Hostname: page-component-586b7cd67f-rdxmf Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-11-28T10:42:44.395Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Does Economic Globalization Influence the US Policy Mood?: A Study of US Public Sentiment, 1956–2011*

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  28 May 2014

Rights & Permissions [Opens in a new window]

Abstract

Does increasing economic globalization influence aggregate policy mood toward the role and size of government in the United States? Drawing on insights from international political economy scholarship, this article suggests that the impact of trade on aggregate preferences will depend on citizens’ exposure to trade. It hypothesizes that employees of import-competing, export-oriented and multinational firms will adopt a ‘compensatory’ model in which higher levels of imports (exports) lead to a liberal (conservative) shift in policy preferences for more (less) government. It distinguishes between intrafirm and non-intrafirm trade flows. It measures policy mood using Stimson's ‘Mood’, and estimates Error Correction and Instrumental Variable models. Trade flows strongly influence Mood in a manner consistent with hypotheses drawn from international political economy and heterogeneous firms (or ‘new new’) trade theory.

Type
Articles
Copyright
Copyright © Cambridge University Press 2014 

The ‘policy mood’, a measure of aggregate public opinion, is generally defined as the public's latent preferences regarding government policy.Footnote 1 Public opinion, in turn, is one of the most important determinants of public policy in advanced industrial democracies, especially in the United States.Footnote 2 Unsurprisingly, given the centrality of policy mood in influencing public policy outcomes in US politics, scholars have extensively explored its determinants, generally using Stimson's measure, ‘Mood’.

The policy mood within the American public has been found to have a main dimension that links issues in terms of a ‘left/right’ or ‘more government/less government’ scope of activity. In Stimson's wording, ‘the first dimension of American public opinion is the welfare state/size of government controversy that divides the parties’.Footnote 3 Erikson, MacKuen and Stimson, in perhaps the most systematic study of Mood, reported that current inflation and changing unemployment are associated with rightward and leftward shifts (respectively) in Mood during the period 1956–96.Footnote 4

However, marked changes in the US economy in the past few decades have had important implications for both the economic realities facing citizens and their preferences about the role and size of the government. Of particular interest to this article is the US economy's growing integration into the world economy in terms of flows of goods, services and finance, with resulting direct and indirect effects on growth, prices, employment, wages and job security. The impact of this increased economic integration on aggregate measures of the public's attitudes has yet to be studied, a lacuna we seek to address.

In this article, we incorporate insights from international political economy (IPE) and international economics into the literature on aggregate US public opinion. We propose that citizens whose livelihoods depend on the success of import-competing, export-oriented and multinational firms face an economic reality that indicators of unemployment or growth only loosely reflect. Therefore, by introducing indicators of imports and exports into the empirical analyses of Mood, we will improve the explanatory power of the resulting models by better capturing the microeconomic climates associated with citizen exposure to trade.

The article proceeds as follows. We begin by reviewing the literature on the determinants of Mood, as the macroeconomic determinants and econometric methods of this literature form the baseline of our investigation. We next review the literature on the internationalization of the US economy, particularly focusing on multinational corporations, foreign direct investment, and trade in goods and services. We review (1) the theory and findings regarding the economic outcomes of import-competing firms compared to those of export-oriented and multinational firms and (2) studies on the consequences of economic globalization for attitudes toward government spending.

We propose that economic globalization variables influence policy mood through their effect on the real economy, and do so in a manner consistent with what IPE research terms the ‘compensation hypothesis’. We use Stimson's ‘Mood’ as the dependent variable in the investigation. To test the hypotheses, we use Error Correction (EC) and instrumental variables (IV) models. In particular, IV methods allow us to account for unobservable variables that are potentially related to firm-specific characteristics but that might also be correlated with trade flows.

The main period of study is the US policy mood from 1956–2011. We also examine the separate effects on Mood of within-firm imports or exports (that is, intrafirm trade flows) by US multinational corporations (MNCs) and US affiliates of foreign multinationals, compared to non-intrafirm trade flows from 1983–2011. (The sample is determined by data availability.) We find that rising imports (exports) are associated with a leftward (rightward) shift in Mood. The estimated effects are particularly pronounced for increasing non-intrafirm imports into the United States. The key results for the effects of imports on Mood are generally robust, providing strong support for the main argument of this article. Finally, we examine whether Mood's established effect on social expenditures is moderated by changing trade flows. In very exploratory work, we find that import flows, especially non-intrafirm imports, moderate Mood's effect on social expenditures.

PRIOR STUDIES OF THE DETERMINANTS OF MOOD

Previous models of the determinants of Mood can be grouped into those that emphasize broad macroeconomic conditions and those that focus on previous policies. Foremost in the first group is work that has focused on the effect of the state of the macroeconomy on Mood. Erikson, MacKuen and Stimson found that increasing rates of unemployment lead to a liberal policy mood shift, while increases in consumer price indices bring forth a conservative shift.Footnote 5 In other words, the public prefers more government spending when unemployment is high, and less government spending when inflation is high.

Durr suggested that prospective economic expectations influence policy mood.Footnote 6 In a study of the quarterly version of Mood from 1968–88, Durr found that citizen expectations of weak future economic performance moved Mood rightward (which he interpreted as being consistent with a ‘budget’ model), whereas expectations of prosperity led citizens to support greater government involvement in the economy.

Stevenson builds on Durr's work, and proposes a version of a ‘consumer choice’ model, which he extends to an analysis of fourteen advanced democracies, using two measures of policy mood: Kim and Fording's indicator of median voter ideology and an indicator of ideological self-placement.Footnote 7 Like Durr, Stevenson argues that policy mood will move to the left when the economy is expanding and to the right as it contracts, because voters make demands subject to a budget constraint.Footnote 8 This hypothesis is similar to Durr's, though Stevenson uses lagged values of economic performance rather than an expectations measure. Stevenson's results show that prior levels of growth (positively), inflation (negatively) and unemployment (negatively) influenced Mood.Footnote 9

An alternative explanation for shifts in policy preferences, which was first proposed by Wlezien, suggests that citizens respond ‘thermostatically’ to prior policies.Footnote 10 In other words, preferences move leftward after periods of lower levels of government spending and rightward after periods of higher levels of government spending. Similarly, Stevenson proposes a policy reaction hypothesis, in which government spending and partisanship are used as a heuristic for current policy.Footnote 11 Erikson, MacKuen and Stimson also found that an indicator of prior government policies was negatively associated with Mood, confirming Wlezien's finding of a thermostatic reaction to government policies.Footnote 12 They found that higher levels of government involvement produce a conservative shift, and lower levels produce a liberal shift.

The literature has not examined the possible effects of increased cross-border trade linkages on policy mood. Increasing international trade integration has changed the structure of the US economy and introduced new factors that might also shape the policy mood.

INTRAFIRM AND NON-INTRAFIRM TRADE AND THE ECONOMY: FIRM-SPECIFIC MICROECONOMIC CLIMATES

The increasing integration of the United States into the world economy has important consequences for public preferences regarding the role and size of government. Imports plus exports of goods and services (as a percentage of gross domestic product, GDP) have risen from under 7 per cent in 1956 to roughly 29 per cent in 2010.Footnote 13 Within these flows, however, is evidence of deterioration in the US economy's relative world position. The United States has gone from a net exporter to a net importer: the trade deficit averaged −4.5 per cent of GDP for the first decade of the twenty-first century.

Multinational corporations (MNCs) play a central role in US trade flows. Considering intrafirm, related party and arm's length trading jointly, MNCs mediate 90 per cent of US imports and exports.Footnote 14 Much of the growth in US trade flows over time, and over 60 per cent of the US trade deficit from 1982–2010, arises from intrafirm trading by MNCs.Footnote 15 In turn, intrafirm trading follows from MNC foreign direct investment (FDI) to and from the United States. In 2010, intrafirm imports by MNCs totaled just over $800 billion, accounting for roughly 5.5 per cent of US GDP and 35 per cent of total imports. An additional $300 billion in imports came from ‘related party’ trading.Footnote 16 In contrast to MNC intrafirm imports, a much smaller share of US exports is classified as MNC intrafirm exports ($500 billion in 2010, or a little more than 25 per cent of US exports), and related party (but not intrafirm) trading accounts for a vanishingly small share of exports (2 per cent).Footnote 17

This article assumes that the magnitude and direction of trade flows influence the US policy mood. We further posit that intrafirm and non-intrafirm flows will differently affect Mood through different distributional consequences for citizens. That is, the presence or absence of an ownership relationship between the parties involved in trade flows will influence the effects of the trade flows on Mood.

We begin by reviewing the recent literature on the behavior of firms engaged in trade and FDI. We next discuss the implications and evidence regarding the economic consequences of firm activity in exports and imports on citizens. Drawing on what is termed in economics the ‘heterogeneous firms’ (or ‘new new’) trade theory, we suggest that the effects of trade on the economy are primarily generated through the behavior of heterogeneous firms involved in either intrafirm or non-intrafirm trading.Footnote 18

Heterogeneous Firms in FDI and Trade

The primary insight from the heterogeneous firms trade theory is that firms with different levels of productivity also have different international strategies, with divergent consequences for their respective demands for skilled, semi-skilled and unskilled labor. Yeaple and Tomiura empirically confirm earlier findings that only firms with productivity levels above a certain threshold are able to engage in exporting, and demonstrate that only those above an even higher cut-off undertake FDI and engage in subsequent intrafirm trading.Footnote 19 In a study of US firms, Ramondo, Rappoport and Ruhl found that the largest MNCs (with very high levels of US employment) were most responsible for intrafirm imports into and exports from the United States.Footnote 20

In particular, purely domestic firms in the tradable sectors (that is, those that face import competition) have different value chains and factor inputs from non-MNC export-oriented firms, which in turn have different value chains and factor inputs from MNCs. Both exporters and MNCs employ more skilled labor than less productive, domestically oriented firms. Multinationals employ even more skilled labor than domestically based exporters.Footnote 21

Because the United States is relatively well endowed with skilled labor and capital, firms in labor-intensive tradable goods industries tend to face greater import competition. These firms are likely to fail or change industries, and their plants are both more likely to close and more likely to have lower employment and wage growth.Footnote 22

Yet firms that export generally have superior economic performance on many dimensions (higher employment, sales, wages, productivity and investment) than firms that do not export.Footnote 23 Thus rising exports tend to benefit employees of exporting firms, which on average utilize skilled labor more intensively.

The exceptions to increasing firm mortality and morbidity in import-competing industries are firms that have relocated production abroad (for example, offshoring), and are importing back into the United States. Intrafirm imports are often intermediate goods that MNCs use to lower the prices of final products and to otherwise enhance the productivity of the home-based operations; as a result, they are not threatening to MNC employees.Footnote 24

Winners and Losers from Intrafirm and non-Intrafirm Trade

The gains from trade tend to be focused among exporting firms and firms with extensive intrafirm trade, while the burdens of trade and trade adjustment tend to be focused on import-competing firms in the tradable sector. Thus citizens who benefit from trade tend to be skilled workers employed by exporting or multinational firms, while citizens hurt by trade tend to be unskilled workers in import-competing firms that do not export or engage in intrafirm trading.

This is in contrast to standard trade models, which interpret the distributional consequences of trade as manifested across factors (Heckscher-Ohlin) or sectors (Ricardo-Viner) or both. One of the key insights of heterogeneous firms theory is that the distributional consequences of trade do not follow industry or factor lines. This is also true of FDI patterns and the resulting intrafirm trading. Even though intrafirm trade is concentrated among a small number of very large MNCs and their affiliates, the MNCs are distributed across a very wide range of industries.Footnote 25

Workers in import-competing firms face a variety of adjustment costs, including effects on the level of employment, wages and job security. In a survey of displaced workers, Kletzer finds that manufacturing workers displaced by import competition are less likely to be re-employed than manufacturing workers displaced for other reasons.Footnote 26 Furthermore, export-competing industries do not account for a large share of re-employment due to different factor demands. Among workers displaced from import-competing sectors, those re-employed have weekly earnings that are 13 per cent lower on average; approximately 25 per cent report wage losses of 30 per cent or more.Footnote 27

Holders of unskilled labor employed by import-competing firms are especially threatened by rising imports from low-wage countries, such as China, which have increased dramatically in low-wage, labor-intensive industries (such as textiles and apparel). Autor, Dorn and Hanson found that US local labor markets that are:

exposed to rising low-income country imports due to China's rising competitiveness experience increased unemployment, decreased labor-force participation, and increased use of disability and other transfer benefits, as well as lower wages.Footnote 28

Heterogeneous firms trade theory implies that the microeconomic conditions facing employees will vary depending on their firms’ value chains, product markets and strategies. Changes in (and levels of) trade flows will proxy for the firm-specific conditions facing employees in this study. MNC intrafirm imports are likely to be less threatening in terms of employment than are non-MNC imports due to the benefits for at least some employees and others affiliated with the MNCs. MNC intrafirm imports are therefore likely to have ambiguous effects on Mood. In contrast, non-intrafirm imports are likely to be threatening to lower-skilled workers without having intrafirm beneficiaries.

Furthermore, these studies of the effects of firm strategies on employee work life suggest that the effect of the increasing importance of international trade in the US economy on Mood cannot be fully understood theoretically or econometrically by analyzing the unemployment rate alone. First, the distributional or welfare consequences of trade extend beyond employment levels. Trade changes the composition of firms in the economy; it is not just the quantity of work in the import-competing sectors that declines, but also its quality and composition in terms of wages, benefits, job security and skills. Secondly, trade is likely to affect Mood before the effects of rising imports or exports are reflected in the unemployment rate. Even before import-competing firms cut jobs, workers can anticipate the effects of reduced production orders (for example, shorter hours, reduced wages, eventual lay-offs). Employees of firms in the import-competing sector might retain their jobs or find new ones, but the terms of employment are likely to worsen in quality.

In summary, we expect that these different climates will affect citizen preferences regarding the role of government with a resulting shift in Mood. The argument about the palliative effect of MNC intrafirm trade flows vs. non-intrafirm flows on the demand for redistribution is consistent with recent studies on firm demands (or non-demands) for trade protection.Footnote 29 The next section further explores the literature on trade and citizen demands for protection and redistribution.

THE MICRO-CLIMATE FROM TRADE AND THE POLITICAL DEMAND FOR COMPENSATION

Although analysis of policy mood has generally centered on American politics, insights from the IPE literature have important implications for models of policy mood, in particular how the distributional consequences of the different facets of trade discussed above are likely to influence the demand for government spending. The ‘compensation’ model is a prominent international relations theory concerning how democratic governments manage the risks of international economic integration so as to generate continued support for integration and its associated benefits.Footnote 30 Its core thesis, as Kim puts it, is that ‘economic globalization bolsters rather than undermines the welfare state by increasing public demand for social protection against externally generated economic instability’.Footnote 31 The compensation literature provides an important link between the distributional consequences of trade and preferences over government spending.

The starting point of the compensation hypothesis is that exposure to economic globalization increases the sense of economic insecurity, particularly of those in import-competing sectors. In a systematic study of British respondents, Scheve and Slaughter find that inward FDI, and globalization more generally, generated increased risk (in terms of the volatility of wages and employment), thus increasing feelings of insecurity among workers.Footnote 32 Similarly, Walter finds in a study of Swiss respondents that individuals hurt by globalization, particularly trade, are more likely to express feelings of economic insecurity.Footnote 33 In a more general study of job insecurity, Aldrich et al. find that those with greater feelings of job insecurity are more likely to favor increased government spending and government provision of jobs.Footnote 34 Rehm argues that preferences regarding redistribution are a function of income and income prospects; those who are more exposed to risk are more likely to favor redistribution.Footnote 35 If trade has the distributional consequences posited above, Mood will likely shift leftwards among those whose current and future economic well-being is hurt by trade.

Therefore we expect citizens to feel greater insecurity regarding non-intrafirm imports for two main reasons. First, when operationalizing risk as the volatility of trade flows, as is standard, we observe markedly different patterns regarding the volatility of intrafirm MNC trade flows vs. non-intrafirm trade flows. For the available period, non-intrafirm imports and exports, measured as a percentage of US GDP, were more volatile (standard deviations of 1.8 and 1.2, respectively) than intrafirm imports and exports (standard deviations of 0.8 and 0.4, respectively).Footnote 36 Non-intrafirm trade flows also grew at a faster pace (2.6 per cent per year for imports; 2 per cent for exports) compared to intrafirm trade flows (1.8 per cent for imports; 0.8 per cent for exports). Secondly, while both intrafirm and non-intrafirm imports are likely to improve the efficiency of the US economy, the employment benefits to US citizens are likely to be far lower for non-intrafirm imports than intrafirm imports.

Micro-level evidence regarding the relationship between increasing integration with the world economy and spending confirms the broad trends described above. In surveys, the American public expresses limited enthusiasm for free trade per se, unless it is accompanied by ‘government programs to help workers who lose their jobs’.Footnote 37 US respondents are concerned about workers losing jobs from trade because respondents generally believe that free trade hurts job security, and that imports cost more jobs than exports create.Footnote 38 This evidence suggests that a substantial portion of the public continues to have reservations about free trade because of its distributional effects on the number of jobs, wages and job security. In a study of US respondents, Ehrlich finds that those who report being hurt by trade are more likely to support trade-related unemployment insurance, and those who benefit from trade are more likely to oppose this form of compensation.Footnote 39 Walter finds that how one is affected by globalization affects preferences over welfare spending more generally, and that preferences over welfare spending affect vote choice.Footnote 40 Though not directly related to the argument tested in this article, recent studies by Margalit and Rickard suggest that politicians recognize the need, and have some ability, to garner public support for liberalization through compensation.Footnote 41

Alternatively, technological innovation may produce some of the same costs and benefits to skilled and unskilled workers as does trade integration. Even if the US economy were to be closed to trade, technological innovation would likely benefit more highly skilled workers, and put downward pressure on wages and employment security for lower-skilled workers.Footnote 42 Thus increases in the skill premium or other indicators of technological advance may lead to a leftward shift in Mood, as unskilled workers in particular experience a decline in economic conditions and an increase in job insecurity. The processes of increasing technological innovation and increasing economic globalization are likely to occur in many firms simultaneously, a point that we address in the empirics.

Summary

The prior literature on the determinants of Mood has emphasized domestic macroeconomic conditions – primarily inflation, unemployment and growth – and citizen reactions to prior government policies. However, the structure of the US economy has changed such that citizens’ microeconomic experiences can no longer be fully represented by these domestic macroeconomic indicators. From heterogeneous firms trade theory, we propose that the increasing integration of the US economy into the world economy produces firm-specific microeconomies that are likely to influence their employees’ Mood. Intrafirm imports by MNCs are likely to produce conflicting effects, since many MNC employees are likely to benefit from the enhanced profitability and employment opportunities of successful international firms. In contrast, increasing non-intrafirm imports are likely to have a broad leftward effect on Mood with little countervailing pressure.

HYPOTHESES

We propose that trade affects aggregate policy preferences, as measured by Mood, via political demands for more or less compensation, and that the direction and intensity of these demands depend on the relative gains or losses from trade. Although inflation and unemployment are still likely to be important determinants of Mood, trade affects a growing proportion of Americans and should therefore also be considered as a possible explanatory factor for shifts in aggregate public opinion.

As suggested above, trade has different distributional consequences for different segments of the US population.Footnote 43 We propose that the distributive consequences of trade shift spending preferences to the left (larger or more active government) or right (smaller or less active government) according to the expectations presented in Table 1. Though employees observe specific firm-level characteristics, we cannot directly observe the microeconomic conditions facing citizens. Thus we look to macroeconomic indicators that capture these conditions. We suggest that individual microeconomic conditions, and thus relevant macroeconomic indicators, vary systematically according to whether citizens are employed in import-competing, export-oriented/multinational firms or firms in the non-tradable sector. Unemployment continues to capture microeconomic conditions for individuals in the non-tradable sector, while imports and exports capture at the macro level some of the microeconomic conditions for those employees in the tradable sectors.

Table 1 Macroeconomic and Microeconomic Conditions Affecting Mood

Note: Δ+ indicates a leftward shift in Mood; Δ− indicates a rightward shift in Mood; a blank cell indicates no expected effects on Mood.

Across all segments of the population, we expect that rising inflation will produce conservative shifts in policy mood, as suggested by the existing literature. However, we expect segmentation among workers regarding their responses to imports and exports, which depend on their employer's exposure to trade. Workers in the non-tradable sector are likely to be economically indifferent to the influences of trade per se (as their economic circumstances are unaffected), and therefore we have no expectation that their Mood will move systematically in response to trade.Footnote 44

Our expectation is that increasing import shares will bring forth a leftward shift in policy mood among those employed by import-competing firms and domestically based export-only firms. Both types of firms face import competition without benefiting from internal-to-the-firm imports, and are likely to reduce hours and wages in response to reduced demand. Recognizing this, workers at these firms are likely to demand greater government spending to compensate them for rising economic insecurity. It is the microeconomic conditions facing the workers in these firms, and not unemployment per se, which will likely condition their policy mood preferences.

However, rising exports benefit workers employed by exporting firms, which will lead to a conservative shift in opinion among them. As wages and employment increase, workers are better off, both in terms of current economic well-being and future job security (in other words, risk).

Intrafirm imports and exports, however, generate a new microeconomy for employees of multinationals. These intrafirm imports and exports benefit employees of multinational firms. Jensen, Quinn and Weymouth found that firms that engaged in FDI and subsequent intrafirm trade (that is, offshoring) were far more likely to survive than firms that did not engage in intrafirm importing.Footnote 45 Intrafirm importing and exporting are likely to enhance at least some employees’ job security, leading to a conservative shift in opinion for those employees.

In terms of aggregate shifts in public sentiment, we propose one case in which employees across different types of firms will shift their opinion in opposite directions in response to different types of imports. Intrafirm imports generate a leftward shift in opinion among employees of non-multinationals (as do imports in general), but this is likely to be offset by a competing rightward shift among employees of multinationals, who benefit from intrafirm imports.Footnote 46 Thus the aggregate effect of intrafirm imports on Mood is ambiguous.

We propose these testable implications for the relationship between increased US trade integration and Mood (controlling for other macroeconomic conditions and prior government policies):

Hypothesis 1: Rising imports will produce a liberal shift in Mood.

Hypothesis 2: Rising exports will produce a conservative shift in Mood.

Exports and imports are proposed to have divergent, and therefore offsetting, effects on Mood, which can be summarized in the US trade balance, which is equal to exports minus imports.

Hypothesis 3: Increases (decreases) in the US Balance of Trade will lead to a conservative (liberal) shift in Mood.

Hypothesis 4: Rising non-intrafirm imports will produce a liberal shift in Mood.

Hypothesis 5: Rising intrafirm MNC imports will have, in aggregate, a null effect on Mood.

Hypothesis 6: Increases (decreases) in the US non-intrafirm Balance of Trade will lead to a conservative (liberal) shift in Mood.

Importantly, our argument does not require that people necessarily have a clear causal understanding of how trade flows affect macroeconomic outcomes. The behavior of firms in an open economy has real microeconomic effects in terms of the level of employment, wages, productivity gains and so forth. Citizens do not have to be conscious of the macroeconomic linkages: they can observe the real microclimate around them, make inferences about future income and job security, and respond. Mood among uninformed individuals, as well as among political sophisticates, responds to basic economic cues, though sophisticates may respond more strongly to information.Footnote 47 Moreover, rising sentiments of economic insecurity, regardless of whether the source is clearly known, are likely to have implications for policy preferences.Footnote 48 Thus our argument does not require individuals to have an awareness of the real macroeconomic effects of trade. We will, even so, explore the possibility that trade's effects on Mood occur through a media effects channel.

DATA AND METHODS

In this section, we introduce the data and methods used to test the hypotheses. Although our argument generalizes to other countries, we test it in the context of the United States using annual data from 1956–2011.Footnote 49 As discussed in more detail below, an error correction specification fits the theory and allows us to account for possible unit roots.

The dependent variable is change in policy mood, measured using Stimson's ‘Mood’ (through 2011).Footnote 50 Mood is a measure of global attitudes toward government, which reflects the aggregate public's underlying support for government programs or involvement on a liberal-conservative scale across a variety of issues.Footnote 51 Latent factors are extracted from survey marginals (that is, the percent supporting the liberal position minus those supporting the conservative one) on policy-related survey items using an algorithm similar to principal components analysis.Footnote 52 This produces ‘a composite measure, a weighted average, of survey respondents to many different policy issues’.Footnote 53 Mood is widely used in studies of American public opinion and public sentiment.

US Mood has a main dimension relating to the role and size of government in the economy. We use the change in Mood, which conveys variation along an axis of more or less government, where higher values indicate greater demand for government spending.Footnote 54 We include the lagged level of Mood as an independent variable.

The main independent variables are measures of international economic activity. First we examine the trade balance, which is equal to exports minus imports as a percent of GDP, as is standard in the IPE literature. Because we expect the direction of trade to affect Mood, exports and imports as a percent of GDP are included separately in our main specification. (See the appendix for sources.) Data for US intrafirm exports and imports by US MNCs and US affiliates of foreign firms are available in a continuous series from 1982 onward. We create indicators of non-intrafirm imports and exports as well as indicators of intrafirm imports and exports, also as a percentage of US GDP.Footnote 55

We also include other independent variables shown to influence Mood, including inflation and unemployment.Footnote 56 We use economic growth as a control, as proposed by Durr and Stevenson.Footnote 57 Finally, following Stevenson, we use government social expenditures as a percent of GDP as a proxy for prior policies.Footnote 58

A necessary assumption of standard ordinary least squares (OLS) estimations is that the data are stationary. Many of the series are, however, possibly non-stationary, which can lead to biased inferences or potentially spurious regressions in an OLS framework. The possibility of unit roots in most of the series in levels cannot be rejected. We find, as have other investigators, that Mood potentially has a unit root. So too do the series for exports, imports, level of unemployment and government social expenditures in levels.Footnote 59 Inflation, growth, and changes in unemployment, imports and exports are stationary.

A standard estimation approach to time-series modeling in the presence of possible unit roots are Error Correction (EC) models, as used in Durr; Erikson, MacKuen and Stimson; Kelly and Enns and others.Footnote 60 EC methods are increasingly common in economics and political science in time series models where unit roots are suspected. One of the important properties of EC models is that they allow the dependent variable to respond to short-term changes in independent variables, and exhibit an equilibrium relationship with the longer-term levels of the independent variables. For variables that are in an equilibrium relationship with Mood, a shift in one of these variables causes Mood to shift as well, at an adjustment rate equal to ß1 .

We note that Mood, a bounded variable, is potentially able to be in an equilibrium relationship with imports and exports because the estimated effects of imports and exports on Mood can offset each other. The estimated effect of the US Trade Balance summarizes the joint effects of imports and exports on Mood.

DeBoef and Keele suggest that EC models are also useful when examining the dynamic properties in stationary data.Footnote 61 Regarding model specification, we follow their recommendation to first examine the unrestricted model where variables have both short- and long-run effects. We include the lagged levels (the long-run variables) and the contemporaneous changes (the shock variables) for all independent variables. The unrestricted base EC Model 1 is:

(1) $$no{ {\rm{\rDelta }}\,Moo{{d}_t}\, = \, & {{\beta }_{\rm{0}}}\, + \,{{\beta }_{\rm{1}}}(Moo{{d}_{t{\rm{ - 1}}}})\, + \,{{\beta }_{\rm{2}}}(Inflatio{{n}_{t{\rm{ - 1}}}})\, + \,{{\beta }_{\rm{3}}}({\rm{\rDelta }}\,Inflatio{{n}_t})\, + \,{{\beta }_{\rm{4}}}(Unemploymen{{t}_{t{\rm{ - 1}}}}){} \cr & + \,{{\beta }_{\rm{5}}}({\rm{\rDelta }}Unemploymen{{t}_t})\, + \,{{\beta }_{\rm{6}}}(Growt{{h}_{t{\rm{ - 1}}}})\, + \,{{\beta }_{\rm{7}}}({\rm{\rDelta }}Growt{{h}_t})\, \cr &+ \,{{\beta }_{\rm{8}}}(Social\,Expenditure{{s}_{t{\rm{ - 1}}}}) + \,{{\beta }_{\rm{9}}}({\rm{\rDelta }}Social\,Expenditure{{s}_t})\, \cr & + \,{{\beta }_{{\rm{10}}}}(Import\,share{{s}_{t{\rm{ - 1}}}})\, + \,{{\beta }_{{\rm{11}}}}({\rm{\rDelta }}Import\,share{{s}_t}){} + \,{{\beta }_{{\rm{12}}}}(Export\,share{{s}_{t{\rm{ - 1}}}})\, \cr & + \,{{\beta }_{13}}({\rm{\rDelta }}Export\,share{{s}_t})\, + \,{{{\epsilon}}_t}\,\,\,\,\,\,\,t\, = \,{\rm{1956}}\,{\rm{ - }}\,{\rm{2011}} $$

An alternate version of the model combines the import and export terms in the Trade Balance:

(1′) $$ + \,{{\beta }_{{\rm{10}}}}'(Trade\,Balanc{{e}_{t{\rm{ - 1}}}})\, + \,{{\beta }_{{\rm{11}}}}'(\Delta Trade\,Balanc{{e}_t})$$

To maintain degrees of freedom, we eliminate short-term adjustment terms if their coefficient estimates have t-statistics that never approach or surpass 1.00.

To explore the possibly divergent effects of intrafirm MNC and non-intrafirm trade flows on Mood, we estimate alternative versions of Model 1. The data on intrafirm trade flows is available from 1982, which limits the degrees of freedom and therefore the number of covariates that can enter the model. For non-intrafirm trade flows, we estimate:

(2) $$no{ \rDelta Moo{{d}_t} = \, {{\beta }_{\rm{0}}}\, + \,{{\beta }_{\rm{1}}}(Moo{{d}_{t{\rm{ - 1}}}})\, + \,{{\beta }_{\rm{2}}}(Inflatio{{n}_{t{\rm{ - 1}}}})\, + \,{{\beta }_{\rm{3}}}(\rDelta Inflatio{{n}_t})\, + \,{{\beta }_{\rm{4}}}(Unemploymen{{t}_{t{\rm{ - 1}}}}) \cr \quad + \,{{\beta }_{\rm{5}}}(\rDelta Unemploymen{{t}_t})\, + \,{{\beta }_{\rm{6}}}(Growt{{h}_{t{\rm{ - 1}}}})\, + \,{{\beta }_{\rm{7}}}(\rDelta Growt{{h}_t})\, \cr \quad + \,{{\beta }_{\rm{8}}}(Social\,Expenditure{{s}_{t{\rm{ - 1}}}}) + \,{{\beta }_{\rm{9}}}(\rDelta Social\,Expenditure{{s}_t}) \cr \quad + \,{{\beta }_{{\rm{10}}}}(nonIntrafirm\,Import\,share{{s}_{t{\rm{ - 1}}}})\, + \,{{\beta }_{{\rm{11}}}}(\rDelta nonIntrafirm\,Import\,share{{s}_t}) \cr \quad + \,{{\beta }_{{\rm{12}}}}(nonIntrafirm\,Export\,share{{s}_{t{\rm{ - 1}}}})\, + \,{{\beta }_{{\rm{13}}}}(\rDelta nonIntrafirm\,Export\,share{{s}_t}) \cr \quad + {{{\epsilon}}_t}\; \; \; \; t\, = \,{\rm{1983 - 2011}} $$

For MNC trade flows, we estimate Model 2, substituting:

(2′) $$no{\qquad\qquad + \,{{\beta }_{{\rm{10}}}}'(Intrafirm\,Import\,share{{s}_{t{\rm{ - 1}}}})\, + \,{{\beta }_{{\rm{11}}}}'(\rDelta Intrafirm\,Import\,share{{s}_t}) \cr + \,{{{ß}}_{{\rm{13}}}}'(Intrafirm\,Export\,share{{s}_{t-1}})\, + \,{{ß}_{{\rm{13}}}}'\,(\rDelta Intrafirm\,Export\,share{{s}_t}) $$

Based on the initial results of Models 2 and 2′, we empirically establish a best-fit model. We estimate related models for intrafirm and non-intrafirm trade balances, and follow the same procedures as above.

We estimate error correction models using OLS. The standard errors are Newey-West standard errors, which correct for possible autocorrelation and heteroskedasticity in the error terms.

We address the possibility that an unmeasured factor might drive both trade flows and the policy mood, thereby creating a spurious estimated relationship between trade and Mood. Such a concern is warranted when variables observed by respondents (but unobserved by investigators) are present. Firm-specific technologies and strategies are particularly problematic in this setting, since a firm's decision to import or export might be correlated with its decisions regarding technological innovation or other strategies.

The instrumental variable (IV) approach is the standard way to account for possible omitted variable bias.Footnote 62 The instruments used here for imports, exports and trade balances are the global averages (excluding the United States) of government regulatory restrictions on (1) the ability of non-US citizens to receive payments for US and other imports, (2) the ability of non-US citizens to make payments for US and other exports and (3) the ability of non-US citizens to receive or remit payments on trade in services (respectively). These measures are components of the Quinn-Toyoda index of international financial restrictions, which codes laws and regulations pertaining to cross-border flows of capital using the International Monetary Fund's (IMF) Annual Report on Exchange Arrangements and Exchange Restrictions (AREAER).Footnote 63 We create global averages of restrictions for each of the three payments listed above, excluding data on the United States. We lag these instruments.Footnote 64

The instruments satisfy the exclusion restriction necessary for instrument validity, as the instruments are strongly correlated with the explanatory trade variables but are not correlated with changes in Mood except through the endogenous explanatory variable. That is, the long lags of indicators of global restrictions on exchange payments and receipts for world trade are exceptionally unlikely to be theoretically (or empirically) connected to contemporaneous changes in the US policy mood, but are correlated both theoretically and empirically with US exports and imports: the more liberalized the index, the fewer restrictions there are on trade payments with the United States, and the greater the flow of trade with the United States. In contrast, changes in Mood are unlikely to respond to multiyear lags in global trade financing regulations of countries other than the United States, and global averages of trade financing restrictions are unlikely to respond to expectations about future shifts in the overall US policy mood.

MAIN RESULTS

To examine our theory, we modify a standard model of the domestic determinants of Mood suggested by Erikson, MacKuen and Stimson and Stevenson.Footnote 65 The base variables include inflation, unemployment, economic growth and social spending. In keeping with the recommendation of DeBoef and Keele for error correction models, both short-term change and level terms are entered.Footnote 66

In Model 2.1, we include the trade balance as the first test of our argument. We find that the trade balance has a negative and significant effect on the policy mood, as expected. That is, when the trade balance is negative (that is, imports exceed exports), Mood moves in a liberal direction (−β*−X), and when the trade balance is positive, Mood moves in a conservative direction (−β*X). Change in the trade balance also has a contemporaneous effect; in other words, a shock to the trade balance has an immediate effect on the change in Mood. This provides initial support for our hypothesis that international economic integration affects Mood, though it assumes that exports and imports have a symmetric effect on Mood. In Model 2.2, we test Hypotheses 1 and 2 by including separate measures of imports and exports, as specified in Equation 1. We find that imports have a positive and significant estimated effect on Mood, as hypothesized. The coefficients on both the short- and long-run import terms are positive and statistically significant. Neither exports nor the change in exports have statistically significant effects on Mood, although the coefficient estimate for exports in levels is more than one and a half times the standard error, and the model contains nuisance parameters. In terms of explanatory power, it is difficult to distinguish between the models with the trade balance and separate imports and exports.

Models 2.3 and 2.4 of Table 2 present more parsimonious specifications of our main results, eliminating three nuisance parameters and improving the fit of the models.Footnote 67 As in Model 2.1, the coefficients on trade balance and change in trade balance are negative and statistically significant. Additionally, the coefficient on growth is now negative and statistically significant at the 90 per cent level.

Table 2 Determinants of Mood

*p < 0.1, **p < 0.05, ***p < 0.01. Parentheses contain Newey-West standard errors.

The significance and magnitude of the main coefficient estimates in Model 2.4 are very similar to those in 2.2, except that the change in unemployment now has a positive and statistically significant coefficient estimate. A 1 per cent increase in unemployment shifts Mood by 0.64 points to the left in the current period, the same direction of effect found in Erikson, MacKuen and Stimson.Footnote 68 Imports again have a positive and statistically significant effect on Mood. A 1 per cent increase in imports shifts Mood to the left a total of 2.07 points (β10/(−β1)). Additionally, exports now have a negative and statistically significant effect at the 90 per cent level, as hypothesized. A 1 per cent increase in exports shifts Mood a total of 1.42 points to the right.Footnote 69

The other variables are control variables, but we note that inflation in levels always has a negative and highly statistically significant estimated coefficient, which is consistent with prior expectations. Social spending in levels is negative and statistically significant in all models in Table 2. This is consistent with previous findings in support of thermostatic response to prior policies, and the ‘compensation mechanism’, as discussed above. Change in unemployment has a statistically significant and positive coefficient in the parsimonious models that control for trade flows (Models 2.3 and 2.4), as expected. Though growth has the expected sign in all models except Model 2.2, it does not have a robust statistically significant effect on Mood. In a series of robustness checks (available in the online appendix), we control for additional possible confounding variables, including inequality, technological innovation, media effects and the deficit level. We find continued support for our hypotheses.

In Models 2.5 and 2.6, we include the trade balance, imports and exports, respectively, in the logged-level form, rather than as a share of GDP. We again find support for Hypothesis 3, that an improvement in the trade balance shifts Mood to the right, while rising imports lead to a leftward shift in Mood.Footnote 70

The results of our preferred model specification, two-stage least squares instrumental variables regression with Newey-West standard errors, are provided in Models 2.7 and 2.8 of Table 2. The first-stage regressions of the IV models, which instrument for trade balance, imports and exports as a per cent of GDP, are presented in the online appendix, and show that the various instruments have good explanatory power for the trade variables.Footnote 71 In the second-stage results in Models 2.7 and 2.8, the instrumented trade variables maintain their signs and levels of statistical significance compared to Models 2.3 and 2.4. The coefficient estimates for the instrumented trade variables are larger, and the standard errors are slightly larger compared to the original variables, but the p-value for the t-statistics on the instrumented trade variable in levels remains at less than 0.05. A 1 per cent improvement in the trade balance shifts Mood a total of 2.13 points to the right and, conversely, a 1 per cent decline shifts Mood a total of 2.13 points to the left.Footnote 72 In Model 2.8, the estimated coefficient estimates for exports and imports are larger than for the OLS estimates. A 1 per cent increase in imports shifts Mood a total of 3.14 points to the left, while a 1 per cent increase in exports produces a 4.68-point total shift to the right.Footnote 73 This suggests that hard-to-measure variables that are collinear with the trade variables cause a downward bias in the OLS estimates, which we correct with the instrumenting procedure. As a measure of model fit, we calculate the generalized R2 developed by Pesaran and Smith for instrumental variables regression and apply a correction for the number of parameters.Footnote 74 The results suggest that Model 2.7, which uses the trade balance, performs better than Model 2.8, which uses imports and exports.

In summary, the core results broadly confirm the long-standing view that policy mood is influenced by economic outcomes. New, however, is the finding that increasing globalization of the US economy influences Mood. In particular, imports influence Mood in a manner that is consistent with the ‘compensation’ hypothesis from IPE. When we account for hard-to-measure variables like technological change using IV, exports have a negative and statistically significant effect on Mood. The estimated effects of the trade balance, which summarizes the theorized offsetting effects of exports and imports on Mood, offer modest to substantial improvements in explanatory power compared to the estimated effects of exports and imports separately.

INTRAFIRM TRADE

Heterogeneous firms theory suggests that not all imports and exports have the same distributive consequences. Therefore, we separate intrafirm (MNC) trade from non-intrafirm (non-MNC) trade.Footnote 75 Intrafirm trade data is available between 1982 and 2010. We follow the same guidelines regarding nuisance parameters as above in order to maximize the degrees of freedom. In the interest of space, we limit our discussion to the main independent variables of interest.

Tables 3 and 4 present the results of our analyses that look at intrafirm and non-intrafirm trade as specified by Equation 2 above. In Table 3 we examine the trade balance. Model 3.1 presents the aggregate trade balance model for the sample restricted to 1983–2011 for comparison with the intrafirm models. The trade balance result for the term in levels (3.1) is consistent with the result in Table 2 (2.3), showing that the temporal composition of the sample only modestly influences the trade results. In Model 3.2, we include the trade balance for non-intrafirm trade. We expect an improvement in the non-intrafirm trade balance to shift Mood rightward and, indeed, the coefficient on non-intrafirm trade balance in levels is negative and statistically significant. The coefficient on the contemporaneous effect is not statistically significant. In Model 3.3, we instead include the MNC-intrafirm trade balance, which also has a negative and statistically significant effect on Mood in levels. Model 3.2, which includes non-intrafirm trade, explains 41 per cent of the variation in Mood and has greater explanatory power than models of aggregate trade (Model 3.1) and intrafirm trade (Model 3.3) with adjusted R2s of 0.38 and 0.35, respectively.

Table 3 Intrafirm/Non-intrafirm Trade Balance

*p < 0.1, **p < 0.05, ***p < 0.01. Newey-West standard errors in parentheses.

Table 4 Intrafirm/non-Intrafirm Imports and Exports

*p < 0.1, **p < 0.05, ***p < 0.01. Newey-West standard errors in parentheses.

In Model 3.4, we include the levels of both non-intrafirm and intrafirm trade balance (and drop the contemporaneous terms, which are nuisance parameters). Only the effect of non-intrafirm trade balance is negative and statistically significant, and the effect of the intrafirm trade balance is no longer significant.Footnote 76 This supports Hypothesis 4, which suggests that it is non-intrafirm trade that largely shapes Mood. In Model 3.5, we present our preferred OLS specification, which includes only non-intrafirm trade balances and which improves model fit. We find that non-intrafirm trade balance again has a negative and statistically significant effect on Mood. Overall, Model 3.5 explains 42 per cent of the variation in Mood, which is the highest of the OLS models.

Finally, in Model 3.6 we instrument for non-MNC trade balance using the same instrument as above, and we again find the hypothesized effect regarding imports. A 1 per cent improvement in the trade balance shifts Mood to the right a total of 2.73 points.Footnote 77 The adjusted generalized R2 suggests that the model performs well overall.

In Table 4, we present the analogous results for intrafirm and non-intrafirm imports and exports. In Model 4.1, we find that aggregate imports have a positive and statistically significant effect on Mood for the sample period 1983–2011, which is consistent with our findings in Table 2. In Model 4.2, we include the levels and changes of non-intrafirm imports and exports, and find that non-intrafirm imports have a long-run positive and statistically significant effect on Mood. Similar results are found in Model 4.3, which eliminates nuisance parameters. The coefficient on non-intrafirm imports is positive and statistically significant. The coefficient on non-intrafirm exports is not statistically significant.

Turning to MNC intrafirm imports and exports, Model 4.4 includes the changes in (and levels of) intrafirm imports and exports. None of the intrafirm coefficient estimates is statistically significant, which suggests that the effects of intrafirm and non-intrafirm trade on Mood vary accordingly with heterogeneous firms theory. In Model 4.5 we exclude nuisance parameters and find that the coefficient on intrafirm exports in levels is negative and statistically significant. However, this effect is dominated by the effect of non-intrafirm imports, as shown in Model 4.6, which includes both intrafirm and non-intrafirm imports and exports. The coefficient on non-intrafirm imports is positive and statistically significant, as suggested by Hypothesis 4, while the coefficient on intrafirm imports is not statistically significant, as suggested by Hypothesis 5.Footnote 78 Neither of the estimates for the export terms is statistically significant. A comparison of adjusted R2 suggests that Model 4.3, which contains only the level of non-intrafirm imports, has superior explanatory power.

Finally, in Model 4.7, we instrument for non-intrafirm imports using the instrument described above. We again find that non-intrafirm imports have a positive and statistically significant effect on Mood. A 1 per cent increase in non-intrafirm imports shifts Mood leftward 3.05 points in the long run.Footnote 79 A comparison of the adjusted generalized R2 suggests that Model 3.6 instrumenting for the non-intrafirm trade balance performs slightly better than Model 4.7, which instruments for non-intrafirm imports.

In summary, the results presented in Tables 3 and 4 suggest that intrafirm and non-intrafirm trade flows have different effects on Mood, as hypothesized. We show that underlying the aggregate trade effects, non-intrafirm imports (rather than intrafirm imports) are responsible for producing a leftward shift in Mood. Intrafirm trade flows do not have a robust effect on policy mood.

We note that the effects of inflation and unemployment have changed in Tables 3 and 4, compared to Table 2 and previous findings. In the shorter sample, the estimated coefficient for change in unemployment is no longer statistically significant. Additionally, the coefficient estimate for inflation no longer has a negative long-run effect on Mood; indeed, the contemporaneous effect of inflation is positive and statistically significant in several models in Tables 3 and 4. This is an area for further research.

EXTENSIONS

One possible extension of the analysis is to explore whether changes in US trade flows moderate the relationship between changes in Mood and government social spending.Footnote 80 Scholars have shown that government policy responds to changes in public preferences, particularly regarding government spending. For example, Kang and Powell demonstrate that the median voter's ideology is an important determinant of welfare spending.Footnote 81 The above findings lead us to expect that trade will moderate the effect of Mood on social spending.Footnote 82

Here we present exploratory results that suggest that imports condition the impact of policy mood on changes in social spending. We use error correction methods to model changes in social spending, measured as a percent of GDP. In our basic model specification, we include political and economic variables that routinely appear in studies of spending.Footnote 83 We control for government partisanship using a dummy variable to indicate whether the president is Republican. To capture demand for social spending, we include the percent of the population that is sixty-five year or older. The baseline model is:

(3) $$no{ {\rm{\rDelta }}Social\,Expenditure{{s}_t}\, = \, &amp;#x0026; {{\beta }_{\rm{0}}}\, + \,{{\beta }_{\rm{1}}}(Social\,Expenditure{{s}_{t{\rm{ - 1}}}})\, + \,{{\beta }_{\rm{2}}}(Republican\,Presiden{{t}_{t{\rm{ - 1}}}}) \, \cr + \,{{\beta }_{\rm{3}}}({\rm{\rDelta }}Republican\,President)\, + \,{{\beta }_{\rm{4}}}(PopOver{{65}_{t{\rm{ - 1}}}})\, \cr + \,{{\beta }_{\rm{5}}}({\rm{\rDelta }}PopOver{\rm{6}}{{{\rm{5}}}_t}) \, + \,{{\beta }_{\rm{6}}}(Inflatio{{n}_{t{\rm{ - 1}}}})\, + \,{{\beta }_{\rm{7}}}({\rm{\rDelta }}Inflatio{{n}_t})\, \cr + \,{{\beta }_{\rm{8}}}(Unemploymen{{t}_{t{\rm{ - 1}}}})\, + \,\beta {\rm{9}}({\rm{\rDelta }}Unemploymen{{t}_t}) \, + \,{{\beta }_{{\rm{10}}}}(Growt{{h}_{t{\rm{ - 1}}}})\, \cr + \,{{\beta }_{{\rm{11}}}}({\rm{\rDelta }}Growt{{h}_t})\, + \,{{\beta }_{{\rm{12}}}}(Moo{{d}_{t{\rm{ - 1}}}})\, + \,{{\beta }_{{\rm{13}}}}({\rm{\rDelta }}Moo{{d}_t})\, + \,{{{\epsilon}}_t} \cr t\, = \,{\rm{1961 - 2011}} }$$

To this specification, we add imports and exports, as well as the interaction between imports and Mood. The main results are presented in Table 5. Robustness checks, including additional measures of partisanship and alternative controls, such as deindustrialization, can be found in the online appendix. We limit the discussion to key variables in the interest of space.

Table 5 Determinants of Social Spending, 1961–2011

*p < 0.1, **p < 0.05, ***p < 0.01. Newey-West standard errors in parentheses.

Model 5.1 presents our base model of change in social spending. The estimated coefficient on Mood is positive and statistically significant, which is consistent with previous literature and suggests that a liberal shift in preferences leads to an increase in social spending. Unemployment has a positive and immediate effect on spending. The coefficient on the percent of the population over sixty-five is also positive, as expected, and statistically significant. Model 5.2 eliminates nuisance parameters from Model 5.1, and the coefficient on Mood is again positive and statistically significant.

Next we introduce the trade balance in Models 5.3 and 5.4. The coefficient on trade balance in levels is not statistically significant in Model 5.3, nor is the interaction with Mood statistically significant in Model 5.4.

In Model 5.5, we include the levels of imports and exports; the coefficient estimates on imports and exports in levels are negative, though not statistically significant. Trade flows appear to have no direct effect on changes in social spending, while Mood again has a positive and statistically significant estimated effect on social spending.

In Model 5.6, we include an interaction between Mood and imports. Mood's coefficient estimate is now negative, though the conditional interpretation of the estimate is when imports as a percentage of GDP take the value of zero, which is out of sample. The conditional coefficient on imports is negative and statistically significant, though Mood never approaches zero. The coefficient on the interaction between Mood and imports is positive and statistically significant.

In Figure 1, we present the marginal effect of Mood on spending, conditional on observed levels of imports (accounting for the covariances of the coefficient in computing the standard errors).Footnote 84 The estimated effect of Mood on changes in social spending increases with the level of imports. The marginal effect of Mood is statistically different from zero at levels of imports above approximately 8 per cent of GDP, which has been true for the United States since the mid-1970s. Substantively, a one standard deviation increase in Mood (4.62 points) increases spending by 0.18 per cent and 0.51 per cent at the mean (9.99 per cent) and maximum (17.89 per cent) levels of imports, respectively. (For reference, the dependent variable, change in social spending, ranges from −0.80 to 2.15, with a mean of 0.21 and a standard deviation of 0.52.) The increase in explanatory power in Model 5.6 over the other models is, however, modest.

Fig. 1 Marginal effect of mood on change in social spending, conditional on imports. Note: estimates based on Model 5.6, for observed levels of imports, 1961–2011. Dashed lines represent 95 per cent confidence interval.

These exploratory results suggest that the effect of policy mood on social spending is conditional on the level of imports. In the online appendix, we present analogous results for the shorter sample that look separately at intrafirm and non-intrafirm trade. This is an area for further scholarly investigation.

CONCLUSIONS

The theory and findings presented here have important implications for the relationship between public sentiment and trade globalization in the United States. We ask if, and how, the policy mood of the public toward the role of government responds to the changing nature of the US economy and its trade integration into the world economy. We hypothesize that increasing imports directly shifts the policy mood in a more liberal direction, and that increasing exports shifts it in a more conservative direction.

The evidence strongly shows that Mood responds to rising imports in a manner consistent with our hypotheses, which are derived from findings in the ‘heterogeneous firms’ literature (also known as the ‘new new’ trade theory literature) in international economics and the ‘compensation’ hypothesis studies from the IPE literature. Citizens appear to prefer higher levels of government involvement in the face of deterioration in the US trade position. In particular, rising imports lead to an immediate and long-term leftward shift in Mood. In contrast, rising exports appear to influence Mood in some specifications, though those results appear in specifications (instrumental variable models) that address omitted variable bias. The effects of trade are centered on non-intrafirm imports and exports, a result that is suggested by the ‘new new’ trade theory. We use various methods and changes in the conditioning information in the models to assess the reliability and robustness of the results.

This analysis provides an important link, not only between separate literatures in American politics and IPE, but also between studies of individual preferences and domestic policy outcomes. One area of future research is whether shifts in policy mood, influenced by increasing economic integration, are systematically reflected in domestic spending outcomes. In that vein, we offer some exploratory work showing that imports potentially moderate the effect of Mood on social spending. Exploring whether and how other facets of economic integration, especially international financial integration, influence Mood is another important direction for further work.

APPENDIX: MEASURES AND DATA SOURCES

Economic growth. We estimate models with real growth per capita, which is available from the IMF's International Financial Statistics.

Exports and imports. Exports and imports are as a percentage of GDP from the IMF's International Financial Statistics. These are standard indicators in IPE.Footnote 85 In robustness checks of logged trade flows, for data on aggregate imports and exports prior to 1960 we use UN historical data on trade in goods, and adjust the measure to account for trade in services. However, results are robust to the sample limited to 1960.

US intrafirm exports and imports; non-US intrafirm exports and imports. Intrafirm exports equal the sum of exports from US parents to their foreign affiliates and exports from US affiliates of foreign parents to the foreign parent group. Similarly, intrafirm imports equal the sum of imports of US parents from foreign affiliates and imports by US affiliates of foreign parents. After 2001, the Bureau of Economic Analyses (BEA) surveys were asked only of majority-owned US affiliates of foreign firms. Therefore our data from 2002–10 is based on Ruhl's calculation, which includes non-majority US affiliates of foreign firms. Also note that related party data from the census includes foreign MNC affiliates. See also Bureau of the Census 2006, 2010.

Prior government policies. We follow Stevenson (Reference Stevenson2001) and use government social expenditures as the indicator of prior government policies. The data are government social benefits as a percentage of GDP, and are taken from the BEA website (Table 3.12, line 1).

Inflation and unemployment. The unemployment series is the unemployment rate of economically active individuals from the BEA website; the Consumer Price Index is from the Bureau of Labor Statistics.

GINI coefficients. We take GINI data from the US Census Bureau,Footnote 86 which changed methodology between 1992 and 1993. The Census Bureau notes that it was ‘unable to determine precisely the proportion of the increase in income inequality between 1992 and 1993 that is attributable to this change’.Footnote 87 See Appendix Figure A1 for a visual representation of the magnitude of the effect. To offset the methodological change, we estimate the GINI models with a step indicator starting in 1993.

Fig. A1 Change in US Gini indicators. Note: the figure depicts the effects of a change in census methodology between 1992 and 1993. Source: Department of the Census, ‘Current Population Reports: Selected Measures of Household Income Dispersion, Table A-2’.

Media. The Vanderbilt University Television News ArchiveFootnote 88 is used to construct an index of the salience of international trade. Using ABC, NBC and CBS news broadcasts from 1968 until the present, we collected headline and abstract-level mentions of ‘trade’, ‘trade deficit’, ‘trade surplus’ and ‘trade balance’, and aggregated them by year. We similarly experimented with ‘exports’ and ‘imports’ in the headlines and story abstracts. Data available upon request.

Patents. We use the number of patents awarded, measured in 1,000s.Footnote 89

Skills premium. These data are the ‘composition adjusted college/high-school log weekly wage ratios’ from Figure 1 in Acemoglu and Autor.Footnote 90 The data measure the skill premium paid to more educated workers over time, adjusting for the composition of work.Footnote 91

Footnotes

*

Department of Political Science, Texas A&M; McDonough School of Business, Georgetown University (emails: [email protected]; [email protected]). We thank Mike Bailey, Laura Bondesen, Marc Busch, Martin Evans, Brad Jensen, John Freeman, Paul Kellstedt, Phillip Lane, Stan Nollen, Keith Ord, Maggie Peters, Pietra Rivoli, Bob Shapiro, Steve Weymouth, John Woolley and participants at the Georgetown Political Economy Workshop, International Studies Association 2012, 2010 Midwest Political Science Association Conference, Princeton, WWZ at the University of Basel, Center for International Studies at ETH/Zurich and Georgetown University McDonough School of Business seminars for comments. We thank the journal's editor and anonymous reviewers for their very constructive comments. We also thank Jim Stimson for a discussion of Mood at a 2006 conference at the European University Institute organized by Mark Franklin. We thank Laura McCann and Wilbert Hidalgo for help preparing the manuscript, and Annalisa Quinn for copy-editing. Online appendices and data replication sets are available at http://dx.doi.org/doi: 10.1017/S000712341400009X.

1 See Stimson Reference Stimson1999 [1991].

2 In the United States, see, for example, Erikson, MacKuen, and Stimson (Reference Erikson, MacKuen and Stimson2002); Page and Shapiro (Reference Page and Shapiro1983); Stimson (Reference Stimson1999 [1991]); Stimson, MacKuen, and Erikson (Reference Stimson, MacKuen and Erikson1995); and Wlezien (Reference Wlezien1995). See Burstein (Reference Burstein2003) and Shapiro (Reference Shapiro2011) for a review. In the comparative context, see, for example, Soroka and Wlezien (Reference Soroka and Wlezien2010); Hobolt and Klemmensen (Reference Hobolt and Klemmensen2008). See also, for example, Franklin and Wlezien (Reference Franklin and Wlezien1997) on the influence of voter preferences for European unification and European Union policies, and Quinn and Toyoda (Reference Quinn and Toyoda2007) on the influence of public sentiment on economic globalization.

3 Stimson Reference Stimson2004, 81.

4 Erikson, MacKuen, and Stimson Reference Erikson, MacKuen and Stimson2002.

5 Erikson, MacKuen, and Stimson Reference Erikson, MacKuen and Stimson2002.

8 de Neve (Reference De Neve2014) tests Durr's hypothesis using a measure of the ideology of the median voter as the dependent variable, and finds that income growth produces a liberal shift in ideology.

9 More recently, Kelly and Enns (Reference Kelly and Enns2010) examine the effects of economic inequality on Mood. Their findings suggest that an increase in inequality leads to a conservative shift in the opinion of the American public.

10 Wlezien Reference Wlezien1995; see also Bølstad Reference Bølstad2012.

11 Stevenson Reference Stevenson2001.

12 Erikson, MacKuen, and Stimson Reference Erikson, MacKuen and Stimson2002.

13 BEA 2011; Heston, Summers, and Aten Reference Heston, Summers and Aten2006.

14 Bernard, Jensen, and Schott Reference Bernard, Jensen and Schott2009.

15 The analyses are based on the authors’ calculation from Ruhl (Reference Ruhl2013); BEA Balance of Payments tables; and Jensen, Quinn, and Weymouth (Reference Jensen, Quinn and Weymouth2013).

16 The intrafirm trading data are taken from Ruhl (Reference Ruhl2013) and BEA. Intrafirm transactions are defined, as is standard, by an equity ownership of at least 10 per cent by one of the parties of the other party in the transaction. That is, intrafirm trading by definition must follow from FDI. ‘Related Party’ transactions include intrafirm trading, but the Census Bureau has a 6 per cent equity threshold and allows for other contractual considerations for a trade's inclusion in ‘related party’ trades. For an exceptionally clear review of the data and issues, see Ruhl (Reference Ruhl2013).

17 See especially Ruhl (Reference Ruhl2013).

18 The ‘new new’ trade theory is in contrast to intra- and inter-industry trade predicted by new and neoclassical trade theory, respectively. Intra-industry trade is conceived of as trade between nations with similar capital-labor ratios and similar comparative advantages: the US trade in pharmaceutical products with Switzerland is an example. Inter-industry trade is conceived as a trade between nations with different capital-labor ratios and different comparative advantages: the US trade in textiles with China is an example. Inter-industry effects are referred to as Heckscher-Olin ‘factor endowment’ effects. See, for example, Mayda and Rodrik (Reference Mayda and Rodrik2005) and Helpman (Reference Helpman2014) for a review. See also Bernard et al. Reference Bernard, Jensen, Redding and Schott2007; Melitz Reference Melitz2003.

19 Yeaple's (Reference Yeaple2009) study examines US firms using the BEA database. Tomiura's (Reference Tomiura2007) study examines 118,000 Japanese manufacturing firms.

20 Ramondo, Rappoport, and Ruhl Reference Ramondo, Rappoport and Ruhl2013.

22 Bernard, Jensen, and Schott Reference Bernard, Jensen and Schott2006.

23 Bernard and Jensen Reference Bernard and Jensen1999.

24 See Gawande, Hoekman, and Cui (Reference Gawande, Hoekman and Cui2014); Helpman, Melitz, and Yeaple (Reference Helpman, Melitz and Yeaple2004); and Ramondo, Rappoport, and Ruhl (Reference Ramondo, Rappoport and Ruhl2013) for discussions.

25 Ramondo, Rappoport, and Ruhl (Reference Ramondo, Rappoport and Ruhl2013) examine manufacturing industries and create an index of intrafirm ‘intensity’. Aggregating data to the two-digit International Standard Industry (ISI) groupings, they show that firms at the 75th percentile of intrafirm intensity have very similar intensity rankings across the entire range of manufacturing industries (Table 6, Panel 1, p. 30). They also find extensive heterogeneity in the intensity of intrafirm trade within three-digit NAICS-ISI industry codes, which is available in an online appendix (accessed at http://personal.lse.ac.uk/rappopor/research.html). Their results offer strong support for FDI and intrafirm trade being a source of intra-industry heterogeneity among firms across a very wide array of industries.

26 Kletzer Reference Kletzer2001.

27 Kletzer Reference Kletzer2001, 4.

28 Autor, Dorn, and Hanson Reference Autor, Dorn and Hanson2013, 2122.

29 Gawande, Hoekman, and Cui (Reference Gawande, Hoekman and Cui2014) found that extensive MNC value chains decreased the likelihood of increasing tariffs during the 2008 financial crisis. Jensen, Quinn, and Weymouth (Reference Jensen, Quinn and Weymouth2013) found that increasing levels of related party (arm's length) imports into the United States were associated with marked decreases (increases) in antidumping trade filings, and with whether the International Trade Agency denied (affirmed) the trade dispute filing.

30 The notion of compensation in international relations comes from the embedded liberalism literature, which suggests that governments can ‘compensate’ citizens for rising insecurity associated with international economic integration in exchange for continued support for openness (Ruggie Reference Ruggie1982). In the American politics literature, social spending is one proxy for prior policies to which citizens respond thermostatically (for example, Stevenson Reference Stevenson2001; Wlezien Reference Wlezien1995). However, social spending is also a mechanism of compensation, such that at higher levels of social spending, citizens feel more secure and thus demand less government spending.

31 Kim Reference Kim2007, 181.

32 Scheve and Slaughter Reference Scheve and Slaughter2004, 662.

35 Rehm Reference Rehm2010; see also Rehm, Hacker, and Schlesinger Reference Rehm, Hacker and Schlesinger2012.

36 The substantive interpretation is that, for example, a one-standard-deviation change in non-intrafirm imports is equal to 1.8 per cent of US GDP.

37 Respondents who favored free trade if the ‘government [has] programs to help workers who lose their jobs’ were 66, 73, 60 and 43 per cent of the 1999, 2002, 2004 and 2006 samples in surveys by the Program on International Policy Attitudes (PIPA), Council on Foreign Relations (CCFR), PIPA and CCFR, respectively.

38 For example, in the Chicago Council of Foreign Relations survey of July 2004, 64 per cent of respondents said that international trade was bad for job security, and 56 per cent reported that trade was bad for creating jobs (CCFR 2006 [2004], 41; CCFR 2007; Kull Reference Kull2004).

39 Ehrlich Reference Ehrlich2010.

40 Walter Reference Walter2010; see also Guisinger Reference Guisinger2009; Scheve and Slaughter Reference Scheve and Slaughter2001.

42 A vigorous academic debate has emerged over whether technological change per se or trade is more responsible for returns to skilled and unskilled labor in the United States. The conventional wisdom suggests that technological change is the key determinant (Krugman Reference Krugman2000), although recent work suggests that globalization factors also contribute to a rising skill premium (Burstein and Vogel Reference Burstein and Vogel2010).

43 This is in contrast to the notion of ‘parallel publics’, in which different subgroups have different levels of preferences, but change in a similar fashion (Page and Shapiro Reference Page and Shapiro1992). Page and Shapiro examine differences across subgroups based on political education. See also Althaus Reference Althaus2003; Enns and Kellstedt Reference Enns and Kellstedt2008; Erikson, MacKuen, and Stimson Reference Erikson, MacKuen and Stimson2002.

44 Baker (Reference Baker2005) suggests that trade liberalization increases the price of goods using intensively the abundant factor, and decreases the price of those using intensively the scarce factor. Thus trade increases the consumption of labor-intensive goods in the United States, which is likely to benefit low-income workers in non-tradable sectors. An empirical implication would therefore be that rising imports lead to a rightward shift in Mood among this group. However, his findings at the individual level suggest that low-skill workers in the skill-abundant countries in particular tend to be protectionist, and that the poor are no more or less protectionist than the rich.

45 Jensen, Quinn, and Weymouth (Reference Jensen, Quinn and Weymouth2013) find that, of the 290,000 manufacturing firms extant in 1993, more than 200,000 had failed or merged by 2009. Employment in manufacturing declined by 5.5 million between 1993 and 2009. Of the employees of the firms that did survive until 2009, only 22 per cent (or 1.9 million workers) worked for purely domestically oriented firms (compared to 5.7 million employees in 1993 working in domestic-only firms). This suggests that (1) firms that did not offshore were less likely to survive and (2) the size of the conservative offset among MNC employees regarding intrafirm imports may be substantial.

46 For example, consider that in 1993, 59.3 per cent of all US manufacturing employees worked for MNCs engaged in intrafirm importing, while 31 per cent of US manufacturing employees worked for domestic-only firms, with an additional 10 per cent working for export-only US firms. The preferences of these workers, we believe, are likely to offset each other in the aggregate. These calculations are derived from publicly available data reported in Jensen, Quinn, and Weymouth Reference Jensen, Quinn and Weymouth2013.

47 Enns and Kellstedt Reference Enns and Kellstedt2008.

49 Firm production structures are ‘sticky’ and do not respond quickly to shifts in trade patterns (Campa and Goldberg Reference Campa and Goldberg2001), making annual data, rather than quarterly data, more appropriate for this study. We also note that the error structure of the quarterly Mood series is complex with evidence of long-lagged autoregressive properties. Details are available from the authors.

50 Downloaded from http://www.unc.edu/~cogginse/Policy_Mood.html. We use Release 2.13.12 with one dimension estimated. We commence the study in 1956, consistent with Erikson, MacKuen, and Stimson (Reference Erikson, MacKuen and Stimson2002) and Stimson, MacKuen, and Erikson (Reference Stimson, MacKuen and Erikson1995), using the Mood data for 1955 for the lagged level in the analysis. Erikson, MacKuen, and Stimson (Reference Erikson, MacKuen and Stimson2002) show that the first years are estimated with very little public opinion data (219).

51 Erikson, MacKuen and Stimson Reference Erikson, MacKuen and Stimson2002.

52 See Stimson (Reference Stimson1999 [1991]) for a detailed discussion of the measurement and estimation of Mood.

53 Erikson, MacKuen, and Stimson Reference Erikson, MacKuen and Stimson2002, 222.

54 In our sample, Mood ranges from 50.1 to 67.6 (on scale of 0 to 100) and has a mean of 58.9 and standard deviation of 4.4.

55 See Ruhl (Reference Ruhl2013) and Zeile (Reference Zeile2003) for details.

56 Erikson, MacKuen, and Stimson Reference Erikson, MacKuen and Stimson2002.

58 See Jacoby (Reference Jacoby2000) for a discussion of public opinion responses to government spending.

59 Details of the unit root tests are available from the authors.

60 Durr Reference Durr1993; Erikson, MacKuen and Stimson Reference Erikson, MacKuen and Stimson2002; Kelly and Enns Reference Kelly and Enns2010.

61 DeBoef and Keele Reference DeBoef and Keele2008.

62 Endogeneity between changes in Mood and prior trade flows is unlikely, because prior levels of US imports and exports are unlikely to respond in anticipation of future changes in Mood.

63 In AREAER, the IMF reviews laws governing current and capital account payments and receipts. It is organized by current account restrictions (e.g., on payments for goods and services) and capital account restrictions (e.g., on payments for capital), and by ‘exchange payments’ and ‘exchange receipts’. Under ‘exchange receipts’, the IMF reports the restrictions on the proceeds of exports of goods transactions, and under ‘exchange payments’ it reports restrictions on residents’ ability to pay for imports. Quinn (Reference Quinn1997) created quantitative indicators of the intensity of restrictions from a coding of the texts. Similar indicators are created for trade in services. See Quinn (Reference Quinn1997), Quinn and Toyoda (Reference Quinn and Toyoda2007) and Quinn, Schindler, and Toyoda (Reference Quinn, Schindler and Toyoda2011) for a detailed description of the procedures used and for a comparison with other indicators.

64 Based on information criteria tests, the sixth lags of export receipt restrictions (for imports into the United States) and services trade restrictions (for trade balance), and the second lag of import payments (for exports from the United States) are used as instruments. Further details available upon request.

65 Erikson, MacKuen, and Stimson Reference Erikson, MacKuen and Stimson2002; Stevenson Reference Stevenson2001.

66 DeBoef and Keele Reference DeBoef and Keele2008. See Table A1 in the online appendix for a replication and extension of Erikson, MacKuen, and Stimson (Reference Erikson, MacKuen and Stimson2002).

67 We eliminate short-term adjustment terms whose coefficient estimates have t-statistics that never approach or surpass 1.00: change in exports, change in economic growth and change in social expenditures. The elimination of nuisance parameters improves the adjusted R2.

68 Erikson, MacKuen, and Stimson Reference Erikson, MacKuen and Stimson2002.

69 The 95 per cent confidence intervals for imports and exports are [1.12, 3.01] and [−2.88, 0.04], respectively.

70 See the Appendix for a discussion of the construction of this series. A concern might be that when trade flows are measured as a percentage of GDP, changes in the denominator might influence the estimated relationship, a concern that the use of the logged trade series obviates. The core results are also robust to the inclusion of lags of national income, or income and income squared in the estimations.

71 To be useful, the IV analysis must satisfy the exclusion restriction, which is that the instrument is strongly correlated with our independent variable but is not correlated with the dependent variable except through the endogenous explanatory variable. The instruments are uncorrelated with changes in Mood. The level of restrictions in the United States is constant from 1960 to 2010, the period for which the data is available.

72 The 95 per cent confidence interval for the coefficient on the trade balance is [−3.83, −0.43].

73 The 95 per cent confidence intervals for the effects of imports and exports are [1.19, 5.09] and [−7.60, −1.76], respectively.

74 Pesaran and Smith Reference Pesaran and Smith1994. The code (in STATA 13) necessary to replicate the adjusted generalized R2 is available in the online replication data set.

76 A linear hypothesis test is able to reject the null hypothesis that the coefficients on intrafirm and non-intrafirm trade balance are the same. This helps alleviate concerns about multicollinearity.

77 The 95 per cent confidence interval is [−3.73, −1.72].

78 We thank an anonymous reviewer for raising the point that multicollinearity may explain why the coefficient on the intrafirm imports is no longer statistically significant and thus limit our ability to find support for Hypotheses 4 and 5. Although a linear hypothesis test is unable to distinguish between the coefficients on intrafirm and non-intrafirm imports in this model, results from the analysis of the trade balance in Model 3.4 suggests that it is the non-intrafirm trade balance which shapes Mood.

79 The 95 per cent confidence interval is [2.09, 4.01].

80 We thank an anonymous reviewer for this suggestion.

81 Kang and Powell Reference Kang and Powell2010; see also Soroka and Wlezien Reference Soroka and Wlezien2010. Other scholars studying dynamic representation have examined the responsiveness of prior policies and budget appropriations to aggregate public opinion. See, for example, Erikson, MacKuen, and Stimson (Reference Erikson, MacKuen and Stimson2002) and Wlezien (Reference Wlezien2004), respectively.

82 We find no evidence of Mood either moderating or mediating the effects of trade flows on social expenditures. Additional details are available upon request.

83 See, for example, Burgoon Reference Burgoon2001; Hays Reference Hays2009; Rickard Reference Rickard2006; Soroka and Wlezien Reference Soroka and Wlezien2010.

84 See Friedrich Reference Friedrich1982.

85 See Swank Reference Swank2006.

87 Jones and Weinberg Reference Jones Arthur and Weinberg2000, 1.

90 Acemoglu and Autor Reference Acemoglu and Autor2011.

References

REFERENCES

Acemoglu, Daron Autor, David. 2011. Skills, Tasks and Technologies: Implications for Employment and Earnings. In Handbook of Labor Economics, Volume 4, edited by Orley Ashenfelter and David E. Card, 10431171. Amsterdam: Elsevier.Google Scholar
Aldrich, John, Kramer, Claire, Lange, Peter, Levine, Renan, Merrolla, Jennifer, Stephenson, Laura, Zechmeister, Elizabeth. ND. In Pursuit of the Missing Link. Presented at the 2002 Annual Meeting of the Political Science Association, Boston, MA.Google Scholar
Althaus, Scott. 2003. Collective Preferences in Democratic Politics. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Autor, David H., Dorn, David Hanson, Gordon H.. 2013. The China Syndrome: Local Labor Market Effects of Import Competition in the United States. American Economic Review 103 (6):21212168.Google Scholar
Baker, Andrew. 2005. Who Wants to Globalize? Consumer Tastes and Labor Markets in a Theory of Trade Policy Beliefs. American Journal of Political Science 49 (4):924938.Google Scholar
Bernard, Andrew B. Jensen, J. Bradford. 1999. Exceptional Exporter Performance: Cause, Effect, or Both? Journal of International Economics 47:125.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bernard, Andrew B., Jensen, J. Bradford, Redding, Stephen J. Schott, Peter K.. 2007. Firms in International Trade. The Journal of Economic Perspectives 21 (3):105130.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bernard, Andrew, Jensen, J. Bradford Schott, Peter K.. 2006. Survival of the Best Fit: Exposure to Low-Wage Countries and the (Uneven) Growth of U.S. Manufacturing Plants. Journal of International Economics 68:219237.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bernard, Andrew B., Jensen, J. Bradford Schott, Peter K.. 2009. Importers, Exporters, and Multinationals: A Portrait of Firms in the U.S. that Trade Goods. In Producer Dynamics: New Evidence from Micro Data, edited by T. Dunne, J. Bradford Jensen, and M. J. Roberts, 133163. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
Bølstad, Jørgen. 2012. Thermostatic Voting: Presidential Elections in Light of New Policy Data. PS: Political Science and Politics 45 (1):4450.Google Scholar
Bureau of the Census. 2010 [2006]. U.S. Goods Trade: Imports and Exports by Related-Parties. Washington, DC: US Census Department News.Google Scholar
Bureau of Economic Analysis (BEA). 2011. National Economic Accounts: Table 3. Available from http://www.bea.gov/newsreleases/national/gdp/gdpnewsrelease.htm, accessed 13 April 2014.Google Scholar
Bureau of Labor Statistics (BLS). 2011. Multifactor Productivity Tables: Historical Multifactor Productivity Measures. Available from http://www.bls.gov/mfp/mprdload.htm, accessed 13 April 2014.Google Scholar
Burgoon, Brian. 2001. Globalization and Welfare Compensation: Disentangling the Ties That Bind. International Organization 55 (3):509551.Google Scholar
Burstein, Ariel, Vogel, Jonathan. 2010. Globalization, Technology, and the Skill Premium: A Quantitative Analysis. NBER Working Paper No. 16459. Department of Economics, University of California, Los Angeles.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Burstein, Paul. 2003. The Impact of Public Opinion on Public Policy: A Review and an Agenda. Political Research Quarterly 56:2940.Google Scholar
Campa, Jose M. Goldberg, Linda S.. 2001. Employment Versus Wage Adjustments and the U.S. Dollar. Review of Economics and Statistics 83 (3):477489.Google Scholar
Chicago Council on Foreign Relations (CCFR). 2006 [2004]. Global Views 2004: American Public Opinion and Foreign Policy. Chicago: CCFR.Google Scholar
De Neve, Jan-Emmanuel. 2014. Ideological Change and the Economics of Voting Behavior in the US, 1920–2008. Electoral Studies 34 (4):2738.Google Scholar
DeBoef, Suzanna Keele, Luke. 2008. Taking Time Seriously. American Journal of Political Science 52 (1):184200.Google Scholar
Durr, Robert H. 1993. What Moves Policy Sentiment? American Political Science Review 87:158170.Google Scholar
Ehrlich, Sean. 2010. Who Supports Compensation? Individual Preferences for Trade-Related Unemployment Insurance. Business and Politics 12 (1):124.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Enns, Peter K. Kellstedt, Paul M.. 2008. Policy Mood and Political Sophistication: Why Everybody Moves Mood. British Journal of Political Science 38 (3):433454.Google Scholar
Erikson, Robert S., MacKuen, Michael B. Stimson, James A.. 2002. The Macro Polity. New York: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Franklin, Mark N. Wlezien, Christopher. 1997. The Responsive Public: Issue Salience, Policy Change, and Preferences for European Unification. Journal of Theoretical Politics 9 (3):347363.Google Scholar
Friedrich, Robert J. 1982. In Defense of Multiplicative Terms in Multiple Regression Equations. American Journal of Political Science 26:797833.Google Scholar
Gawande, Kishore, Hoekman, Bernard Cui, Yue. 2014. Global Supply Chains and Trade Policy Responses to the 2008 Crisis. World Bank Economic Review doi: 10.1093/wber/lht040.Google Scholar
Guisinger, Alexandra. 2009. Determining Trade Policy: Do Voters Hold Politicians Accountable? International Organization 63 (3):553557.Google Scholar
Hays, Jude. 2009. Globalization and the New Politics of Embedded Liberalism. New York: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Helpman, Elhanan. 2014. “Foreign Trade and Investment: Firm-Level Perspectives”. Economica 81 (1):114.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Helpman, Elhanan, Melitz, Marc J. Yeaple, S. R.. 2004. Export Versus FDI with Heterogeneous Firms. American Economic Review 94 (1):300316.Google Scholar
Heston, A., Summers, R., Aten, B.. 2006. The Penn World Table, Version 6.2. Center for International Comparisons of Production, Income and Prices at the University of Pennsylvania, September.Google Scholar
Hobolt, Sara Binzer Klemmensen, Robert. 2008. Government Responsiveness and Political Competition in Comparative Perspective. Comparative Political Studies 41 (3):309337.Google Scholar
Jacoby, William. 2000. Issue Framing and Public Opinion on Government Spending. American Journal of Political Science 44:750767.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Jensen, J. Bradford, Quinn, Dennis P., Weymouth, Stephen 2013. Global Supply Chains, Currency Undervaluation, and Firm Protectionist Demands. NBER Working Paper No. 19239. McDonough School of Business, Georgetown University, Washington, D.C.Google Scholar
Jr.Jones Arthur, F., Weinberg, Daniel H.. 2000. The Changing Shape of the Nation's Income Distribution, 1947–1998. Current Population Reports. Washington, DC: US Census Bureau.Google Scholar
Kang, Shin-Goo JrPowell, G. Bingham. 2010. Representation and Policy Responsiveness: The Median Voter, Election Rules, and Redistributive Welfare Spending. Journal of Politics 72 (4):10141028.Google Scholar
Kelly, Nathan J. Enns, Peter K.. 2010. Inequality and the Dynamics of Public Opinion: The Self-Reinforcing Link Between Economic Inequality and Mass Preferences. American Journal of Political Science 54 (4):855870.Google Scholar
Kim, Heemin Fording, Richard. 1998. Voter Ideology in Western Democracies, 1946–89. European Journal of Political Research 33:7398.Google Scholar
Kim, So Young. 2007. Openness, External Risk, and Volatility: Implications for the Compensation Hypothesis. International Organization 61 (1):181216.Google Scholar
Kletzer, Lori. 2001. Job Loss from Imports: Measuring the Costs. Washington, DC: Institute for International Economics.Google Scholar
Krugman, Paul R. 2000. Trade, Technology and Factor Prices. Journal of International Economics 50 (1):5171.Google Scholar
Kull, Stephen. 2004. Americans on Globalization, Trade, and Farm Subsidies. The American Public on International Issues: The PIPA/Knowledge Networks Poll. Available from http://www.worldpublicopinion.org, accessed 13 April 2014.Google Scholar
Margalit, Yotam. 2011. Costly Jobs: Trade-Related Layoffs, Government Compensation, and Voting in U.S. Elections. American Political Science Review 105 (1):166188.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mayda, Anna Maria Rodrik, Dani. 2005. Why are Some People (and Countries) More Protectionist than Others? European Economic Review 49:13931430.Google Scholar
Melitz, Marc J. 2003. The Impact of Intra-Industry Reallocations and Aggregate Industry Productivity. Econometrica 71 (6):16951725.Google Scholar
Page, Benjamin I. Shapiro, Robert Y.. 1983. Effects of Public Opinion on Policy. American Political Science Review 77:175190.Google Scholar
Page, Benjamin L. Shapiro, Robert Y.. 1992. The Rational Public: Fifty Years of Trends in Americans’ Policy Preferences. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Pesaran, M. Hashem Smith, Richard J.. 1994. A Generalized R2 Criterion for Regression Models Estimated by the Instrumental Variables Method. Econometrica 62 (3):705710.Google Scholar
Program on International Policy Attitudes (PIPA). 2002. Americans on Globalization: Questionnaire and Results. Washington, D.C.: Program on International Policy Attitudes.Google Scholar
Quinn, Dennis. 1997. The Correlates of Change in International Financial Regulation. American Political Science Review 91 (3):531551.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Quinn, Dennis P. Toyoda, A. Maria. 2007. Ideology and Voter Sentiment as Determinants of Financial Globalization. American Journal of Political Science 51:344363.Google Scholar
Quinn, Dennis P., Schindler, Martin Toyoda, A. Maria. 2011. Assessing Measures of Financial Openness and Integration. IMF Economic Review 56 (3):488522.Google Scholar
Ramondo, Natalia, Rappoport, Veronica, Ruhl, Kim J.. 2013. Horizontal Versus Vertical Foreign Direct Investment: Evidence from U.S. Multinationals. Working Paper, University of California at San Diego.Google Scholar
Rehm, Philipp. 2010. Risk Inequality and the Polarized American Electorate. British Journal of Political Science 41 (2):363387.Google Scholar
Rehm, Phillipp, Hacker, Jacob Schlesinger, Mark. 2012. Insecure Alliances: Risk, Inequality and Support for the Welfare State. American Political Science Review 106 (2):386406.Google Scholar
Rickard, Stephanie J. 2006. The Costs of Risk: Examining the Missing Link Between Globalization and Social Spending. Institute for International Integration Studies Discussion Paper No. 185. Department of Government, London School of Economics.Google Scholar
Rickard, Stephanie J.. 2012. Globalization with Compensation: Congressional Votes on Trade and Spending. Working Paper, London School of Economics.Google Scholar
Ruggie, John. 1982. International Regimes, Transactions, and Change: Embedded Liberalism in the Postwar Economic Order. International Organization 36 (2):203223.Google Scholar
Ruhl, Kim J. 2013. An Overview of U.S. Intrafirm-Trade Data Sources. Working Paper, New York University.Google Scholar
Scheve, Kenneth Slaughter, Matthew J.. 2001. What Determines Individual Trade-Policy Preferences? Journal of International Economics 54 (2):267292.Google Scholar
Scheve, Kenneth Slaughter, Matthew J.. 2004. Economic Insecurity and the Globalization of Production. American Journal of Political Science 48:662674.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Shapiro, Robert Y. 2011. Public Opinion and American Democracy. Public Opinion Quarterly 75 (5):9821015.Google Scholar
Soroka, Stuart Wlezien, Christopher. 2010. Degrees of Democracy: Politics, Public Opinion and Policy. New York: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Stevenson, Randolph. 2001. The Economy and Policy Preference: A Fundamental Dynamic of Democratic Politics. American Journal of Political Science 45 (3):620633.Google Scholar
Stimson, James A. 1999 [1991]. Public Opinion in America: Moods, Cycles, and Swings, 2nd Edition. Boulder, CO: Westview Press.Google Scholar
Stimson, James A. 2004. Tides of Consent: How Public Opinion Shapes American Politics. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Stimson, James A., MacKuen, Michael B. Erikson, Robert S.. 1995. Dynamic Representation. American Political Science Review 89:543565.Google Scholar
Swank, Duane. 2006. Tax Policy in an Era of Internationalization: Explaining the Spread of Neoliberalism. International Organization 60 (4):847882.Google Scholar
Tomiura, Eiichi. 2007. Foreign Outsourcing, Exporting, and FDI: A Productivity Comparison at the Firm Level. Journal of International Economics 72 (1):113127.Google Scholar
Walter, Stephanie. 2010. Globalization and the Welfare State: Testing the Microfoundations of the Compensation Hypothesis. International Studies Quarterly 54 (2):403426.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wlezien, Christopher. 1995. The Public as Thermostat: Dynamics of Preferences for Spending. American Journal of Political Science 40:9811000.Google Scholar
Wlezien, Christopher. 2004. Patterns of Representation: Dynamics of Public Preferences and Policy. Journal of Politics 66 (1):124.Google Scholar
Yeaple, Stephen Ross. 2009. Firm Heterogeneity and the Structure of U.S. Multinational Activity. Journal of International Economics 78 (2):206215.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Zeile, William J. 2003. Trade in Goods Within Multinational Companies: Survey-Based Data and Findings for the United States of American. Paper prepared for the Working Party on Statistics, OECD Committee on Industry and Business Environment, 3–4 November.Google Scholar
Figure 0

Table 1 Macroeconomic and Microeconomic Conditions Affecting Mood

Figure 1

Table 2 Determinants of Mood

Figure 2

Table 3 Intrafirm/Non-intrafirm Trade Balance

Figure 3

Table 4 Intrafirm/non-Intrafirm Imports and Exports

Figure 4

Table 5 Determinants of Social Spending, 1961–2011

Figure 5

Fig. 1 Marginal effect of mood on change in social spending, conditional on imports. Note: estimates based on Model 5.6, for observed levels of imports, 1961–2011. Dashed lines represent 95 per cent confidence interval.

Figure 6

Fig. A1 Change in US Gini indicators. Note: the figure depicts the effects of a change in census methodology between 1992 and 1993. Source: Department of the Census, ‘Current Population Reports: Selected Measures of Household Income Dispersion, Table A-2’.

Supplementary material: PDF

Owen and Quinn Supplementary Material

Appendix

Download Owen and Quinn Supplementary Material(PDF)
PDF 400.1 KB
Supplementary material: File

Owen and Quinn Supplementary Material

Supplementary Material

Download Owen and Quinn Supplementary Material(File)
File 78.3 KB