to the Paris Convention and PCT, it cannot contravene the provisions thereof. Article 1, subsection 2 of the Paris Convention states that the protection of industrial property has as its object patents, UMs and more. Therefore, in countries where UM protection is available, the general principles of the Paris Convention, such as national treatment and the right of priority, are also applicable to UMs. If an international patent application under the PCT is filed, UMs are available at the national level in designated countries that have a UM system. Article 43 of the PCT provides the legal basis for an international applicant to obtain a UM instead of or in addition to a patent (in accordance with national law), cf. Article 4(3) and R 4.1 (b)(iii) of the PCT.
Further, despite the EPC being patent-centred, UMs are no stranger to the convention. Article 140 of the EPC (Part VIII Impact on national law), stipulates that Articles 66, 124, 135, 137 and 139 of the EPC shall apply to UMs and utility certificates (the latter is a French instrument (see Chapter 5), and to applications for UMs and utility certificates registered or deposited in the Contracting States whose laws make provision for such models or certificates.Footnote 36 This interface of patent applications and UM applications motivates us to consider whether decisions by the UPC may impact UM protection and prosecution in the Member States.
17.2.3 The EPO, UMs and National Granting Authorities
Article 140 of the EPC provides the basis for a European patent application to be converted into a national UM application while maintaining its priority claim, cf. Articles 66 and 135. It further follows from Article 87, subparagraph 1, of the EPC, that the right of priority according to the Paris Convention applies to UMs and utility certificates.Footnote 37 Pursuant to Article 124 of the EPC, the applicant on request of the EPO must inform the office of all states in which it has filed UMs and the reference number of these applications.Footnote 38 Articles 135 and 137 of the EPC allow the application to be converted into a national UM or certificate without any additional national formal requirements.
Article 140 of the EPC is only directed towards patent applications to be converted into national UM applications by a request from the applicant. By the time the patent is granted and published – with or without a further request for unitary effect according to Article 9 (1)(g) of the UPReg – it is no longer relevant.
The UPC has not been given jurisdiction over UM protection, and once a patent application has been converted into a national UM application, all future aspects concerning the UM application are left to the autonomy of the national patent authority. Nevertheless, we cannot disregard that the UPC can have a potential impact on, for example, EPO patent families which have a UM registered as well. Thus, UPC case law might (indirectly) affect UM claim interpretation or undermine their validity given their potential overlap or connection to an EP or a UP.
17.3 Division of Judicial Competences Post-UPC
As alluded to before, the UP and the UPC only form an extra layer in the existing patent landscape; they do not replace any type of patent or court.Footnote 39 However, this new patent and court are not created to form an isolated system either, which results in an interesting patchwork of jurisdiction in Europe. Moreover, it will both affect existing judicial relationships and create new ones. Directly or indirectly, such shifts may, in turn, bring about change in legal doctrine and who drives it for a given territory. It is improbable that these changes will be without some impact on business strategies involving patents and UMs of businesses operating in Europe. What the next part of this chapter contributes is a first exploration into some of the avenues that may effect change now that the UPC has become operational, starting with the division of jurisdiction.
17.3.1 Jurisdiction on Non-national Patents
What the creation of this new system means for the division of judicial competence on patents in Europe is as follows. According to the UPCA, the UPC will have exclusive competence on actions for revocation and enforcement of both classical EPs and UPs, as well as SPCs.Footnote 40 That is, after the expiration of the transitional period. The UPCA provides for a transitional regime for certain categories of patents during the first seven years (subject to a potential extension) of entry into force of the UPCA.Footnote 41 Until this regime lapses, disputes involving EPs and SPCs may also still be brought before national courts, resulting in shared competence between the UPC and national courts for such rights.
However, the UPCA also provides the option to formally opt out of the UPC’s jurisdiction.Footnote 42 EPs and SPCs for which their proprietors have made use of the possibility to opt-out of the UPC’s jurisdiction, remain the sole prerogative of the competent national courts within the territories in which they are valid even after the expiration of the transitional period. This point will not be pursued further, but it bears mentioning that the new UPC will thus essentially be competing with domestic courts for the favour of patentees. The system will only succeed, if patentees are willing to use the system, either by obtaining a UP or by choosing not to opt out for their EP. Another important caveat here is that the UPC’s decisions will not have the same territorial effect for UPs and EPs and SPCs without unitary effect. As already mentioned in Section 17.1, in the UPReg and UPCA, it is stated that the UPC’s decisions on unitary patents shall have effect for the whole of the “unitary territory,”Footnote 43 whereas for EPs, the UPC’s decisions will cover only “the territory of those Contracting Member States for which the European patent has effect.”Footnote 44 It is certainly a positive development that the need to conduct parallel litigation in Europe for the same dispute is mitigated. This also seems to limit the pre-UPC possibilities for parties to commence in forum shopping, without completely foreclosing such opportunities.Footnote 45 Nevertheless, it should be noted that this also has its (potential) repercussions for, amongst other things, litigation costs, invalidation for the entire unitary patent area, being able to only focus on markets of consequence, the ability to recover from being enjoined and the attractiveness of designating European countries for a EP outside of the unitary patent area.
17.3.2 Jurisdiction on National Patents and UMs
What has been discussed in the previous subsection does not apply to the last category of patents in Europe, namely national patents, nor does it apply to UMs. Both remain national rights within the exclusive competence of the relevant domestic courts. It is worth reiterating that, in contrast with national patents, the relationship of the UPC with UMs has not been formally addressed. The UPC has not been given jurisdiction on either national right but, again, UMs are not even mentioned in the instruments of the Unitary Patent Package (including the Rules of Procedure of the Unified Patent Court “RoP”). In fact, this omission is notable, as the failed instrument for a Community Patent did contain a provision declaring certain provisions applicable to UMs, as well.Footnote 46 However, the absence of references to such rights in the Unitary Patent Package does not mean that UMs will not be affected by the UPC’s decisions due to their potential connections with patents (e.g., double patenting, branched-off UMs).
As pointed out above, another complicating factor in this respect is the patchwork of different types of legal instruments that may (indirectly) apply in a given case, particularly when combined with the varying national scope limitations on UMs. The influence of a particular instrument depends on, amongst other things: (a) whether a country is a member to a particular organisation and (b) the nationally determined scope of a UM. This has its implications for which granting and judicial bodies have some authority in the matter, and to what extent. The most dominant form of a UM appears to be a cheaper and more attainable patent, but there are variations between states such as in the patentability requirements and exclusions of subject matter.
A good example to explore this with is the EU’s Biotech Directive.Footnote 47 Since an EU directive is not directly applicable, EU Member States had to transpose its mandatory provisions, and their courts (and the UPCFootnote 48) must ensure that national law is interpreted and applied in compliance with this instrument. If we take a look at what this would mean for Germany and Italy, the Biotech Directive is relevant for their national patenting of biotechnological inventions, but both preclude UMs on that category of subject matter.Footnote 49 Consequently, there should logically not be any influence from the Biotech Directive upon their national UMs as far as their exclusion goes. This might be different for EU Member States which have chosen not to exclude biotechnological inventions from the subject matter of UMs, such as France and Denmark. In France, the patentability requirements and eligible subject matter are the same for UMs as for patents (see Chapter 5). What applies to patents in terms of biotechnological inventions, would thus generally be understood similarly for UMs. There are repercussions to the relevance of the Biotech Directive, such as some role for the CJEU as to what this instrument requires and inhibits within the Member States.
Another exclusion of note from the coverage of UMs is processes and methods (in general). This exclusion is adopted in, for example, Germany, Italy, Czechia and Denmark, whereas countries such as France and Austria allow it. This has ramifications for any potential overlap allowed between patents and UMs.Footnote 50 Under the EPO, the protection afforded by a process patent also covers the direct resulting product, as long as the product itself is also patentable and meets the requirements. Particularly, there is a whole range of inventions for which the line between process and product has arguably blurred, for example, product-by-process claims. Additionally, as explained on the EPO’s website, “[f]or many inventions, claims in more than one category are needed for full protection.”Footnote 51 Decisions by the EPO’s bodies, including the Boards of Appeal, on the interpretation of concepts (also) relevant to process and use claims, as well as their validity, also have their bearing on UMs when subject to the same requirements and exclusions as patents in a given territory. As noted in Section 2.3, the EPC even contains some mandatory law applicable to UMs.Footnote 52
Importantly, these examples predate the UPC becoming operational and the creation of the UP. It underscores that UMs and patents were already subject to a fragmented field of legal instruments and authorities even before the addition of the unitary patent and UPC. The chosen construct, of the EPO as the granting authority and the UPC as the main judicial authority, with the latter bound by EU law and thus the CJEU’s decisions, alongside (and interacting with) pre-existing systems of granting and adjudicating pre-UPC categories of patent rights (including national rights), adds to that. Again, it is difficult to predict how this will affect the proprietors of patents and UMs. It is arguable that it will not necessarily make navigating this field post-UPC that much harder for aspiring proprietors of UMs within their home jurisdictions. It may get more complicated when there is a cross-border element or there is a connection between UMs and certain categories of patents. The introduction of the UPC and UP have certainly made the legal fragmentation more complex.
To explore this, the following section will look at how the UPC will operate vis-á-vis other authorities, and the implications thereof for, amongst other things, (new) occupants of this already fragmented field. This section will first lay some of the groundwork to reflect upon connections between patents and UMs post-UPC, starting with a procedural perspective on the relationship between domestic courts and the UPC.
17.4 The Relationship between Domestic Courts and UPC Divisions
The relationship between the domestic courts in the EU and the UPC divisions heeds some further consideration given the partial overlap of competence and, more importantly, the exclusive competence of both courts over separate rights with potentially connected subject matter. More specifically, a brief closer look at their potential feedback loop is warranted. To this end, we will mostly leave UMs and patents aside for a moment to consider some of the practical aspects of the (indirect) working relationship between these different judicial bodies on a more abstract level. This is important to show the potential influence of the UPC, even on matters not directly within the UPC’s jurisdiction. Hence, Section 17.4.1 will focus on staying the proceedings and judicial dialogue, and Section 17.4.2 will contemplate the driving force of these courts to develop legal doctrine.
17.4.1 The Working Relationship
First, there is the possibility for both types of courts to stay their proceedings to await and consider the other’s decision. The RoP offers a number of grounds upon which a UPC division may decide to stay its proceedings, some of which are mandatory or subject to additional requirements.Footnote 53 When it comes to proceedings on actions involving the same patent, SPC, or a related UM playing out before national authorities (including national courts), the RoP specify that the UPC may stay the proceedings.Footnote 54 The UPC has been awarded discretion in this respect and is not required to await the decisions of national courts to avoid any potential conflict in its decisions. However, in reference to opposition or limitation proceedings on a patent before a national court, the rule in question adds “where a decision in such proceedings may be expected to be given rapidly.”Footnote 55 This signals that if there is doubt about the speediness of such a decision, the UPC should actually refrain from staying the proceedings. The importance placed on expedient proceedings is also stressed in the Preamble of the RoP: “[…] proceedings shall be conducted in a way which will normally allow the final oral hearing on the issues of infringement and validity at first instance to take place within one year whilst recognising that complex actions may require more time[…].”Footnote 56 Evidently, this limits the UPC’s discretion in favour of preserving the speed of their own procedure.
Another aspect relevant here is that no official forum for dialogue appears to have been provided between national courts and UPC divisions that would allow for potential mitigation or avoidance of potential conflicts in judgments or misapplication of national law. The UPC is set to apply national law of the participating EU Member States, as the UP will be governed by the law of the Member State where the applicant had its residence or principal place of business or, if inapplicable, had a place of business, on the date of filing.Footnote 57 Therefore, at the time of writing, each unitary patent is governed by the national law of one out of 18 EU Member States currently part of the unitary patent area. However, which UPC division has competence to hear a case depends on the type of claims brought by parties,Footnote 58 as well as on where the infringement occurred within the unitary territory or where defendants have their residence or (principal) place of business.Footnote 59 This means that a UPC division in Italy – where the infringement took place or the defendant resides – may have to decide a dispute on a unitary patent governed by Belgian law – the place of residence or business of the proprietor. What is more, there may be connected proceedings in a normal domestic court at the same time.
While there are certainly some mitigating factors (which will be considered below), there is some concern about the consistency and accuracy of the interpretation and application of all the different sets of national laws by judges not always familiar with them, particularly in the early days of the UPC. Moreover, the UPC judges will have to navigate the development of doctrine and (potentially connected) judgments in normal domestic courts and the EPOrg’s Board of Appeals, as well as to observe EU law.Footnote 60 A forum for dialogue on national law – especially in the early years of the UPC’s operation – may have been useful to ensure uniformity and legal certainty and avoid potential conflicts between the UPC’s and domestic judgments. This is especially true considering that UPC divisions may have to apply national law foreign to them. Still, there are annual conferences which provide for a more informal forum at which judges can exchange insights.Footnote 61 Such forums were already popular pre-UPC, so these may continue to aid judges with the laws of different jurisdictions in this respect. Furthermore, many UPC judges are likely to maintain a domestic judicial position part time until the case load picks up enough to require their UPC appointment to be fulfilled full time, which may not ever occur for some divisions. Such judges will thus continue to be involved in the development of domestic case law and generally be more aware of local pending cases. Another apt mitigating factor is that all of the UPC divisions have a multinational composition, meaning that each division will represent a perspective broader than a single national judicial experience. Other than such informal avenues, the UPC and “normal” domestic courts may be expected to talk to each other largely through their judgments.
17.4.2 Driving the Doctrine
Presumably, it will take some time for the new UPC and domestic courts to sort out their working relationship. It will also be interesting to see how the feedback loop develops and evolves between the national courts and the UPC, given the division of jurisdiction over different categories of patents, SPCs and UMs. However, this is further complicated as key matters for patent enforcement are spread out over several instruments of varied origin and impact. As noted in Section 17.3.2, some EU or international instruments may also be applicable to some extent to national UMs. National law, the UPReg (an EU regulation) and the UPCA (an intergovernmental treaty) all – in varying degrees – contain some substantive patent law, in addition to the EPC’s provisions on matters such as inventiveness, sufficiency of disclosure and equivalence.
The rights conferred by the unitary patent and exceptions were dealt with in earlier drafts of the UPReg (Articles 6–8) but were ultimately moved to the UPCA.Footnote 62 According to the UPReg, national law determines the scope of protection in terms of the acts against which the UP protects, the limitations of the right and the exceptions available.Footnote 63 However, the UPCA also contains provisions which set forth acts of direct and indirect infringement, thereby creating two competing sources of law on the same matter. This is yet another example of the created confusion emanating from the chosen manner for introducing this new layer for a new patent and court system. As the UP is supposed to be governed by the law of a single Member State throughout the unitary patent area by virtue of an EU regulation, combined with the consideration that the UPC is bound by EU law, national law should presumably have priority here.Footnote 64 This invites the interpretation that, at least on this specific matter, the UPCA should be understood as the boundary within which to interpret and apply national law. This also seems likely considering the objective behind this project is to further European harmonisation towards an EU patent system. If this interpretation is correct, this emphasis on national law bestows a bigger role on domestic courts in driving the doctrine, both nationally and for the UPC to apply. Naturally, national courts are the judicial authorities on the interpretation and application of their respective national legal systems. However, the exact reliance on, and weight given to, these transnational instruments, particularly in relation to national law, is another aspect that will become clearer over time through the UPC’s case law.
Regardless of the ultimate interaction and priority between these sources of patent law, some thought needs to be given to the impact that the decisions of UPC divisions will have in general. If the system proves successful, the UPC divisions will undoubtedly help develop the national system further and help evolve judicial doctrine, particularly states’ local or regional divisions. What is more, this will inevitably lead to national patent systems moving closer to each other. Furthermore, the UPC will be capable of gaining a lot of experience within its field of specialisation in a short period of time thanks to the combined effect of its mandate and territorial reach, and the potential counterbalancing influence it may have as a result on the EPOrg’s strong executive and administrative arms.Footnote 65 There is some reasonable expectation that the UPC, created by an intergovernmental treaty between some EU Member States and an even smaller portion of EPOrg members, will have greater ramifications for the EPC system. Due to the UPC’s competence to review the validity of rights granted by the EPO for a larger geographical area, this court may interfere with the EPO on granting matters. This means that the UPC’s decisions may quickly gain a lot of weight in the European patent arena, irrespective of which law it applies. The broader reach of the UPC’s decisions makes for a stronger impact on the stability of both national and European patent law, as well as related areas of law. That also has its downside, as the broader reach of the UPC’s decisions may increase the impact of conflicting decisions on the same or overlapping subject matter by the UPC and national courts, and misinterpretation and/or misapplication of national law by UPC divisions. Naturally, conflicting decisions issued by judges from different states occurred frequently pre-UPC, but these judges only decide for their respective territory;Footnote 66 the UPC’s decision will have effect for the combined territory of states designated for a EP within the unitary patent area, be it a portion or the entirety of this area. This means the consequences thereof are more serious across the board, not just for the parties to the dispute, but also for specific third-party interests or the public interest at large or, on a more abstract level, the stability and consistency of national or regional legal systems.
With regard to the latter, patent disputes are generally not isolated from other areas of law. Obvious examples of such areas are civil procedure, domestic contract law, and competition law, but also the different UM systems provided for by some of the participating countries. Naturally, the UPC cannot directly rule on UMs since such rights have not been placed within its jurisdiction. However, as discussed in this and the previous subsection, the potential of the UPC’s (indirect) influence in Europe should not be underestimated. As will be discussed in the coming sections, there are strategies which were used by companies prior to the UPC that involved both patents and UMs, for example, branched-off UMs. Moreover, the UPReg has allowed for the possibility of double patenting in states where the law permits this. If disputes involving patents using such strategies make it before the UPC, the UPC’s decisions could directly affect national rights and indirectly impact national legal doctrines in this particular field. This will be explored further in the next section.
17.5 Converting, Double Patenting and Branching Off (BOUM)
Again, while it is not possible within the scope of this research and the instruments at our disposal to say something more meaningful about the exact impact and likelihood, it is possible to observe where the new system may limit or enhance the potential of pre-UPC strategies combining different types of patent rights. The analyses in the next subsection will thus first focus on pre-existing conversion and BOUM strategies, followed by a subsection on the room for double patenting and branched-off UMs strategies post-UPC, and last, by a third subsection which briefly considers the costs of a UP, particularly given territorial limitations.
17.5.1 Reasons for Converting Patents into UMs or for Branching Them Off (Pre-UPC)
In addition to offering the possibility of seeking UM protection from the start, many countries allow the conversion of a patent application into a UM application. If a patent application has a very low chance of being granted, for example, due to prior art that is close to the claimed invention, converting the patent application into a UM might offer an attractive option. However, in some countries there is a time limit for doing so.Footnote 67 If a patent application is refused, some countries allow the patent application to be converted into a UM within a certain period after the refusal.Footnote 68
Moreover, in some countries, such as Germany and Denmark,Footnote 69 UMs can be branched off (also called “split off”) from a pending international, European or national patent application by claiming the filing date or priority date of the first filing. A branch-off is possible in Germany, for example, until up to two months after granting a patent or withdrawing or rejecting the patent application.Footnote 70
In light of these procedural options, several – often interrelated – factors may make UMs an attractive strategic option for small and medium-sized entities (SMEs), as well as larger institutions or companies.Footnote 71 For example, UMs usually have a faster registration process compared to the lengthy patent prosecution procedures. This can be a huge advantage in fast-paced industries, such as software or telecommunications, where swift market approval and product adoption is critical. By converting a patent into a UM or branching it off as a separate UM, inventors can expedite the registration process and secure faster protection for their inventions.Footnote 72 In terms of strategic timing, a German branched-off UM is also well suited to stop infringement activities during grant proceedings in Germany.Footnote 73
Moreover, cost-effectiveness is an important consideration for many stakeholders, and in particular for SMEs. UMs are generally less expensive to register and to maintain compared to national and European patents.Footnote 74 Obtaining UM protection instead of a patent may be the preferred option when a patent is not generating – or expected to generate – any more substantial revenue. This is particularly relevant when the cost of maintaining a patent outweighs its economic benefits. The same reasoning applies to branch-offs: a German branched-off UM, for example, is an alternative to a costly divisional application.Footnote 75
The limited lifespan of UMs, which typically ranges from 6 to 10 years, can also entail strategic benefits, for example, in fast-paced technologies with shorter commercial lifespans. In some fast-moving and highly dynamic industries, such as in software, energy storage or telecommunications, converting a patent into a UM or branching it off as a UM allows the inventor to align the duration of protection with the expected commercial viability of the invention. In such cases the cost-benefit ratio of UM protection is more beneficial and attractive in comparison to patents, which typically have a longer lifespan, usually 20 years from the filing date.
Furthermore, regional considerations and IP strategies will also be considered by inventors. Seeking UM protection can be particularly beneficial when aiming to expand the protection of an invention in a specific market, while seeking to reduce the costs and time that would need to be spent when filing separate patent applications in multiple jurisdictions.Footnote 76 Even under the new UP system, patent laws and regulations will continue to differ across various jurisdictions. For example, an inventor might prefer UM protection for the aforementioned reasons, but also hold patents in countries without any available UM protection, such as the United Kingdom or Sweden. If that patentee prefers to protect the invention as a UM in another country where UMs are recognised, such as Germany, converting the patent into a UM or branching it off as a UM can provide a cost-effective local protection in that jurisdiction.
Last, but not least, the scope of protection is another important consideration that might motivate stakeholders to pursue UM protection instead of – or in addition to – patents. In many innovative technologies, UMs typically provide narrower protection compared to patents. By converting the patent into a UM or branching it off as a UM, inventors can obtain additional protection for those specific features or improvements of an invention that are not covered by the existing patent claims.Footnote 77 Provided that such features are not automatically excluded from UM protection, which can be the case in some areas of health and life science inventions, such strategies can be particularly useful when there are incremental improvements or variations with a considerable commercial value that may not meet the more restrictive novelty or inventive step thresholds for a patent.
Before the UPC system became operational, the possibility to simultaneously apply for and convert a UM, a national patent, and/or a EP – now with or without unitary effect – was thus already widely available. There is nothing to suggest that such opportunities would cease post-UPC. Indeed, the expected dominance of German law for governing UPs would make this very likely to subsist as a common business strategy, as their system for branched-off UMs appears to be thriving.Footnote 78 This will be further explored in the next section, focusing predominantly on the possibility for double patenting post-UPC.
17.5.2 National Examples of Double Patenting within the Unitary Patent Area
The UPReg specifically addresses the possibility of double patenting. Article 4, second paragraph, requires that
[t]he participating Member States shall take the necessary measures to ensure that, where the unitary effect of a European patent has been registered and extends to their territory, that European patent is deemed not to have taken effect as a national patent in their territory on the date of publication of the mention of the grant in the European Patent Bulletin.
This is similarly stressed in Recital 8, last sentence, of the UPReg for national patents when an EP is granted. Put simply, it inhibits double patenting. Since the possibility of the simultaneous protection by a UM is not mentioned, this possibility may arguably depend on the existence of a national law preclusion.
However, this prohibition on double patenting is undercut by Recital 26 of the same instrument, which provides that this does not affect “the right of the participating Member States to grant national patents and should not replace the participating Member States’ laws on patents.” This suggests that, if a state allows for double patenting (e.g., the same matter protected by both a national patent and a EP), this should remain possible. This interpretation, that Recital 26 allows for double patenting, is one settled upon by important patent jurisdictions in Europe such as Germany, France and Italy, which have all amended their laws to this effect after the adoption of the UPReg. Their systems are discussed elsewhere in this volume in more detail, but it is useful to mention these specific changes briefly to consider their implications for the UPC-context.
Specifically, Germany technically allowed for some form of double patenting previously, as it was possible to maintain a national patent and EP on the same invention in Germany.Footnote 79 However, Article II, section 8, of the German Act on International Patent Conventions (“Gesetz über internationale Patentübereinkommen”Footnote 80) undercut the usefulness of maintaining the national patent. It provided that a defendant against which the patent was asserted in court proceedings could object to its effect because it was already covered in Germany by a EP. As for France, before 2018, a French patent would lose its effect upon conclusion of opposition proceedings or after the expiration of the period to initiate such proceedings.Footnote 81 The same was true in Italy. All three countries have amended their respective patent laws to allow for some form of double patenting, but there is a striking difference in the Italian approach.
First, the undercutting German provision has been amended in 2017 – so after the UPReg was adopted – for the “no-effect” limitation to only apply to a EP valid in Germany for which its proprietor has successfully opted out of the UPC’s jurisdiction.Footnote 82 Put differently, it means that defendants would no longer be able to challenge the national patent’s effect when it is covered by a corresponding UP or EP valid in Germany falling within the UPC’s jurisdiction. France has essentially done the same in response to the UPReg with their 2018 amendment.Footnote 83 A French national patent will only lose its effect if it concerns a corresponding EP valid in France for which the proprietor has chosen to opt-out of the jurisdiction of the UPC. The result is that there is a possibility for double patenting in cases where there is a clear separation of jurisdiction between the “normal” German/French domestic courts and UPC divisions.
Interestingly, the same applies to the Italian national patent, but without a very important caveat: it has been reported by several sources that the Italian version does not limit this possibility for double patenting in case of EPs in Italy to those instances of a successful opt-out.Footnote 84 This means that non-opted-out European patents could co-exist with Italian national patents, resulting in a shared competence between UPC divisions and “normal” Italian domestic courts on – albeit it being different types of – patents with the same subject matter. It would seem that, so far, the Italian legislator has not yet provided any mechanisms or limitations for the domestic courts in case of parallel proceedings on the same subject matter before the UPC.
Whether businesses will make use of these new avenues for double patenting that some states have created in response to the UPCA remains to be seen. Businesses will presumably continue to base their patenting and UM strategies in Europe on, inter alia, which markets are most important to them, the costs of applying for and maintaining such rights in a given jurisdiction, and where enforcement mechanisms are most attainable and effective. Over the years, this has led to a shift in focus from applications for national patents at national patent offices to designating the states of choice through an application at the EPO. Now, businesses can opt to apply at the EPO for a UP instead, meaning that, if granted, the UP is valid in all states part of the unitary patent area. For businesses, the potential of combining an EP or UP with a national patent (or UM) within the same territory will hinge on whether the national right would likely form a substantial asset on top.
17.5.3 The Cost of the Unitary Patent Area: A Boost for Other Rights?
It is prudent to explore next when a UP might be an attractive alternative to pre-existing options, and under what circumstances it may make national patents or UMs more advantageous for (aspiring) right holders, be it as a supplement or an alternative. Cost is one of the key factors for deciding whether or not to apply for a UP instead of opting for pre-existing patenting or UM strategies. Cost-saving and procedural streamlining were important factors for the uptick in applications for the EP at the expense of national patents. Lower cost and ease are also cited by proponents of UMs, irrespective of whether this is demonstrated to be the case in practice.Footnote 85 One of the key objectives stressed in favour of the UP is also cost-saving. A closer look at the cost of opting for a UP is thus warranted. This section will briefly explore this issue based on the application and renewal costs of a UP, and relevant territorial limitations.
Generally, applying for a UP and maintaining it is less costly than applying for a EP designating all states that are part of the unitary patent area. According to the EPO’s website, the annual fees for the entire area “[correspond] to the combined renewal fees due in the four countries where European patents were most often validated in 2015, when the fee level was agreed by the Select Committee.”Footnote 86 Consequently, the UP could make for a cost-effective option should a business be interested in obtaining a patent in those particular four states or, alternatively, if interested in a selection of countries within the unitary patent area that would amount to the same total of renewal fees or surpass it. However, if this is not the case, the UP may cost more than the traditional routes. Notably, even if a business were interested in obtaining protection in those four states that are part of the unitary patent area or, alternatively, if interested in a selection of countries within the unitary patent area that would amount to the same total of renewal fees or surpass it, the cost of obtaining a UP may be infeasible for many businesses.
For some businesses, it may be more cost-effective to opt for a more selective approach in designating states for a EP or national rights, or a combination thereof. This is especially true when additional rights would have to be obtained by a business for jurisdictions of note outside of the unitary patent area. As discussed in Section 17.2.1, there are currently six EU Member States which are not yet part of the unitary patent area. That means that businesses from those states would automatically lose out on the possibility to have a UP covering their home state. The same is true for businesses originating from the other 12 states which are part of the EPO, but not members of the EU. Obtaining additional protection outside of the unitary patent area would amount to an additional set of costs, on top of those for the UP.
This may be a more potent issue than just the omission of the home state, as one key patent jurisdiction in Europe is not part of the unitary patent area as a result of BREXIT, namely the United Kingdom. If there is need and/or value in obtaining a patent in the United Kingdom, this must be done separately from the application for a UP, or via its designation in an application for a EP. As a result, obtaining a UP may prove to be too costly for a lot of businesses, even without factoring in other aspects such as the risk of invalidation for a larger territory or, conversely, the rewards of enforcement in this larger territory.
This may affect business strategies towards patents and UMs, both within and outside this area, but this is not a given. For many businesses, the UP may simply be too costly or not attractive for other reasons. They will presumably continue to rely on pre-UPC strategies encompassing EPs, national patents or UMs, or a combination thereof (e.g., BOUM). The only additional considerations for such companies are whether or not to make use of the more recent room for double patenting created in some jurisdictions, and whether opting out of the UPC’s jurisdiction is a relevant and desirable option (and if/when to opt back in).
Businesses for which a UP is worthwhile and feasible would need to determine whether additional protection outside of the unitary patent area is necessary and cost-effective. Because obtaining a UP is already quite pricy, for those jurisdictions important to a company’s business falling outside of this territory, a UM may be an interesting alternative if it provides for equivalent protection to patents. However, if a business can afford a UP and a jurisdiction outside of the unitary patent area really is an important market, this may still move a business to apply for a patent instead. Yet, there may still be companies which may abandon any efforts towards additional protection in Europe outside of the unitary patent area. It remains, for example, to be seen whether the United Kingdom is able to retain its notable importance in the European patent area, that is, what number of applicants for UPs will make a separate application for this jurisdiction, or whether this will affect whether aspiring patentees will choose a UP over an EP.
Be that as it may, many more questions on the potential relationship of the UPC with UMs remain open. The next section will discuss some of the implications of the more important factors that we have considered so far, along with the limits of what can be concluded and some more food for thought. More specifically, it considers all the previously discussed factors and other grounds bearing on the decision on whether or not to opt out of the UPC system, before circling back to when UMs are a good alternative or addition to the IP strategy.
17.6 Discussion of Findings and Stakeholder Choices
Patent protection has always been at the top of the agenda in the EU to achieve a fully harmonised IP system, whereas an EU-wide approach to UM protection became a subordinated goal. Now, with the UPC having become operational on 1 June 2023, European patent law has been subject to a regime-change involving a new transnational institution and an unusual combination of EU and transnational law outside the scope of traditional EU harmonisation. Yet, as we have explored in the previous sections, the chosen route towards a harmonised patent in the EU is not without its complications for the European patent arena, nor for UMs. A lot of literature has already been dedicated to such complications on different aspects and types of patents, but the implications for UMs are generally overlooked. How this long-awaited achievement will impact UMs remains to be seen, but the establishment of the UPC and UPs necessitates reflections on UM protection as such. On this background, we have asked if the troublesome way to a transnational regime has left the protection of UMs behind. Based on our explorations in the previous sections, this section will highlight some of the implications for inventors and companies.
To reiterate, our starting point is that UM protection is a national matter only, but for several reasons it can be linked to either an EP, SPC (European, EU or otherwise) or to a UP. As we have discussed in Section 17.2, the unitary patent area (18 Member States) overlaps with UM systems in 11 EU Member States. The granting of EPs and UPs are subject to EPO’s authority, and the granting of UMs and national patents are subject to national authority. In a current Commission proposal on a Regulation on SPC’s it is suggested that the (new) unitary SPC’s are to be granted by the national authorities with the EUIPO as the central examination authority.Footnote 87 Thus, stakeholders will then have to involve three different authorities to protect and arrange for a broader IP portfolio, let alone consider the territorial implications and the interplay of different types and sources of law that may have their bearing on (parts of) their portfolio.
Then there is the matter of authorities in the post-granting phase. It is mostly the establishment of the UPC as a transnational patent court which we expect to have an impact on the future UM landscape in Europe. If a UP is declared void by the UPC, such a ruling may have spill-over effects on (connected) UMs in one or more of the 11 UPC participating Member States with UM systems. What is more is that the decision may have an impact on the non-participating UPC Member States who have UM protection as well. Domestic courts within those jurisdictions are not in any way bound to follow the UPC’s decisions relevant to disputes pertaining to their own jurisdiction, particularly when it comes to national rights such as UMs. There is the additional aspect of meaningful legislative differences in their national UM model to patents that may warrant a different approach or outcome, even if the normal domestic court considers the UPC’s findings. However, as we have argued, there are several reasons not to underestimate the UPC’s authority and territorial reach. If the UPC succeeds, its harmonising force is likely to affect EU Member States currently not part of the unitary patent area. That may not be on the forefront for all companies when planning their IP strategies, but the decision of whether or not to choose a route which would lead to the involvement of the UPC has to be made early on in most cases.
That said, when considering the uncertainties and risks associated with interpreting Article 83 of the UPCA and its subsections (1), (3) and (4) on opting out, it is challenging to determine the best course of action. This concerns in particular the benefits and risks of opting out. Each option has its own strengths, weaknesses, opportunities and threats. The suitability of each approach must be evaluated on a case-by-case basis, taking into account the invention, patent claims and business strategy.Footnote 88 And this will also have to include the consideration of opting for UM protection, i.e., either from the start, by conversion or by “branching off.”
When it comes to the “opt-out” question for European patents, two basic criteria should be carefully considered when making strategic decisions for relevant portfolios. First, the strength of the patent(s) and their enforceability in infringement and invalidation proceedings should be evaluated. Second, estimating the importance of the patent(s) to the relevant business and technology is also crucial. In general, the larger the patent portfolio, the more difficult it becomes to find a clear solution to minimize risks. The strategies that need to be employed become more complex.Footnote 89 It is crucial to remain in control and anticipate potential actions by licensees, infringers or as a claimant. Additionally, future filing strategies should be anticipated, tailored and diversified. In specific cases concerning EP applications, this may involve considering the use of divisionals or branching off UM protection in different systems. If available, UM protection can be useful for establishing priority for future patent applications.Footnote 90
If the patent claims are strong and enforceable, it might generally be advisable not to opt out, convert claims into UM or branch off during the transitional period to take full advantage of the benefits and choices offered by the new system. The higher the likelihood that an important and strong patent will be upheld within the UPC system, the less reason there is to pay significant opt-out fees and risk competitors initiating national proceedings, which would eliminate the option to “withdraw the opt-out” under Article 83(4) of the UPCA and proceed at the UPC. However, if a patent is very important but includes claims that are at high risk of not surviving a central challenge within the UPC system, opting out, converting it into a UM or branching off certain claims as UMs to defend them on a country-by-country basis may make sense. In other words, opting out or UM protection could be helpful to avoid the risk of the patent being invalidated in one proceeding across Europe.Footnote 91 If a patent is not very relevant, however, spending money on a substantial opt-out fee might not make any sense. Patent holders should consider letting it expire, or converting it into a UM, which is also cheaper to maintain.Footnote 92
17.7 Concluding Remarks and Open Questions
Given the pre-UPC fragmentation of the law and institutions for patents and UMs, the attempt towards harmonisation in the former field is, on its face, progress. Since the latter was not included, this raised the question how the UPC will interact with and affect the system for UM protection in Europe and vice versa. The progress towards establishing a unified patent system in the EU has (almost) achieved its first objectives, but what the impact on UM protection and their strategic use will be remains to be seen. As our chapter has demonstrated, the direct consequences and wider implications of the latest UPC and UP developments raise numerous questions, not only about the interplay between the patent system and UM protection, but also on the role of UMs in today’s innovation systems and their underlying rationales as such. Given this backdrop, it is pertinent to question whether the arduous journey towards harmonising IPR in the EU has overlooked the protection of UMs.
In this chapter, we have outlined some of the forthcoming considerations that the IP system is likely to confront with regards to UMs in Europe. The fragmentation in European patent law and UMs is exacerbated by the introduction of the UPC and UP, an odd repercussion for an (at least partially successful) attempt at harmonisation. In the coming years, it will be important to monitor the implications of this and, if necessary, to mitigate them. However, too little is currently known to make recommendations on this. In fact, it is clear that much more research is necessary on both the value of legal harmonisation in the IP space in general,Footnote 93 and on the benefits and drawbacks of European UMs in a highly competitive global economy, in particular.Footnote 94 Ultimately, this also entails the question whether the distinct European national frameworks for UM protection should be harmonised and introduced into the legislative system of all EU Member States by EU legislation, or if the European IP and innovation landscape would be best served and “harmonised” simply by getting rid of UM protection. Both may simplify matters, both may make them worse. The empirical research on the value of UMs is not unequivocal. Moreover, there are EU Member States in which the system is quite widely used, and taking away rights – particularly types of property rights – is tricky, to say the least.
Unfortunately, tackling this provocative question would also mean that we would have to confront an elusive and technology-specific “elephant in the room,” which is still extraordinarily difficult to study: the strategic use of trade secrets as an alternative. There is always the consideration that, if some form of protection is not offered, businesses may resort to secrecy instead. Not all types of UMs would lend themselves to reliance on secrecy, such as those on improvements in the shape of a product. Such improvements may generally be unearthed by third parties without relative difficulty upon studying the product. Yet, in those jurisdictions where the UM takes on a more patent-like nature with the same eligible subject matter, this may indeed be a concern. Would we lose out on knowledge, on innovative progress, should we abandon UMs? If so, is it concerning enough to provide for UM protection? We are convinced that unpacking, analysing and understanding these intricate dynamics will be one of the more important research tasks of the future.
Utility models (UM) are not patents, yet in some cases they may be treated like patents. One such case is the declaration of UM as “essential” to industry standards such as Wi-Fi and 5G, and the attendant licensing of these UM to the manufacturers of standardized products on terms that are “fair, reasonable and nondiscriminatory” (FRAND) under the rules of the relevant standards-development organization (SDO). This chapter explores the prevalence and implications of declaring and licensing UMs as standards-essential patents.
18.1 Standards-Essential Patents and Utility Models
18.1.1 FRAND Licensing Commitments
Some technical standards, particularly in the telecommunications and computing sectors, can be covered by hundreds or thousands of patents.Footnote 1 Accordingly, SDOs often require their participants to disclose patents believed to be “essential” to the implementation of a standard (standards-essential patents, or SEPs) to other participants in the SDO prior to approval of the standard. This obligation is intended to allow SDO members to work around or avoid any patent that could unduly impair the broad adoption of the standard.Footnote 2 SDO participants that fail to disclose SEPs when so required by an SDO’s policies can be found to have breached the SDO’s policy or to have engaged in deceptive or anticompetitive conduct.Footnote 3
Furthermore, in order to promote broad adoption and use of their standards, most SDOs also require that participants license their SEPs to the manufacturers of standardized products (“implementers”) on terms that are either royalty free or bear royalties that are “fair, reasonable and non-discriminatory” (FRAND).Footnote 4 This obligation is intended to assure implementers that they will be able to incorporate widely adopted standards into their products without the threat of being sued by the holders of SEPs.
18.1.2 Essentiality
A SEP holder’s obligations to disclose and grant licenses generally applies only to patents that are “essential” to the implementation of the standard. That is, a product implementing the standard will necessarily infringe the claims of the patent.Footnote 5 Despite the importance of the concept of essentiality to the value of patents covering standardized products, the essentiality of a particular patent to a particular standard is usually determined unilaterally by the patent holder without external verification.Footnote 6 Yet this decision is often made with incomplete information at a time when the patent in question may still be in prosecution and the standard is not yet finalized.Footnote 7 As such, the declaration of a patent as a SEP often constitutes a best guess by the SEP holder as to the likely essentiality of an issued patent, or a patent application, to a draft or published standard.
Not surprisingly, given the potential royalty revenue that may be earned from SEPs, and the potential liability that can arise under the antitrust and competition laws from the failure to disclose SEPs in compliance with an SDO’s policies, SDO participants have often erred on the side of over-declaration of SEPs in relation to many standards.Footnote 8 For this reason, the essentiality of declared SEPs to particular standards is frequently challenged in litigation, with the result that some patents asserted against products implementing standards as to which they were declared essential are found to be neither essential to the standard nor infringed by the product implementing the standard.Footnote 9
18.1.3 Injunctive Relief and SEPs
One of the typical remedies available to a patent holder upon proving infringement is a court-ordered injunction preventing the infringer from continuing to make or sell infringing products. The availability of injunctions when SEPs are infringed has been the subject of considerable debate, as the general availability of the injunction remedy can be seen to conflict with the SEP holder’s commitment to grant licenses to all implementers of the standards covered by the SEPs.Footnote 10 As a result, the availability of injunctive relief when SEPs are infringed by an unlicensed implementer varies by country, and may depend on applicable competition law as well as a determination whether the infringing implementer is “willing” to accept a license on FRAND terms.Footnote 11
18.1.4 Utility Models as Standards-Essential
In addition to patents, some SDO policies require SDO participants to disclose UMs as potentially essential to implement their standards. This requirement is made explicit, for example, in the Guidelines for Implementation of the Common Patent Policy of the International Telecommunications Union (ITU), International Organization for Standardization (ISO) and International Electrotechnical Committee (IEC), which defines a “patent” as including “those claims contained in and identified by patents, utility models and other similar statutory rights based on inventions (including applications for any of these)”.Footnote 12 Other prominent SDOs, including the European Telecommunications Standards Institute (ETSI), the Internet Engineering Task Force (IETF) and the HDMI Forum, also expressly require the disclosure or licensing of UMs that are believed to be essential to a standard.Footnote 13
While the policies of some SDOs expressly mention UMs, the policies of other SDOs, including ATSCFootnote 14 and JEDEC,Footnote 15 do not, and instead apply their disclosure and licensing requirements only to “patents”. At these SDOs, it is not clear what effect the disclosure of a UM under the SDO’s disclosure or licensing policies would have, and whether the FRAND or other licensing commitments of the SDO apply to UMs. Conversely, it is not clear whether an SDO participant’s failure to disclose a UM would constitute a violation of such an SDO’s disclosure policy or deceptive conduct that is otherwise actionable. The implications of this definitional gap are considered more fully in Section 18.3.1.
And while commentators have casually observed that UMs have infrequently been disclosed as essential to technical standards,Footnote 16 there has not, until this study, been an empirical assessment of the rate at which UMs are declared to be essential. With the caveat that, just as with patents, a declaration to an SDO that a UM is believed to be essential to the implementation of particular standard is not an assurance that the UM will ultimately be found to be essential, this chapter refers to such declared UMs as “standards-essential utility models” (SEUMs).
18.2 Findings: Standards-Essential Utility Models
18.2.1 Methodology
This study utilized data on UM filings around the world provided by the World Intellectual Property Organization (WIPO)Footnote 17 as well as the IPLytics platform (now a part of Lexis-Nexis).Footnote 18 As an official United Nations organization, WIPO makes available filing data from the patent offices of its 193 member states.Footnote 19 The IPLytics database includes patent and UM filing data from 98 national and regional patent offices.Footnote 20 IPLytics also contains SEP declarations made at 35 different SDOs and 11 patent pools, including disambiguated information regarding SEP declarants, as well as information (sourced from Darts IP) concerning SEPs that have been litigated.Footnote 21 These databases were queried between March and May 2023. Separately, detailed information regarding litigated SEUMs was sourced from Darts IP.
18.2.2 Findings: Standards Essential Utility Models (SEUMs)
18.2.2.1 Technical Content of SEUMs
As discussed elsewhere in the volume, UMs may cover anything from very simple mechanical designs to complex technological systems. In the case of SEUMs, the technical complexity of claimed inventions tends toward the more complex, given that most standardization activity in which patents and UM are filed occurs in the information and communications technology (ICT) sector in which products are largely electronic and software-based. As a result, the technical descriptions and claims contained in most SEUM documents are largely indistinguishable from those contained in patent documents.
18.2.2.2 SEUM Declarations
In considering SEUMs, it is important to recall that a single UM (like a single patent) may be declared as potentially essential to different standards and different versions of the same standard.Footnote 22 Thus, when considering standards-essential patents (SEPs), from 1990 to 2022, approximately 5.9 million individual SEP declarations have been made across all SDOs tracked by IPLytics, covering approximately 500,000 unique patents (counted by declaration year). The number of SEUMs is far lower. During the same period, approximately 7,700 SEUM declarations corresponding to 947 unique UMs were identified, representing approximately 0.2 percent of all SEP declarations.
Figure 18.1 shows total SEUMs by year of UM issuance and year of first declaration. Declarations can be made years after a patent is issued (e.g., in response to a “call for patents” made when a draft standard is submitted to the SDO for approvalFootnote 23), explaining why declarations appear to be weighted toward later years. Yet as shown in Figure 18.1, there does not appear to be a discernable trend in SEUM declarations over time, either increasing or decreasing.
![](https://static.cambridge.org/binary/version/id/urn:cambridge.org:id:binary:20250103071022584-0229:9781009478113:47812fig18_1.png?pub-status=live)
Figure 18.1 SEUM filings by year
18.2.2.3 Geographic Distribution of SEUMs
A total of 946 SEUMs were declared across a total of fourteen jurisdictions between 1990 and 2022.Footnote 24 Data regarding each jurisdiction in which SEUMs were declared during this period, compared to overall UM filings and SEP declarations in these jurisdictions, is contained in Supplemental Data Table 2.
Figure 18.2 illustrates the distribution of SEUMs among jurisdictions, which varies significantly both from that of all UMs generally and that of all SEP declarations. First, the number of SEUMs is considerably lower than the total number of declared SEPs in those jurisdictions.Footnote 25 SEUMs make up the highest portion of SEPs in Germany (4.26 percent) and Taiwan (2.05 percent). This percentage approaches zero in most other jurisdictions, with six or fewer SEUMs declared in all but the top five jurisdictions.Footnote 26
![](https://static.cambridge.org/binary/version/id/urn:cambridge.org:id:binary:20250103071022584-0229:9781009478113:47812fig18_2.png?pub-status=live)
Figure 18.2 Share of SEUM declarations by jurisdiction, 1990–2022
Perhaps the most notable divergence among filing rates of SEUMs, SEPs and UMs within a jurisdiction can be seen in China, which has by far the greatest number of UMs worldwide (97.6 percent). While patents issued by China have been declared as SEPs more than patents issued by any other country in this study,Footnote 27 the total number of Chinese SEPs exceeds that of Japan and Korea by only a factor of two. Of Chinese SEPs, only 237 are SEUMs (0.32 percent), placing China behind both Germany and Taiwan in terms of SEUM declarations and behind Germany, Taiwan, Ukraine and France in terms of the percentage of UMs that are declared as SEUMs. Moreover, given China’s huge number of UMs (nearly 20 million), the percentage declared as SEUMs is vanishingly small. These results reinforce the notion that the Chinese UM system is largely oriented toward local manufacturing of simple products and not toward the type of sophisticated international technology development that occurs within SDOs. Nevertheless, Chinese UMs are still declared as SEUMs more than UMs from any countries other than Germany and Taiwan. Thus, even though representing a small percentage of China’s overall UM volume, the number of Chinese SEUMs is significant.
18.2.2.4 SEUM Declarants
Unlike ordinary UMs, which have applicants from a broad cross-section of industries and geographies, the majority of SEUM declarations have been made by a single firm: US-based Interdigital, which held 613 of a total 985 declared SEUMs (61 percent) from 1990 to 2022. Figure 18.3 shows the number of declared SEUMs held by declarants of ten or more SEUM during this period (with full data in Supplemental Data Table 3).
![](https://static.cambridge.org/binary/version/id/urn:cambridge.org:id:binary:20250103071022584-0229:9781009478113:47812fig18_3.png?pub-status=live)
Figure 18.3 Top SEUM declarants, 1990–2022
As shown in Figure 18.3, InterDigital, based in the US, has been the most prolific declarant of SEUMs by a wide margin. Yet InterDigital’s SEUM filing and declaration program is of largely historical interest. Representatives of InterDigital note that the company filed numerous UMs between March 2001 and January 2012, with the volume decreasing substantially beginning in 2009.Footnote 28 As of July 2023, InterDigital claims that it holds no active UMs.Footnote 29
In addition to InterDigital, the top eleven SEUM filers include two other US firms, Intel and Dolby Laboratories, despite the fact that the US does not itself have a UM system. This observation suggests that firms such as these operate strategically across borders, irrespective of the rights offered by their home jurisdictions.Footnote 30 The other top SEUM holders originate from Korea (Samsung and LG), China (ZTE, Huawei), Taiwan (HTC), Japan (Panasonic), Sweden (Ericsson) and Finland (Nokia). Each of these jurisdictions has a UM system.
Below the top eleven firms, 123 additional firms from a range of countries held between 1 and 7 SEUMs each, with a total of 173 SEUMs among them. This “long tail” suggests that, other than InterDigital during the early 2000s and, possibly, some of the other top SEUM filers, firms involved in standardization have not developed a concerted strategy of filing UMs or declaring SEUMs at SDOs, resulting in SEUM declarations that are for the most part sporadic and nonpurposive.
While the absolute number of SEUM declarations made by individual firms may allow conclusions to be drawn about firm strategy, additional insight can be gained by comparing SEUM declarations with SEP declarations made by these firms. Accordingly, Figure 18.4 compares the SEUM declarations made by the top SEUM declarants (excluding, for purposes of presentation, InterDigitalFootnote 31) with SEP declarations by those firms and other “top” SEP declarants, in each case based on the percentage that such firms’ declarations represent of all SEUM and SEP declarations.
![](https://static.cambridge.org/binary/version/id/urn:cambridge.org:id:binary:20250103071022584-0229:9781009478113:47812fig18_4.png?pub-status=live)
Figure 18.4 Comparison of SEP and SEUM declaration shares by Top SEUM declarants (excluding InterDigital), 1990–2022
Interestingly, there appears to be little correspondence between the percentage of SEP and SEUM declarations made by any given firm. Most striking is InterDigital (omitted from Figure 18.1 to delineate the shares of other firms more clearly), which declared 613 of 985 SEUMs (62 percent) but only 21,404 of 502,717 SEPs (4.3 percent). As shown in Figure 18.1, Samsung, Intel, Panasonic, Dolby and HTC follow a similar pattern, accounting for a much larger share of SEUM than SEP declarations. In contrast, firms such as Qualcomm, Huawei, LG, Nokia, Ericsson, Oppo, NTT Docomo, Sharp and Apple were responsible for a much larger share of SEP than SEUM declarations.
18.2.2.5 Jurisdictional Choices by SEUM Declarants
The jurisdictions in which SEUMs are issued does not correspond to the national origin of their declarants, nor follow any discernable pattern at all. Table 18.1 shows the countries in which declared SEUMs have been issued for the top five SEUM holders.
Perhaps the only general conclusion that can be drawn from Table 18.1 is that most large holders of SEUMs declared German SEUMs. Despite China’s significant share of all global UMs, only InterDigital and, to a lesser degree, Intel, have declared SEUMs issued in China.
Curiously, ZTE, a large Chinese handset manufacturer, has declared no SEUMs issued in China, but is the declarant of the only SEUMs issued by three smaller European jurisdictions (Denmark, Hungary and Finland). While Finland, the headquarters of Nokia, can potentially be explained for this reason, there is no obvious explanation for ZTE’s interest in Denmark or Hungary, and, again, this declaration pattern must be attributable to ZTE’s unique business objectives and strategies.
In short, these data reveal a highly idiosyncratic pattern of SEUM declaration across firms, which is likely driven by individual firm strategies.Footnote 32
18.2.2.6 SEUMs and SDOs
SEUMs have been declared across a variety of SDOs. Table 18.2 shows the SDOs at which SEUMs have been declared from 1999 to 2022 across the top five UM filing jurisdictions.
Not surprisingly, the “xG” series of wireless telecommunications standards developed under the aegis of ETSI, which are documented as having the largest number of SEP declarations,Footnote 33 also have the most SEUMs declared against them. Yet several other SDOs also have declared SEUMs. ATSC, ITU-T and JEDEC include declared SEUMs from each of the top 5 SEUM jurisdictions, while nine other SDOs have a handful of SEUM declarations.
Moreover, individual firms choose which SDOs to participate in based on their own product offerings and research programs. Thus, firms primarily engaged in wireless telecommunications and heavily involved in standardization at ETSI would not necessarily participate in JEDEC, which focuses on semiconductor memory devices.
18.2.3 SEUMs in the Judicial System
SEPs can give their owners significant leverage in the negotiation of licensing agreements, in part, because SEPs can be enforced in court against unlicensed implementers. Depending on the jurisdiction, a court may award a SEP holder that successfully enforces its SEP against an unlicensed implementer monetary damages and fee awards and may also enjoin the implementer from further manufacturing or selling standards-compliant products.Footnote 34 In recent years, there has been a significant amount of SEP- and FRAND-related litigation. One 2023 study commissioned by the European Commission identified more than 1,000 reported judicial decisions involving FRAND issues around the world between 2009 and 2021.Footnote 35 Another recent study found that in the US, disclosed SEPs are more than five times more likely than non-SEPs to be litigated.Footnote 36 Litigation of SEPs is thus a significant feature of the standards-setting environment.
In addition to enforcement litigation, the validity of SEPs can be challenged in judicial and administrative proceedings around the world (e.g., oppositions at the European Patent Office and inter partes review proceedings at the US Patent Trials and Appeal Board). We are unaware of statistics regarding the total number of such challenges, though Lemley and Simcoe recently studied validity rates of SEPs challenged in US litigation.Footnote 37
The frequency with which SEUMs are enforced or challenged in administrative proceedings (which, for the sake of convenience, we refer to as “litigated”), however, has not been studied. This section provides initial descriptive statistics concerning litigation and challenge of UMs and SEUMs.
18.2.3.1 Litigated Utility Models
From 2000 to 2022, we identified approximately 30,000 UMs that were the subject of judicial proceedings, including both administrative challenges and court litigation.Footnote 38 These figures do not include UMs that were subject to arbitration proceedings. As shown in Table 18.3, litigated UMs can be found across a wide range of jurisdictions, from large, developed economies to small and developing ones.
Table 18.3 Jurisdictions where utility models were litigated, 2000–2022
Consistent with its position as the leading jurisdiction in terms of overall UM filings, China is also the site of the greatest number of UMs subject to litigation (69.5 percent). This being said, this share is significantly lower than China’s share of overall UM filings during this period (95.6 percent). As such, China appears to have a somewhat lower rate of litigation than other jurisdictions.
Other jurisdictions in which large numbers of UMs are filed (i.e., Germany, Japan, Russia, Korea) also lead the rankings for litigated UMs. Nevertheless, there is a “long tail” of jurisdictions in which UMs are litigated but relatively few UMs have been issued. For example, Finland, with 79 litigated UMs, ranks 13th in terms of litigated UMs, but only 23rd in terms of overall UM filing during the period. Moreover, some jurisdictions that rank fairly high in terms of UM issuance (e.g., Australia, France, Philippines) have very little UM litigation, and Thailand, Mexico and Hong Kong, which ranked 11th, 17th, 19th, respectively, in terms of UM issuances during the period, had no reported UM litigation during the period.
A wide range of parties have been involved in UM litigation, with no individual party holding more than 0.2 percent of total UMs subject to litigation (either as the plaintiff or defendant). Of the 20 firms holding the largest number of UMs subject to litigation from 2000 to 2022 (ranging from 22 to 63 UMs), 3 were Taiwanese and 17 were Chinese. Even among the top 50 holders of litigated UMs, the large majority were Chinese (including Segway, the former US manufacturer of personal mobility devices, now a Chinese-held firm), together with a handful of Taiwanese and Japanese firms.
18.2.3.2 Litigated SEUMs
Unlike UMs more generally, IPLytics identified only 13 SEUMs that were involved in judicial or administrative proceedings around the world between 2000 and 2022: six in China and seven in Germany (Table 18.4).
Table 18.4 Litigated SEUMs, 2000–2022
Despite the low number of litigated SEUMs, Table 18.4 makes possible a few observations. First, as noted above, SEUMs are technical in nature, often indistinguishable in their specifications and claims from patents. This being said, upon a cursory inspection, at least two of the three SEUMs declared with respect to JEDEC standards appear to relate more to physical connections among electronic components than the internal functionality of those components (a more typical approach for UM). The SEUMs declared with respect to ETSI standards, however, appear highly technical in nature and are of a nature similar to other SEPs declared at ETSI.
Second, the large majority of these cases (92 percent) involved administrative validity challenges to SEUMs. In China, these were brought in the Reexamination and Invalidation Department of the China Patent Office, though three of the six challenges were appealed to the Chinese courts.
In Germany, these administrative challenges were brought at the Deutsches Patent und Markenamt (DPMA) (the German Patent and Trademark Office). Of the seven German SEUM cases identified, two involved both an administrative validity challenge at the DMPA and a judicial enforcement action (one in Düsseldorf and one in München), and one involved only an enforcement action (brought in München). All of the German administrative challenges appear to have been unsuccessful, as each of the challenged UMs is recorded as having expired at the natural end of its 10-year term (i.e., it was not prematurely canceled).
The three German enforcement actions were brought by IP Bridge, a patent assertion entity, and Netlist and Nokia, product-based companies that are active in patent enforcement.Footnote 39 Florian Mueller offers a first-hand report on the Netlist litigation, which involved prominent litigation counsel and sophisticated legal issues and was seemingly tied to related litigation in other jurisdictions.Footnote 40
18.2.4 Summary of Findings
The principal findings of this study can be summarized as follows:
1. Some, but not all, SDOs expressly permit or require the disclosure and licensing of UMs that are potentially essential to their standards. The requirements of SDO policies that do not expressly mention UMs are ambiguous.
2. Nearly 1,000 UMs (SEUMs) have been declared as essential to broadly adopted industry standards at ETSI and other prominent SDOs in the ICT sector.
3. Firm strategies appear to differ dramatically in terms of SEUM declaration, ranging from intensive to virtually no SEUM activity, even among firms of similar size and market focus.
4. Though far less than other SEPs, SEUMs have been subject to litigation multiple times in China and Germany, and there appears to be no structural barrier to their litigation in other jurisdictions.
18.3 Discussion
The findings of this study raise a number of implications for governmental policy, SDO operations and firm strategy, and also suggest numerous avenues for additional research.
18.3.1 SDO Policies and UMs: Is a UM a “Patent”?
One of the key questions raised about UMs is whether they should be considered to be “patents” for purposes of SDO policy requirements. While UMs are clearly distinct from patents under international IP treaties and the laws of countries with UM systems, the distinction may be less clear when viewed from outside those countries.Footnote 41 And, as noted in the Introduction, some jurisdictions refer to UMs as petty patents, innovation patents or registration patents,Footnote 42 implying that, at least in a broad definitional sense, they constitute a form of patent.
As discussed in Section 18.1.4, while some SDOs, such as ETSI and IETF, expressly require the disclosure and licensing of SEUMs in their IPR policies, other SDOs do not expressly include UMs within the scope of their patent disclosure and licensing commitments. Yet, as shown in Table 18.2, firms have nonetheless disclosed SEUMs to SDOs, such as JEDEC and ATSC, that fail to include UMs within their definitions of “patents”.
At these SDOs, the legal effect of such disclosures is not entirely clear. Would a UM declared as essential to a standard be treated in the same manner as a patent declared under that policy and thus be subject to the SDO’s FRAND licensing requirements? Or would the UM disclosure be disregarded as noncompliant with a policy that only permitted the disclosure of patents, and thus lack any legal effect?
The converse question also arises: if an SDO policy does not explicitly require the disclosure of UMs, then what obligation, if any, does the holder of an SEUM have to disclose and/or license that UM to implementers of the standard? Technically speaking, if UMs are not subject to an SDO’s FRAND licensing requirements, then an SEUM holder would be free to charge supra-FRAND royalties for its SEUMs, or to refuse to license them at all. Though one could argue that the nondisclosure or concealment of a UM would implicitly violate the spirit of the SDO’s disclosure and licensing policies, or even applicable competition law.Footnote 43
It is likely that the answers to these questions would depend on the specific understandings and intentions of the SDO members who drafted and approved the relevant policy,Footnote 44 and would thus be highly fact-specific (and vulnerable to differing recollections). In order to avoid these interpretive uncertainties, SDOs that have not expressly addressed the treatment of UMs under their disclosure and licensing policies (as well as any governmental policies relating to SEPs) would do well to do so.
18.3.2 Including SEUMs in SEP Databases
While some UMs are currently included in SDO-maintained databases of SEPs, it is sometimes difficult to distinguish SEUMs from ordinary SEPs in the relevant database entries.Footnote 45 Understanding this distinction could be useful for SDO participants and standards implementers, however, given the shorter duration of UMs and their different use in litigation. SDOs could do more to clarify the type of rights that are listed in their databases by clearly identifying which disclosed rights are SEUMs versus SEPs.
In addition to SDOs, the European Commission recently proposed legislation that, among other things, would create a new official registry and database for SEPs issued in the European Union.Footnote 46 Though early drafts of the proposal included utility models within the scope of the proposed regulation,Footnote 47 the current proposal does not contemplate UMs,Footnote 48 thereby omitting these potentially important rights. The reasons for this change have not been disclosed publicly by the Commission.Footnote 49 As one of us has previously noted in written comments submitted to the Commission, it should revise its proposed regulation to include European UMs along with patents or, at a minimum, reduce ambiguity by indicating why UMs were excluded from the proposal.
18.3.3 Enforcement of SEUMs
The potential overlapping coverage of patent and UM protection and the malleable nature of UM claims (including the ability, in countries such as Germany and Italy, to alter them during the course of litigation),Footnote 50 have led to their tactical use in infringement litigation. This degree of uncertainty is not likely to improve the clarity or predictability of the standardization ecosystem, particularly if individual firms begin to increase their declaration of UMs as SEUMs. While it appears that little short of national UM reform and/or harmonization can fully address these concerns (see Section 18.3.5), SDOs could eliminate at least some potential ambiguity by affirmatively including UMs within the scope of their disclosure and licensing requirements. Doing so would, at a minimum, reduce the likelihood that SEUMs could be used to obtain injunctions against the use of standards by implementers “willing” to obtain licenses of SEUMs on FRAND terms.
18.3.4 Essentiality of SEUMs
As discussed in Section 18.1.2, patents are defined as SEPs only if they are “essential” to the implementation of a standard, where essentiality exists if a product implementing the standard necessarily infringes the claims of the patent. The obligation to disclose SEPs (and, presumably, SEUMs) typically arises during development of a standard, prior to its approval and publication by the SDO. Yet UM claims may be more malleable after issuance than those of patents. This malleability raises questions concerning the potential essentiality of SEUMs, and the degree to which changes to claim scope can or should be taken into account when assessing the effect of FRAND commitments on UMs.
18.3.5 SEUMs and FRAND Royalties
If SEUMs are deemed to constitute SEPs under an SDO’s disclosure and licensing policies, SEUMs raise distinct but related questions regarding the calculation of FRAND royalties. First, given that UMs are generally not given substantive examination by relevant patent offices, their terms are shorter than those of patents and in some jurisdictions they lack direct enforceability, an argument could be made that UMs are, on average, less “valuable” than patents. As such, an argument could be made that the “fair and reasonable” royalty payable with respect to a SEUM should be less than the “fair and reasonable” royalty payable with respect to a SEP. By extension, the value of (and the FRAND royalty payable with respect to) a portfolio that includes SEUMs should be less than the value of a similarly sized portfolio that includes only SEPs. If SEUMs are not distinguished from SEPs when portfolios are valued, then incentives will exist for opportunistic firms to “stuff” their portfolios with cheap and easy-to-obtain SEUMs of questionable validity and essentiality in order to increase the size (and putative value) of those portfolios.
The issue of SEUM valuation has implications not only for transactions between individual holders of SEUMs and potential infringers, but for all holders of SEPs (and SEUMs) that are declared to be essential with respect to a particular standard. For example, when SEPs and SEUMs are placed into a pool for collective licensing to implementers of a standard, the royalty received from implementers is often distributed among pool members in proportion to the number of patents that they have licensed to the pool. The share of such royalties allocable to SEUMs, however, should arguably be lower than the share allocable to SEPs.
The same issue arises in connection with the “top-down” calculation of FRAND royalties payable with respect to a standard. Top-down royalty calculation methodologies seek to determine the overall value of a standard to a product, to use that value to assess an aggregate royalty for SEPs covering the standard, and then allocate a portion of the aggregate royalty to each holder of SEPs based on the number (and possibly the value) of its SEPs.Footnote 51 Top-down FRAND royalty calculations, which have already been utilized in judicial decisions in the US, UK and Japan may take on even greater prominence under a recent European Union proposal to implement a top-down calculation methodology in official calculations of aggregate SEP royalties.Footnote 52
If SEUMs are valued lower than other SEPs, then in such top-down royalty determinations, the presence of SEUMs should be a factor used in determining both the overall level of royalties payable with respect to a standard, as well as the share of such aggregate royalty that is allocated to different holders of SEPs and SEUMs.
18.3.6 Harmonization
Traditionally, UMs have existed largely as devices of national law with little harmonization among jurisdictions, even within closely knit regions such as the European Union. Yet the entry of UMs into the field of technical standardization, an inherently multinational arena, begs the question whether UM systems should be harmonized to a greater degree. That is, if UMs can effectively be utilized to expand individual firm portfolios of patents subject to FRAND licensing, then jurisdictions that make it easier to obtain UMs are likely to attract more UM filers, and perhaps to draw applicants away from their own, or other, patent systems (e.g., if a UM can be obtained for one fourth the cost of a patent, in one fourth the time, but yields a similar value, then UMs could quickly become preferred instruments in some markets). What’s more, fast and cheap UMs could result in a “race to the bottom” among jurisdictions seeking to capitalize on the “numbers game” among SEP holders. These considerations should encourage policy makers to consider more closely aligning UM systems across borders.
18.3.7 The Costs of Uncertainty Surrounding SEUMs
As noted above, UMs involve substantial uncertainty, both as to their coverage and enforceability, as well as their status (or not) as SEPs. This uncertainty can be utilized opportunistically by actors within the standardization ecosystem. For example, depending on the relevant SDO policy in effect, the holders of UMs may argue that UMs are excluded from the SDO’s FRAND disclosure or licensing commitments, thus giving them free rein to conceal these UMs from SDOs and implementers and to charge supra-FRAND royalties for the use of these rights. Likewise, UMs may be used tactically to seek injunctive relief against implementers before SEPs are issued. On the other hand, implementers that wish to delay negotiation over FRAND licenses (i.e., “holding out”) may raise the inherent uncertainty of UMs when negotiating such licenses. This uncertainty could thus destabilize the standardization system, imposing greater transactional costs on both UM holders and implementers, delaying the development of important new standards, imposing costs on consumers and depriving the market of new standardized products.
18.3.8 SEUMs and Innovation
UM systems were introduced in many jurisdictions to stimulate local innovation and industry via a low-cost pathway to intellectual property protection for modest or incremental designs not rising to the level of patentable invention. Yet our findings show that SEUMs are largely being filed and declared by major international firms with active patenting programs, and that these UMs often cover technologies that are, or could also be, covered by patents. To the extent that UMs are being used primarily to obtain duplicative coverage for the same technological innovations, or for tactical litigation advantage, they may not be achieving the goals for which they were originally designed. As a result, policy makers may wish to consider the findings of this study when evaluating the ongoing value of UM systems in their countries.
18.3.9 Areas for Further Research
There remains more to be studied with respect to UMs and the standardization ecosystem. One area for further research is an assessment of the “quality” of UMs that are declared as SEUMs, both in comparison to other UMs and to SEPs. The question of patent quality has attracted significant attention from scholars as well as governmental authorities in recent years, and numerous metrics for the measurement of patent quality have been developed (e.g., citation analysis). However, we are unaware of any significant study of UM quality or analysis on whether the same metrics applied to patents can be applied to UMs. Further research of these questions would help to establish the value of SEUMs that form a part of SEP portfolios and to establish FRAND royalty rates both for individual SEUMs, portfolios including both SEUMs and SEPs, and for top-down FRAND royalty determinations for entire standards.
It would also be useful to gain a better understanding of the business strategies that have led some firms to declare SEUMs in large quantities, while others have largely ignored them. Thus, just as Ford Motor Co. in the automotive sector has been observed by Cahoy and Oswald to have adopted a business strategy involving the acquisition (and possibly assertion) of UMs,Footnote 53 InterDigital, during the 2000s, appears to have adopted such an approach in the ICT sector, particularly around standards developed under the aegis of ETSI. Samsung, the second highest holder of SEUMs, appears to have adopted a similar strategy. A greater appreciation for firm strategy in relation to UMs could help policy makers to tailor their UM systems to the needs of the private sector.
Further research into SEUM assertion and litigation is also warranted. The litigation data that we reviewed could be supplemented with more detailed information regarding case outcomes, timing and tactics. Greater visibility into these issues could help policy makers to assess whether UMs are being (or could be) abused as litigation devices, and whether procedural safeguards should be put in place to avoid such abuse in the future.
18.4 Conclusion
UMs, once a “back water” of intellectual property scholarship,Footnote 54 may be more relevant to technology-intensive standards than previously thought. This study demonstrates that UMs are being declared essential to industry standards in significant numbers, at least by some firms. Given the relative ease, speed and cost-effectiveness of obtaining UMs, it is possible that this trend will continue. Yet UMs involve a degree of uncertainty, both as to their coverage and enforceability, as well as their status (or not) as SEPs. Such uncertainty imposes unnecessary costs on the standardization ecosystem and can be utilized opportunistically both by UM holders and implementers. Accordingly, policy makers and SDOs should thus consider clarifying, and more intensely harmonizing, their rules concerning UMs and SEUMs. Firms and courts should likewise consider the value of SEUMs when calculating FRAND royalties for portfolios and overall standards. Finally, these findings invite reconsideration of the role of UMs in the innovation ecosystem.
In a world of increasing harmonization of intellectual property rights, the “utility model” stands out as a stark outlier. This specialized form of a lesser innovation right is available in only about half of the world’s intellectual property systems, and the scope of protection and rules for acquisition can vary widely among offering countries.
This disharmony is surprising as utility models fill a unique niche in the innovation ecosystem. Although a utility model has claims like a standard patent, utility models cover a narrower range of inventive activity, are subject to less governmental scrutiny, and have a significantly shorter life than standard patents. In most respects, utility models provide a simpler route to low-level protection for useful inventions. Intuitively, they should be attractive to a variety of actors, including small firms whose inventive activity does not rise to the level required for standard patents or large firms that wish to more completely blanket the landscape. The disparate embrace of utility models in the world’s intellectual property systems, however, means that this option is often unavailable to actors who might benefit from it.
Despite the differential availability of national utility model rights we see no evidence of businesses or policymakers pushing to harmonize in this field. Rather, firms appear to adopt country-specific intellectual property strategies that leverage differential qualities in legal protection and maximize available efficiencies in a manner that would be otherwise unavailable in a fully standardized intellectual property environment.Footnote 1
This chapter draws on empirical research that demonstrates that utility model protection can address differential capture or appropriabilityFootnote 2 needs for a firm’s portfolio of inventions in terms of time and cost. We propose that a “zone of appropriability preference” exists when utility models and standard patents overlap, and this zone provides important opportunities to firms with global intellectual property portfolios. Using the European Patent Office’s PATSTAT patent data and a novel experimental construct that tracks inventions that are pursued as a utility model instead of a standard patent, we demonstrate that firms appear to seek utility model protection when their overall appropriability needs differ by region. We make the case that a firm may choose standard patent protection in one region and utility model protection in another, even though standard patent protection is available in both settings.
Our analysis suggests that firms exploit utility model disharmony to their benefit, choosing utility models over standard patents in some countries or certain instances in order to better appropriate (i.e., obtain greater economic returns on) their innovations. This behavior, along with the relative indifference of policymakers, firms and commentators to the fractured utility model landscape, indicates that disharmony may provide an important means of addressing differential national and firm-level needs and preferences. In the end, the strategic advantages that utility models provide to firms along with the additional flexibility such systems give countries to tailor and optimize national intellectual property protection schemes raise the counterintuitive possibility that disharmony in this field of intellectual property law may in fact be the best policy.
19.1 Global IP Strategy and the Challenge of Utility Model Disharmony
Multinational firms have a strong interest in relatively uniform and predictable legal rules and regulations across countries. More consistency in legal regimes lowers transaction costs and creates efficiencies that can be leveraged as a firm extends its reach in new territories. In addition, because information can be so easily appropriated by competitors, it is extremely important to have the assurance of legal protection for inventive technologies and creative ideas before products and services are globally disseminated. Foreign direct investment also hinges on consistency in intellectual property protection.
However, intellectual property rights are national in character and may vary in availability or enforceability across countries. For that reason, governments have undertaken a purposeful effort to harmonize intellectual property through treaties and other international rights. As a result, a firm can expect to encounter a patent system that is generally nondiscriminatory in its protection,Footnote 3 a copyright system that protects computer programsFootnote 4 and a common system for registering trademarks in multiple jurisdictions.Footnote 5 Even rights that still have significant national differences in scope and nature, such as trade secrets, nonetheless carry an expectation that some level of protection will exist based on treaty obligations.Footnote 6 The convergence of intellectual property rules and norms across the world is a legal harmonization success story.
Utility models have been conspicuously absent from the harmonization conversation, despite the important niche they purportedly fill. Policymakers in many countries believe that intellectual property rights serve as an important incentive for small business investment,Footnote 7 but that obtaining patent rights is burdensome and expensive for small and medium-sized enterprises.Footnote 8 Moreover, development advocates and scholars argue that less-invention-intensive rights could serve a potentially important role for emerging economies.Footnote 9
Despite these policy rationales arguing for utility model systems, harmonization efforts in this field have been very rare. There was, for example, discussion about regional harmonization of utility model systems in the European Union (EU) in the 1990s.Footnote 10 The effort eventually resulted in a formal proposal from the European Commission for a utility model “directive,” but the effort stalled in the early 2000s when member states decided to instead focus on a standard European patent.Footnote 11
Other countries have eliminated their utility model systems in recent years. For example, citing legal uncertainty and a lack of innovation enhancement, the Netherlands abolished its “short-term” patent system in 2008.Footnote 12 Belgium eliminated its “small patent” in 2009 for essentially the same reason.Footnote 13 The lost filings in both countries arguably were absorbed by the standard patent system.Footnote 14 Australia replaced its 1970s-era “petty patent” right with a new “innovation patent” in 2001, but eliminated the relatively new right just twenty years later,Footnote 15 fearing it conveyed few benefits to inventors and created risks of abuse.Footnote 16
Efforts to implement new national utility model systems are even scarcer and typically unsuccessful. A Private Member bill to create such a system was introduced in New Zealand in 2018, but it was not supported by Government; a motion to pass the bill failed at the first reading.Footnote 17 In 2011, India issued a discussion paper inviting public commentary on the potential adoption of a utility model system. After evaluating extensive commentary on draft policies, the IPR Think Tank recommended adoption of such a system in its final report in 2015, but no further action has been taken.Footnote 18
Thus, utility model systems are characterized by profound disharmony at the global level. Moreover, no overarching historical theme dictates whether a country has a utility model system. The developmental status of a country appears to be disconnected from this question, as utility model systems can be found in a selection of countries ranging from major developed economiesFootnote 19 to least developed countries.Footnote 20
One might assume that, if utility model systems convey advantages to society, efforts to expand their presence are justified and arguably should be the subject of international harmonization. Moreover, if there is a particular set of utility model attributes that are optimal, discordant systems should be brought in line. This has been the global approach in almost every other intellectual property context.
However, our study of the real-world use of utility model systems by firms suggests that a broad harmonization effort would be misplaced. Our findings suggest that the firms and individuals that rely on innovation incentives not only accept the discordant environment of utility models but may even embrace it as a means of achieving optimal protection under different conditions. Additionally, from a policy perspective, our findings further suggest that division creates diversity at the national level that may act as a laboratory for innovation stimulation.
In sum, our investigation of utility model use supports the general notion that harmonization is not always the answer; a nuanced and informed approach to modifying existing protection schemes is more important than is generally acknowledged.
19.2 Evidence of Firm Utility Model Use and Strategy
How do users of the intellectual property system respond to utility model regimes? Who is actually obtaining utility models, and what does that say about whether this form of intellectual property law protection is integrated into innovation markets or is an outlier? Recently available data on utility model use is the best starting point to better understand their impact.
19.2.1 Overall Business Use of Utility Models
It is difficult to identify which industries make use of utility model protection globally, because the covered subject matter can differ from country to country, skewing the results.Footnote 21 For example, a software invention protectable as a utility model in one country may be excluded in another. In addition, surprisingly few studies detail use of utility models by industry, as opposed to the countries targeted or the size of applicants. However, a recent review of several EU countries noted that the “mechanical engineering” sector was dominant across the board, followed closely by “electrical engineering.”Footnote 22 Even more specifically, the study found the top industries linked to utility models in each country were all manufacturing related, but the order of each specific type can differ.Footnote 23
19.2.2 Existing Assessments of Utility Model Disharmony Impact on Firm Strategy
Existing assessments on the impact of utility models disharmony on firm intellectual property strategy are limited.Footnote 24 A 2015 study conducted by the Technopolis Group, tendered by the European Commission (the “Technopolis Report”), involved a review of the literature and available evidence on the impact of utility models on European states as well as selected non-EU countries that offer the rights.Footnote 25 It found that legal uncertainty across systems was a key barrier to more widespread use of utility models by firms.Footnote 26 But more importantly for our purposes, the study noted that utility models were used as an auxiliary tool by practitioners to avoid perceived problems in the standard patent system rather than as a primary protection mechanism for “minor inventions by small inventors.”Footnote 27 It concluded that the evidence on the impact of utility models to support innovation was ambiguousFootnote 28 and recommended against a move to harmonize utility models similar to standard patents.Footnote 29
In a similar study funded by the European Commission and the Office for Harmonization of the Internal Market (OHIM), Prud’homme (Reference Prud’homme2014) undertook a more granular analysis by considering the legal details of different utility model systems to determine if a particular iteration has a more positive economic impact. He compared the systems of Austria, China, the Czech Republic, Finland, France, Germany and Italy in terms of qualities such as subject matter, duration, filing costs, examination form and nature, and the potential for double or parallel filing.Footnote 30 Prud’homme found that utility models are of some, but limited, use to developing countries.Footnote 31 Moreover, there are specific attributes of systems (e.g., electronic filing, subsidies or restricted subject matter) that are clearly more preferable from the perspective of the offering country.Footnote 32
19.3 A New View on Utility Models: The Zone of Appropriability Preference
The existing literature permits few conclusions on the likely impact on innovation from utility model systems. Observers can reasonably disagree on whether this form of intellectual property serves as a complement to standard patents, a competitor, or simply a distinct right with no clear analogy in systems such as the United States. Without more, it is impossible to say anything definitive on the need for harmonization of utility model systems. A deeper dive into firm-level strategic choices for innovation protection is necessary.
19.3.1 “Carve-outs” versus “Add-ons” and the “Zone of Appropriability Preferences”
A common context for assessing whether utility model systems are advantageous is the understanding that they are “add-ons” to the standard patent system; that is, that utility models protect inventions that would not normally be covered by patents because they are not sufficient advances over existing technology.Footnote 33 The evaluation of the contribution of utility models to a country’s innovative output necessarily considers whether this separate system actually encourages more inventive activity or simply pulls information out of the public domain to the detriment of the overall environment. The add-on opportunity is how the literature to date has viewed utility models.
However, we posit a novel possible explanation of how utility model systems are used: they provide an important choice to firms by serving as an alternative to standard patents. In some systems, such as China’s, firms may have the option to file a utility model and standard patent application on the same invention; in those instances, the utility model rights could act less like an add-on regime, and more like a partial “carve-out.” In other words, utility models in these systems pull some inventions away from standard patents. The carve-out is not simply a matter of failed attempts at full patenting, but rather a deliberate strategic choice by the applicant to opt for the second-tier right. Importantly, the extent to which a system facilitates a carve-out strategy is highly dependent on the various elements that define its utility model rights. This difference is essentially the result of disharmony.
Why would a firm ever choose a utility model when its invention is eligible for a stronger standard patent? In fact, there are advantages to the generic utility model that may be more important for certain inventions in particular locations. One such advantage is speed. Because utility models generally require no initial examination, they issue quickly, providing a firm with rights that it can assert and license. Additionally, given the possibility of protecting additional pieces or branches of a core invention, it may be possible to blanket a product with rights that essentially create a single-firm thicket that competitors find difficult to avoid. Finally, a firm’s operations in a particular location with a particular legal system might be optimally protected by many utility models over a few standard patents.
We define the decision-making process of choosing utility models over standard patents (or vice versa) in those systems that treat utility models as carve-outs as operating in the “zone of appropriability preference” (see Figure 19.1). In this zone, inventors and firms have a choice between protection regimes – standard patents or utility models – and their choice represents a preference among qualities that differ between the two. For example, the choice for speed in securing a utility model over the longer protection period for a slower-to-issue standard patent represents such a preference. The existence of the zone allows a firm to extract optimal appropriability from invention rights and not waste resources on securing protection that is too powerful or too long.
![](https://static.cambridge.org/binary/version/id/urn:cambridge.org:id:binary:20250103071022584-0229:9781009478113:47812fig19_1.png?pub-status=live)
Figure 19.1 Role of utility models in a country’s IP system
19.3.2 Data Supporting Optimal Appropriability Strategies
There is support for the proposition that sufficient knowledge and legal flexibility exist to enable businesses to engage in invention appropriation preference strategies. The 2015 Technopolis Report concluded that in developed economies, utility models can be used “as an auxiliary tool to patenting for a range of specific purposes” and they can help “deal with certain country-specific issues ….”Footnote 34 Moreover, according to the report’s assessment of firm use, it appears that utility models “are utilised to a considerable extent to overcome specific challenges in the national patent systems ….”Footnote 35
Two studies explicitly connecting patents and utility models – one centered in Europe and one in China – also provide some empirical evidence of the zone of appropriability preference theory. Heikkilä and Verba (Reference Heikkilä and Verba2018) considered connections between standard patent and utility model filings in the European Union. Using PATSTAT data, they collected one dataset comprising (1) patent and utility models families filed at any EU patent office offering utility model protection, and another (2) restricting such families to those claiming priority from an EU patent or utility model filed at any EU patent office offering utility model protection.Footnote 36
Heikkilä and Verba found that utility model filings may be used as part of an international filing strategy, belying the idea that utility models only cover minor inventions worthy of protection in the domestic market.Footnote 37 However, they also found that inventions with patent priorities are of higher quality than those with utility model priorities.Footnote 38 Those quality differences between patent and utility model priorities are less important than other indicators of patent quality, such as citation count, patent family size and whether there is an associated Patent Cooperation Treaty (PCT) filing.Footnote 39 Heikkilä and Verba failed to find any clear indication of strategies to obtain quick rights related to utility model priorities.Footnote 40
Cao et al. (Reference Cao, Lei and Wright2014) considered Chinese patent and utility model applications that served as priority for a U.S. patent application that was subsequently granted. Similar to our construct below, they assumed that any utility model application that was sufficiently inventive to serve as a basis for a U.S. patent must be inventive enough to also qualify for a Chinese patent.Footnote 41 Therefore, their study set considered patents of similar quality that are by choice filed as either patents or utility models in China. One important finding from Cao et al.’s work is that inventions filed as Chinese utility models have much shorter time lags between applications, indicating that the applicant desired speed in particular.Footnote 42 These patents are also less likely to have continuations filed at the U.S. Patent and Trademark Office or to be maintained during the patent term.Footnote 43 Again, this indicates that utility models are connected to inventions that do not require the full length of U.S patent rights. Applicants are exposing their appropriability interests and making more efficient use of them through the broader options in protection offered by China’s system.
19.3.3 Additional Litigation Evidence of Utility Model Use
If firms indeed perceive utility models as a useful tool for optimally appropriating innovation, one would expect to see more substantive activity than simple rights accumulation. Effectively capturing innovation should include enforcement activities. Conversely, if utility models serve primarily as a weak credential for individuals and firms wishing to memorialize innovative activity, one might expect very little litigation and low rates of success when it does occur. Unfortunately, the lack of comprehensive global litigation data in the utility model arena makes it difficult to decide between real value or mere credential.
Fortunately, China, the most prominent utility model filing target, has now made available a significant amount of information.Footnote 44 Those data suggest that, despite the lower standards and lack of examination, utility model rights fare quite well in terms of enforcement success: they are enforced at a level at least as high as standard patents with better win rates for rights holders. Unofficial sources have reported this robust litigation activity for some time.Footnote 45 Bian (Reference Bian2018) conducted an empirical analysis of Chinese patent litigation using an official source, China Judgements Online. According to Bian’s analysis of final judgments from 2014, owners of Chinese utility models constitute a greater share of the litigation landscape than standard patents (25% versus 13%), and are slightly more likely to be successful, with a win rate of 77% versus 72%.Footnote 46
For purposes of our analysis, perhaps the most interesting statistic in Bian’s article is the fact that foreign litigants make up 3.33% of the plaintiffs in the cases studied.Footnote 47 Although this is relatively low – and certainly much lower than the 28.44% foreign litigant share in standard patent cases – it is higher than the percentage of foreign utility model ownership (1.12%).Footnote 48 This indicates that foreign utility model owners litigate at a higher rate than domestic owners. In other words, foreign owners of Chinese utility models seem to value their rights as real appropriation tools at least as much as, if not more than, domestic owners.
Of course, it is possible that the litigation numbers might reflect a selection bias rather than suggest that utility models are generally valuable (e.g., perhaps only the strongest or more straightforward utility models are asserted). However, this is no different than with standard patents; most are not enforced and those that are can be viewed as part of a specialized subset.Footnote 49 Based on this slice of the global litigation environment, utility models seem to have an enforceability potential that allows them to serve as a reasonable innovation investment incentive.
19.4 Business Strategy and Motivations for Utility Model Filings: A Study of U.S. Patent-to-Utility Model Pathways
With the Heikkilä and Verba (Reference Heikkilä and Verba2018) and Cao et al. (Reference Cao, Lei and Wright2014) studies in mind, we endeavored to extend the analysis to better understand the patent-utility model strategy. Are patent-utility model pairs simply a subclass of substandard inventions that are crammed into the standard patent system in order to execute a broader rights grab? Or is there evidence that firms are attempting to optimize a differential appropriation strategy, in which utility models provide distinct advantages in place of or in addition to standard patents in certain countries or instances? To better assess the strategic opportunity in filing utility models, we carried out our own novel empirical analysis.
In a study presented in more detail in a separate paper,Footnote 50 we used PATSTAT data to focus on a particularly relevant stream of utility model rights that could provide a unique perspective on (1) how these rights impact innovation and (2) what firms appear to exploit system disharmony. Specifically, we considered inventions objectively viable as standard patents that are nonetheless filed as utility models in at least one country. Our presumption was that firms see a particular advantage in undertaking the time and expense of such filings, and this can reveal important information about the appropriability potential of certain systems.
We looked for indicators that would permit us to assess the validity of two hypotheses. First, we propose that this subset of utility model applicants is choosing this form of innovation protection in order to attain some local advantage. Again, because we presume the applicant could have filed only a standard patent, the choice to file a utility model evinces a strategy that accounts for the expense of filing for and possibly enforcing a lower form of intellectual property.
Additionally, we considered the possibility that firms filing a large number of utility models may simply be attempting to obtain every right possible in every location possible. This kind of strategy conflicts with the more purposeful strategy that acknowledges utility models are an advantage only in some countries for some technologies. We believe that firms are more likely to choose the latter, more specific strategy and that it is useful to distinguish between the two.
Our analysis bore out the hypothesis that firms chose to file utility models when a standard patent would be attainable to take advantage of country-specific conditions. Moreover, as to whether patent-to-utility model strategies are simply an attempt to accumulate more rights whatever the cost, we looked to the number of different utility model filings per U.S. patent application. If rights accumulation were the ultimate goal, we would expect to see a large percentage of the inventions filed in multiple countries.
However, the evidence suggests that broad rights accumulation is not the dominant strategy. In our study set, we found that most applicants file for a utility model in only one country. Overall, throughout the studied time period, 79.5% of the U.S. patent applications were filed in a second country as a utility model, and only 16% were filed in two additional countries as utility models (with the remaining percentage being filed in three to fourteen countries).
Additionally, we find that the top technologies underlying the utility models change by forum (see Figure 19.2). In China, we see “electrical machinery, apparatus, energy” at the top whereas Germany’s filings are led by “computer technology.” Similarly, digital communication draws a relatively high filing rate in Germany but not in China. Pharmaceuticals factor highly in Germany’s filings but low in China, though this is likely due to the fact that, strictly speaking, chemicals and pharmaceuticals are not protected under China’s utility model system.
![](https://static.cambridge.org/binary/version/id/urn:cambridge.org:id:binary:20250103071022584-0229:9781009478113:47812fig19_2.png?pub-status=live)
Figure 19.2 Share of U.S. patent-to-utility models in selected technologies (2000–2018)
Note: The technology fields in PATSTAT are based in the WIPO Statistics Database IPC8 Technology Concordance. See Schmoch Reference Schmoch2008.
Again, these data support the conclusion that, at least in some industrial sectors, firms are employing a forum-specific strategy rather than broad rights collection. We infer that firms are likely considering local industries and markets in seeking utility model protection.Footnote 51
19.5 Insights on Navigating Utility Model Disharmony
Despite existing in disharmony, utility models are an important part of the global intellectual property system for innovators. Our analysis, as well as recent literature, suggests that firms value utility model rights and actually use them to protect truly inventive activity. Typically, a discordant intellectual property system that plays a contributing role in creating innovation incentives would be a target for harmonization, yet there is no evidence of significant lobbying by either firms or policymakers to harmonize global utility model law. This suggests that both groups of stakeholders find the disharmonious status quo satisfactory.
The results of our study help explain the lack of enthusiasm for harmonization by providing important evidence that firms can effectively navigate the disharmonious environment of utility model systems. Importantly, ours was the first work to assess utility model use in a context that suggests a purposeful strategy of optimal intellectual property protection rather than simple rights capture. Although additional research is necessary to determine whether disharmony is better for global innovation or a particular country’s economic health, our proposed framework posits that, at the firm level, an innovator may consider the availability of utility models around the world and utilize the systems it finds advantageous in view of the overall economic, legal and political environment.
In particular, firms can optimize the differential appropriability of utility models to achieve protection efficiencies and accommodate national differences. Possible applications include employing utility models as an efficient antipiracy device in foreign locations, rather than a long-term, global competition exclusion tool as they would with traditional patents. Firms in fast-moving industries can put up roadblocks with utility models on their minor advances that are otherwise easy to copy. With cheap filing costs and no examination, ultimate enforceability may not be so important. In other cases, utility models may fill a gap that exists between what can be protected through design patents or other industrial design measures and what is worth protecting with traditional patents.Footnote 52 And, if there are differences in standard patent acquisition and enforcement rules between countries of interest, utility models may fill that gap as well.
At the national level, individual countries may well benefit from not being forced into a harmonized utility model system. They may use utility model systems to experiment with a combination of intellectual property protection elements that best optimize their desired economic or policy goals. They may adopt utility model systems to fill a specific national need, such as satisfying inventor rights or providing a defensive publication to preclude another’s capture of an invention.Footnote 53 Some countries may even seek to align their systems with desired firms or economic outcomes and modify utility model attributes in accordance.Footnote 54
Of course, even though disharmony may have some benefits for some firms or some countries, those benefits could be outweighed by anti-competitive negatives. For example, commentators have noted the potential to use easy-to-obtain utility models as a vehicle for trolling.Footnote 55 Given the efforts in the United States to curb abusive patent behavior, firms and policymakers may be loath to see another potential trolling vehicle arise in other systems. Additionally, the higher costs of navigating disparate systems may disadvantage smaller firms with global goals.
More broadly, our study and related analysis are the first to present the idea of utility models as an appropriability choice rather than a means of capturing otherwise unprotectable inventions; as such, our study may address a persistent problem in innovation system assessment. Namely, study after study has failed to find sufficient evidence for changing the status quo regarding utility model structures as a component of national or regional innovation systems. For example, the Technopolis Report stated that “it is not possible for us to conclusively say whether UM systems – or particular incarnations of those – actually support innovation.”Footnote 56 A follow-up article by Radauer et al., discussing evidence since the study, doubled down on this conclusion.Footnote 57 Similarly, Prud’homme found that while utility model systems can be useful tools to stimulate innovation and technological diffusion in some developing countries, they “can grow to be of limited value in developed countries.”Footnote 58 Other studies reach similar conclusions.Footnote 59
Although one possibility may be that utility model systems fundamentally fail as innovation incentives, the zone of appropriability preference model suggests that innovators may be simply allocating the same inventions between different protection regimes. To be sure, optimal capture may have some positive impact on the incentive to innovate and one might still expect to see that in measures of innovative activity. The reason this does not show up in the studies is likely that this impact is far less significant than that which one would expect from bringing an entirely new group of innovators into the system.
Taken together, one can reasonably conclude that the invention appropriation advantages of utility models, lack of evidence of significant abuse in the existing systems and relatively small impact on the overall innovation activity of countries or regions produce general satisfaction with disharmony among both firms and policymakers. Reports suggest that the small portion of the intellectual property community that has an interest in utility models does not generally favor harmonization efforts.Footnote 60 Moreover, users of the global intellectual property system would probably be wary of reform that may not address known problems but instead end up eliminating the strategic advantages in pursuing utility model protection.Footnote 61 Considering all available information, including our study results, we believe that policymakers have a basis to determine that a TRIPS-like harmonization effort for utility models would be unhelpful and even potentially harmful.
Finally, one might ask if it is legitimate for there to be a policy contrast between utility models and standard patents. In other words, if disharmony is permitted for utility models, how can it be problematic for standard patents? However, the contrasting conditions underlying such an inquiry may not be as stark as many assume. In fact, there is actually some variation in standard patent rights across the world. In particular, enforcement systems can differ in aspects such as government prosecution, bifurcated validity and infringement proceedings, criminal liability and the availability of jury trials.Footnote 62 It is primarily the availability of basic protection that is harmonized through TRIPSFootnote 63 and other treaties such as the PCT.Footnote 64 More uniformity may be desired, but it may be impossible to fully harmonize every aspect of various domestic legal systems, even in a narrow area like invention rights. Firms naturally look to a means for accommodating the disparity. In this space, the utility model fills the gap and provides a buffer of disharmony that allows a more optimal capture of a given invention in a given country.
In the end, we believe that there is a basis for the counterintuitive proposition that disharmony can be the optimal intellectual property policy from a country-level perspective in some instances to maximize efficiency, exploit system differences and experiment with specific protection standards. Although such an approach conflicts with the historical and political drive toward harmonization, it is a flexibility that may be demanded by the complexities of global production and trade. If the status quo works, the harmonization journey may not be the best policy route.
19.6 Conclusion
Based on empirical evidence of the use of utility model systems coupled with the relative indifference on the part of policymakers and firms, we believe that there is support for the proposition that marginal disharmony can work in the context of utility models. In this particular intellectual property rights setting, disharmony may allow countries space for experimentation and tailoring to national policy objectives while not impeding effective management of global intellectual property portfolios at the firm level. Reasonable policymakers may conclude that uniformity in intellectual property protection is not necessarily the correct objective.