Hostname: page-component-586b7cd67f-r5fsc Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-11-20T06:42:37.711Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Accommodating China's Floating Population: Local Variations and Determinants of Housing Policies for Rural Migrant Workers

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  08 December 2022

Chenhong Peng
Affiliation:
Department of Social Work and Social Administration, The University of Hong Kong, Hong Kong SAR, China,
Julia Shu-Huah Wang*
Affiliation:
Department of Social Work, National Taiwan University, Taiwan
*
Corresponding author: Julia Shu-Huah Wang, email: [email protected]
Rights & Permissions [Opens in a new window]

Abstract

What are the various ways in which local governments in China accommodate migrants through housing policies, and what are the forces that drive these variations? Through systematic coding of policy documents from 97 prefecture-level cities, this study captures the patterns of migrant housing policies using cluster analysis. We found that 18.6 per cent of the cities adopted a residual approach. Most cities adopted a rental-based approach (public and private rental, and collective rental) that could only meet migrants’ short-term housing needs. Only a few cities (12.4 per cent) adopted a citizenship-oriented approach, which best fits the central government's overarching goal of facilitating migrant workers’ long-term settlement in the host cities. Regression analyses examining the determinants of local migrant housing policies showed that the policy variations were not only shaped by economic and political concerns but also the salience of urban issues (problem-solving functions) and previous welfare generosity (path-dependency tendencies).

摘要

摘要

中国的地方政府采取了怎样不同的农民工住房政策?什么因素影响了这些政策的差异性?本文先对 97 个地级市的住房政策文件进行系统地编码,然后采用聚类分析的方法对各城市的农民工住房政策进行分类,最后采用回归分析的方法探究政策差异的影响因素。聚类分析发现,18.6% 的城市采取了“残补式”政策。大部分城市采取只能满足农民工短期住房需求的租赁为主的政策(如“公共或私人租赁房”和“集中式租赁房”)。只有少数城市(12.4%)采取了有利于促进农民工在城市定居的”市民化导向”的政策。回归分析发现,政策的差异性不仅受政治和经济因素影响,还受到当地城市问题的突出性和先前福利的慷慨性影响。

Type
Research Article
Creative Commons
Creative Common License - CCCreative Common License - BY
This is an Open Access article, distributed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution licence (https://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/), which permits unrestricted re-use, distribution, and reproduction in any medium, provided the original work is properly cited.
Copyright
Copyright © The Author(s), 2022. Published by Cambridge University Press on behalf of SOAS University of London

Although rural-to-urban migrants (nongmingong 农民工), also termed “migrant workers,” have contributed significantly to China's recent sustained economic growth, their housing needs received little attention from the government until October 2014, when the State Council issued its “Opinions on bringing further success to the work of providing services to migrant workers” (2014 Opinions, hereafter). This initiative proposed the establishment of a government-led, multiagency migrant housing system, comprising government, employers and the informal and formal housing markets, to improve migrant workers’ housing conditions. In response to the central government's 2014 initiative, local governments promulgated corresponding, city-level proposals. Social policy provision is decentralized in China: the central government sets the policy framework for the whole country, but local governments have discretion to adjust the policy design to fit local conditions.Footnote 1 To what extent do local governments’ migrant housing policies vary, and what are the forces that drive such variations? This study empirically addresses these questions by examining the local patterns of migrant housing policies across 97 cities and investigating their associations with economic, political, housing and social factors.

In 2019, there were an estimated 290.8 million rural migrants in China. Almost half of them were rural-to-urban migrants (135 million).Footnote 2 Despite their vital contribution to China's economic advancement, migrant workers are subjected to discriminatory “secondary citizen” status in cities owing to the hukou 户口 (household registration) system, which affords rural and urban residents different basic rights.Footnote 3 Without an urban hukou, migrant workers are not entitled to social welfare benefits in cities and are excluded from almost all sources of housing welfare programmes. Many rent informal private housing in “urban villages” (chengzhongcun 城中村) or live in employer-provided dormitories. It is well documented that migrant workers’ housing conditions are inferior to those of local residents.Footnote 4 For example, in coastal cities the per capita living space of migrant workers was 15.4 m2 in 2014, compared with 26.5 m2 for local residents in 2010.Footnote 5 The proportions of households having a private kitchen (38 per cent of migrant households versus 84 per cent of urban resident households), bathroom (65 per cent versus 84 per cent) and natural gas (24 per cent versus 97 per cent) reveal the suboptimal living conditions of migrant workers compared to local residents.

Migrant workers’ housing needs were largely ignored by central government until 2006, when the centre declared its goal to build a “harmonious society” (hexieshehui 和谐社会). This new idea has “drawn much attention to policy and institutional reforms, and assisted [in] facilitating and protecting ‘basic housing rights’ of all residents, including migrants.”Footnote 6 In January 2006, the central government issued its “Several opinions on the settling issues of rural migrant workers” (2006 Opinions hereafter), which, for the first time, recognized the need to improve migrants’ housing conditions. However, the turning point for migrant policies came with the announcement of the New Urbanization Plan in March 2014, which called for a reorientation of the development strategy of the Chinese economy, from an export and (infrastructure) investment-driven economy to one driven by domestic consumption. Migrants, whose consumption propensity was previously severely constrained by the hukou system, were regarded as the vital engine for domestic consumption. “Allowing migrants to settle in the cities and increasing their demand for public services is a key to the success of the national economic rebalance.”Footnote 7 Later, the “Opinion on the further deepening of the hukou system reform” (hukou reform hereafter) and the 2014 Opinions were issued to buttress the New Urbanization Plan. Hukou reform aimed to remove institutional barriers by relaxing hukou registration in small- and medium-sized cities, whereas the 2014 Opinions aimed to promote the citizenization of migrant workers and facilitate their long-term settlement by improving various services, including housing.

In response to the central government's drive to improve migrant workers’ conditions, local governments issued corresponding policy guidance. With regards to housing, the local-level 2014 Opinions specify the policy instruments adopted in each housing area, demonstrating various levels of policy efforts. Since the 1980s, local governments have been granted increased autonomy in policymaking so they may adapt the central government's policy framework to meet local needs. The degree of autonomy varies by region, each possessing a differing degree of leverage over the central government.Footnote 8 Studies have documented subnational local variations in various policy areas such as the environment,Footnote 9 healthFootnote 10 and social welfare.Footnote 11 Previous discussions of local variations in housing policy design have centred around variations relating to public rental housing, and most studies have taken a case study approach, covering just a few major cities such as Beijing, Chongqing and Shanghai.Footnote 12 Studies that have adopted quantitative approaches mainly examine the diffusion of housing policy (for example, house-purchase restriction policies,Footnote 13 and housing adaptation policy for older adultsFootnote 14). As the provision of housing is closely associated with land use, another stream of quantitative studies explores local variations in leasing residential landFootnote 15 and land supply for affordable housing.Footnote 16

Building upon the extant literature on subnational variations in housing or land policies in China, this study investigates local variations in housing policies for migrant workers and the forces driving these variations. It contributes to the existing literature in four ways. First, we focus on migrant workers. Previous studies have exclusively focused on housing programmes that target low-income groups as a whole, overlooking the marginal status of migrant workers constrained by their hukou status.Footnote 17 Second, the 2014 Opinions offer a unique opportunity to comprehensively examine migrant housing policies, including not only housing programmes provided by the government but also the role government plays in supporting other providers such as employers and the market, an aspect that has been largely overlooked in previous research.Footnote 18 Third, we identify the patterns of local housing policies for migrant workers based on an original systematic coding of policy documents. Previous research mainly relied on case studies covering a few cities or used secondary proxy variables collected from statistical compilations.Footnote 19 Fourth, we have developed a theoretical framework to explain local variations in migrant housing policies. We find that the variations are not only driven by economic and political concerns but also by the need for a problem-solving function and previous welfare generosity. This comprehensive scope extends previous studies’ examinations of the determinants of housing/land policies that largely focus on economic and/or political factors only.Footnote 20

Housing Provision for Migrant Workers: Government, Employer and the Market

In 2016, the “Monitoring and investigative report for migrant workers,” issued by the Chinese National Bureau of Statistics (NBS), showed that 77.5 per cent of rural-to-urban migrants were living in rental housing (61 per cent) or self-owned property (16.5 per cent) provided by the market; 13.4 per cent were living in rental housing provided by their employers; and only 3 per cent were living in rental housing or self-owned property provided by the government.Footnote 21 The government, employers and markets are the three main housing providers for migrant workers. The government, besides being a provider itself, also applies policy tools to affect housing provision on behalf of the other two providers.

The government has long played a residual role in migrant housing. Without an urban hukou, migrant workers have been excluded from all housing welfare programmes in cities, including subsidized ownership housing,Footnote 22 low-rent housing (lianzufang 廉租房) (LRH hereafter) and public rental housing (gongzufang 公租房) (PRH hereafter). Subsidized ownership housing promotes home ownership among low-to-middle income households, LRH and PRH provide discounted rental housing for low-income and low-to-middle income households, respectively. A few cities took the initiative by providing a special type of LRH – “migrant worker apartments” (nongmingong gongyu 农民工公寓) – to accommodate migrant workers.Footnote 23 Others offer a special type of PRH for migrant workers who work in industrial parks or economic development zones.Footnote 24 The government only started to play a more active role in migrant housing provision after the central government issued its “Guiding opinions on the construction and administration of low-income housing projects” in 2011 (2011 Opinions hereafter), which allowed migrant workers to apply for PRH. Although migrant workers have been eligible for PRH since 2011, in 2018 only 1.3 per cent of non-local migrant workers lived in PRH. The strict eligibility rules set by local governments preclude most migrant workers from benefiting from PRH.Footnote 25

Employers also provide housing for migrant workers, particularly those in the manufacturing and construction sectors. Previous research indicates that the work-based dormitory system is designed to maximize employers’ profits through exerting labour control, facilitating long working hours, enhancing productivity and driving down workers’ salaries.Footnote 26 The dormitories are often cramped, of poor quality, lack privacy and discourage family formation. However, they are popular among migrant workers looking for low-cost housing and an easy commute.Footnote 27 The government's role in the employer-provided housing sector was primarily regulatory – for example, implementing building, sanitation and environmental standards.Footnote 28

Migrant workers living in market-provided housing for the most part live in informal rental housing in urban villages and shantytowns.Footnote 29 The houses in urban villages are largely self-built by villagers on collectively owned rural land. They are characterized by a lack of public services, unstable tenure and violations of construction regulations.Footnote 30 Despite the poor conditions, such housing provides affordable accommodation for migrant workers who cannot afford accommodation in the formal housing market.Footnote 31 In the past decade, local governments have demolished and replaced many urban villages with commodity housing in an attempt to eliminate informality and create more “governable spaces.” Migrant workers living in urban villages have been forced to leave the city or relocate to other urban villages in the peri-urban area. Researchers have critiqued the high cost of large-scale demolition and its negative effect on rural migrants’ options for affordable housing.Footnote 32 More recently, local governments have begun to adopt a micro-level redevelopment approach that aims to improve the public facilities and living conditions in the urban villages.Footnote 33

Determinants of Housing Policies: Theoretical Framework and Hypotheses

Our theoretical framework draws on factors of the economic development stage, political concerns, problem-solving function and path dependence to explain variations in migrant housing policy (see Figure 1).

Figure 1: Theoretical Framework on Housing Policymaking

As regards economic factors, the provision of housing is guided by the human capital requirements to sustain economic growth.Footnote 34 “Migrants who have gained assistance in accessing housing have normally been the ones that best fit the market's needs.”Footnote 35 Prior research has examined the provision of PRH during the 12th Five-Year Plan (2011–2015) in Chongqing and Shenzhen, two cities at different phases of development.Footnote 36 Chongqing underwent rapid industrial growth, which required a significant low- and semi-skilled workforce for its labour-intensive manufacturing sector. Its extensive PRH programme was extended to non-hukou residents to attract cheap rural labour. In contrast, Shenzhen, in the post-industrial stage, upgraded its economy towards service-oriented and value-added industries that demanded skilled and educated workers who were, therefore, offered PRH and monetary subsidies. Similarly, research comparing Chongqing with other cities such as Beijing and Nanjing also supports the close association between the provision of public housing and the economic stage and associated demand for labour of cities.Footnote 37 We therefore expect that local governments at an earlier economic development stage, when there is greater demand for more low-skilled workers to achieve sustained economic growth, are more likely to attend to the housing needs of migrant workers, whereas those at a later economic stage are less likely to attend to migrant workers’ housing needs (H1).

Regarding political concern, our hypotheses are grounded in two contextual factors in China: the central–local fiscal relationship and the local leaders’ performance appraisal system. First, since the 1994 fiscal reform that recentralized tax revenue collection and decentralized expenditure, local governments have retained an increasingly smaller share of tax revenues while shouldering the cost of the majority of public services. The current fiscal arrangement leads to a vertical fiscal imbalance that puts intense fiscal pressure on local governments.Footnote 38 Second, under the target responsibility system, the appraisal of local political leaders is largely related to “hard indicators” such as gross domestic product (GDP) growth and revenue. Social targets are internally regarded as less important – “soft targets.”Footnote 39 As they engage with the “promotion tournament competition,” local political leaders are incentivized to prioritize short-term GDP growth over social development.

Against this backdrop, we include four factors connected to political concerns: residential property prices, land-based revenue, fiscal dependency and leadership tenure. Since the market-oriented housing reform in the late 1980s, the real estate sector has become the key pillar upholding economic growth in China. There is a two-way linkage between residential property prices and GDP growth.Footnote 40 The target responsibility system encourages local political leaders to maintain the booming real estate market. The opportunity costs of addressing migrant workers’ housing needs, such as the construction of affordable housing, are greater for localities with higher residential property prices. Therefore, such locations are less likely to attend to migrant workers’ housing needs (H2.1). Intense fiscal pressures also encourage local governments to look for ways in which they can increase their extrabudgetary revenue without having to share it with the central government.Footnote 41 Land revenue, such as land conveyancing fees collected from leasing land usage rights and real estate-related tax, constitutes a substantial proportion of local governments’ extrabudgetary revenue. Previous research finds that cities more highly dependent on land revenue are less likely to build affordable housing because it not only increases direct spending on housing construction but also reduces the land revenue that otherwise would be collected from real estate developers.Footnote 42 Given the vital role land revenue plays in revenue generation, we expect that local governments that are more reliant on land revenue are less likely to attend to migrant workers’ housing needs (H2.2).

Fiscal dependency also affects local governments’ housing policies. After the 1994 fiscal reform, the central government gradually introduced a fiscal transfer system that aimed to alleviate local governments’ vertical fiscal imbalance. Fiscal transfers from the centre can be divided into two broad components: general purpose and specific purpose.Footnote 43 General-purpose transfers are designed to reduce regional fiscal disparity and are distributed based on a formula that assesses local fiscal capacity and expenditure needs. Specific-purpose transfers cover ad-hoc but earmarked grants that incentivize local governments to undertake specific policies and programmes. The distribution of specific-purpose transfers is usually not rule-based or subject to rent-seeking.Footnote 44 In general, local governments that receive more fiscal transfers have greater fiscal dependency because they have fewer economic resources at their disposal and are more fiscally constrained by the central government.Footnote 45 Previous research indicates that local governments with lower fiscal dependency are less likely to adopt pro-poor policies such as building affordable housing and increasing dibao 低保 (minimum living standard guarantee) expenditure.Footnote 46 Investment in housing for migrant workers is regarded as a revenue-depleting, social welfare investment, as it “enables a high influx of poor migrants, who need support in not only accommodation but also many other aspects of [their] livelihood.”Footnote 47 Therefore, under the current target responsibility system, which rewards GDP growth, local governments with lower fiscal dependency are more likely to spend on productive investments (for example, high-speed rail) rather than social welfare. Productive investment not only boosts GDP growth but can also more effectively demonstrate local officials’ achievements to their superiors.Footnote 48 Therefore, we expect that local governments with higher levels of fiscal dependency are more likely to attend to migrant workers’ housing needs (H2.3).

Local political leaders’ tenure also shapes migrant housing policy. Local leaders at the beginning of their tenure are much more incentivized to boost GDP growth and revenue in order to boost their prospects for promotion. Previous research reveals that in jurisdictions where local leaders are at an earlier stage of their tenure, GDP accelerators such as property prices and over-investment in state-owned enterprises are higher,Footnote 49 and social welfare spending tends to be lower, than in jurisdictions where the leaders are at a later stage of their tenure.Footnote 50 As investment in migrant workers’ housing is regarded as a revenue-depleting social welfare expenditure, we expect that local leaders are less likely to attend to migrant workers’ housing needs during the early stages of their tenure (H2.4).

Migrant housing policy may also serve a problem-solving function, either by responding directly to migrant workers’ housing problems or as a more general tool to address overall urban issues. In China, localities with more severe housing problems are not more likely to respond to them.Footnote 51 For example, Fox Hu and Jiwei Qian show that localities with higher housing unaffordability do not devote more land to affordable housing.Footnote 52 Therefore, we expect local governments’ housing policies for migrant workers to be unaffected by the severity of migrant workers’ housing problems (H3.1). Although prior studies reveal that housing policy in China is not particularly designed to address this specific housing problem, it may be regarded as a policy tool to address overall urban issues. Rapid urbanization brings problems such as housing shortages, traffic congestion and environmental pollution. Localities with more salient urban issues have a greater urgency to address these issues.Footnote 53 Therefore, we hypothesize that the more salient the urban issues, the more likely it is that local governments will attend to migrant workers’ housing needs (H3.2).

The formulation of new policy does not occur in a vacuum but is heavily influenced by institutionalized legacies and trajectories of past reform. According to path dependence theory,Footnote 54 “the present policy choice is also shaped or constrained by institutional paths that result from choices made in the past.”Footnote 55 Governments may be inclined to follow their previous policy paths because they may induce lower costs associated with changes and greater public acceptance. Hence, we expect that path dependence also exists in the social welfare domain. Therefore, localities with higher levels of prior welfare generosity should be more likely to attend to migrant workers’ housing needs (H4).

To summarize, we hypothesize that local governments’ housing policies for migrant workers are affected by economic development stage (H1), political concerns (H2.1, H2.2, H2.3 and H2.4), the salience of urban issues (H3.2) and previous welfare generosity (H4), but not the severity of migrant workers’ housing problems (H3.1).

Data: Construction of Dataset on Housing Policies for Migrant Workers

The policy dataset was constructed from a comprehensive collection of prefectural-level government documents responding to the State Council's 2014 Opinions. Among the 337 prefecture-level cities, 97 had policy documents retrievable online (for example, on government websites and the Law and Regulations Chinese Database).Footnote 56 We extracted migrant housing content where each city listed its housing policy areas and the policy instruments that it had adopted for each policy area (detailed below). The average word count of migrant housing content ranges from 128 in Yichang 宜昌 to 640 in Wuzhou 梧州. We compared the characteristics of these cities and the 240 cities that did not have retrievable policy documents.Footnote 57 As Table A1 in the Appendix shows, they are not statistically different in demographic and economic characteristics, suggesting that the coverage of cities in our investigation was not biased based on these observed characteristics.

Policy coding scheme

The purpose of coding was to transfer housing policy content into a quantifiable format for analysis. We first identified the policy area in the policy content and then assigned a policy score for each area. The policy score captures the resources or efforts devoted to a particular policy area and is based on the density and intensity of the policy instrument adopted in each policy area. The definition and operationalization of the policy area, policy instrument, policy intensity and policy density are explained below.

Inspired by the multiagency housing provision system proposed by previous research,Footnote 58 we developed policy areas in our coding scheme based on three housing providers (government, market and employer) and two types of housing tenure (owner-occupied and rental) (see Figure 2). Owner-occupied housing provided by the government is subsidized-ownership housing. Government-provided rental housing is subsidized rental housing, including LRH and PRH. Two types of PRH were differentiated, general public rental housing (PRH-general) and specific public rental housing (PRH-specific). The former refers to PRH targeting general low- and lower-middle income populations, whereas the latter refers to PRH located in economic development zones or industrial parks and primarily targeting employees including migrant workers. Owner-occupied housing provided by the market is commercial ownership housing. Formal rental housing provided by the market is commercial rental housing, whereas informal rental housing is urban village or shanty town accommodation. Employer-provided rental housing is dormitory accommodation. In sum, the eight policy areas included in the coding scheme are: subsidized-ownership housing, LRH, PRH-general, PRH-specific, commercial ownership housing, commercial rental housing, urban village and dormitory.

Figure 2: Typology of Policy Area

Policy instruments refer to the specific policy tools used to achieve policy objectives and are classified into two broad types: market-based instruments (MBIs) and administrative instruments (see Figure 3). MBIs are defined as instruments encouraging behaviour through market signals.Footnote 59 MBI instruments include both price-based and quantity-based instruments. Price-based instruments lever behavioural change by changing the prices of goods and services in existing markets and include subsidies, tax incentives and financing instruments. Quantity-based instruments lever behavioural change by specifying the “amount” of new rights/obligations. We further classified these into land-quantity and housing-quantity instruments that reserve land or housing quotas for migrant workers. Administrative instruments include policy tools related to procedures (for example, streamlining the application process). In summary, the policy instruments were classified into six sub-types: subsidies, tax incentives, financing, land-quantity, housing-quantity and administrative instruments. Each of these can be further classified into supply-side (targeting producers) and demand-side (targeting consumers) instruments. Figure 2 illustrates the typologies of the policy instruments and examples. Policy density refers to the extensiveness or breadth of the policy instruments and is measured by counting the number of policy instruments adopted in a given policy area. Policy intensity is defined as the “organization and mobilization of resources, i.e., the amount of resources, effort, or activity that is invested or allocated to a specific policy instrument.”Footnote 60 The six sub-types of policy instruments represent different levels of intensity: subsidies, land-quantity and housing-quantity=3, tax incentives and financing instruments=2, and administrative instruments=1. Figure 4 explains the assignment of intensity scores to policy instrument.

Figure 3: Typology and Examples of Policy Instruments

Figure 4: Assignment of Intensity Score to Policy Instruments

Policy coding process

We coded each city's migrant housing policy content on a point-by-point basis. First, we coded whether the eight policy areas were covered or not. Second, we coded the policy instruments adopted in each policy area. Third, we calculated the policy intensity and weighted policy density based on the policy instruments adopted in each area. Last, we constructed a policy score for each area as a continuous variable ranging from 0 to 5 (0 if the policy area was not covered; 1 if the policy area was covered without any policy instrument; 2 if policy instruments were proposed and the policy density weighted by policy intensity was 1; 3 if the weighted policy density was 2; 4 if the weighted policy density was 3; 5 if the weighted policy density was 4 or above). The overall policy score is the sum of the policy scores of the eight policy areas. The detailed policy coding process is shown in Figure A1 in the Appendix.

Measures and Empirical Strategies

First, we used descriptive statistics to describe the policy area, policy instrument and policy score. Next, we performed agglomerative hierarchical cluster analysis to depict the patterns of migrant housing policies across the 97 cities. We conducted cluster analysis based on the nine indicators: the standardized overall policy score and the respective standardized scores in each of the eight areas. Last, we examined the determinants of migrant housing policies. The overall policy score and the cluster membership identified from cluster analysis were used as the outcome variables. To test the eight proposed hypotheses, our analytic models include the following prefecture-level indicators as explanatory variables: economic development stage, residential property price, reliance on land revenue, fiscal dependency, political leaders’ tenure, severity of migrant workers’ housing problem, salience of urban issues and previous welfare generosity. We employed Ordinary Least Square (OLS) regression when the outcome was overall policy score, and multinomial logistic regression when the outcome was cluster membership. Cluster-robust standard errors were controlled to account for model error in cities from the same province.

Indicators of economic development stage include the increase rate of number of workers in secondary industry and GDP per capita. Cities with a higher increase rate of workers in secondary industry are at an earlier stage of development which demands more low-skilled workers, whereas cities with higher GDP per capita are at a later stage. As most (99 per cent) policy documents were released on or after 2015, we collected cities’ characteristics as reported in 2014, and for the nearest year when 2014 data were unavailable. GDP per capita is the ratio of GDP value in 2014 to the population in 2010. The rate of increase in the numbers of workers in secondary industry is the averaged rate in increase from 2010 to 2014. GDP values and percentages of workers employed in secondary industry were drawn from China City Statistical Yearbooks from 2011 to 2015. Population data were drawn from the 2010 Chinese Census.

Political concerns include reliance on the residential property price, land revenue, fiscal dependency and political leaders’ tenure. Residential property prices in 2014 were collected from the China Premium database. The indicator of reliance on land revenue is defined as the ratio between land conveyance fees and budgetary revenue. The 2014 land conveyance fee data and 2014 budgetary revenue data were collected from the 2015 China Land and Resources Statistical Yearbook and 2015 China City Statistical Yearbook, respectively. Our fiscal dependency indicator was the ratio between general-purpose transfer and budgetary expenditure. We used general-purpose transfer to capture local governments’ fiscal dependency levels because its allocation is mainly based on local fiscal capacity and is less subject to political influence than specific-purpose transfer. We extracted 2009 general-purpose transfer and budgetary expenditure data from the 2009 Financial Statistics of Cities and Counties. Regarding political leaders’ tenure, we accounted for the time lag between policy decision making and release of policy documents by identifying the mayors and Chinese Communist Party (CCP) secretaries who were in office three months before each city-level policy was released. Then, we constructed continuous variables measuring the number of years that mayors or CCP secretaries had been in office. These data were extracted from the Chinese Political Elite Database.

Problem-solving function includes the severity of migrant workers’ housing problems and the salience of urban issues. The indicators used for migrant workers’ housing problem severity were the proportion of migrant workers living in informal housing and rent unaffordability. We calculated the proportion of migrant workersFootnote 61 living in informal housing (for example, borrowed places, onsite shelters and self-built houses),Footnote 62 and rent-to-income ratio by pooling data from the China Migrant Dynamic Survey (CMDS) in 2013 and 2014, and calculated the indicators by city of residence. Indicators of salience of urban issues include urbanization level (the proportion of the population in the urban area) and size of migrant population (ratio of migrant population to permanent residents). Both indicators were collected from the 2010 Chinese Census.

We used the dibao replacement rate to measure previous welfare generosity. Dibao is the flagship social assistance programme in China. We measured the dibao replacement rate as the ratio of urban dibao eligibility standard to urban residents’ per capita disposable income. We collected dibao standards for 2014 from the website of the Ministry of Civil Affairs, and 2014 disposable income statistics were obtained from the 2015 Statistical Yearbooks from 31 provinces. We also included control variables covering the proportion of GDP contributed by tertiary industry (China City Statistical Yearbook 2015), population (2010 Census) and mayors and CCP secretaries’ age (Chinese Political Elite Database). The descriptive statistics on explanatory and control variables are presented in Table A2 in the Appendix.

Results

Patterns of housing policies for migrant workers

Policy area, policy instrument and policy score

Table 1 presents the summary statistics related to the policy area, policy instruments and policy scores. Local governments took various approaches to accommodate migrant workers, with the average number of policy areas covered by each city being 4.1. Panel A displays the proportion of cities that covered a particular policy area. PRH-specific, commercial ownership housing and dormitories were the three most frequently mentioned policy areas (75.3 per cent, 72.2 per cent and 69.1 per cent, respectively), followed by commercial rental housing (65.0 per cent), PRH-general (59.8 per cent) and urban villages (42.3 per cent). Subsidized-ownership housing (17.5 per cent) and LRH (9.3 per cent) were the two least covered areas and were less favoured by local governments to accommodate migrant workers.

Table 1: Summary Statistics of Policy Area, Policy Instrument and Policy Score (N=97)

Panel B displays the distribution of policy instruments by policy area. Among the 259 policy instruments, tax incentive was the most frequently adopted instrument (35.5 per cent), followed by administrative instruments (22.0 per cent), financing (12.7 per cent) and subsidies (12.4 per cent). The least adopted policy instruments were land quantity (9.7 per cent) and housing quantity (7.7 per cent). The distribution of policy instruments also varied by policy area. Both subsidized and commercial ownership housing predominately used (demand-side) tax incentives (90.9 per cent and 95.2 per cent, respectively). For LRH, administrative instruments (41.2 per cent) and land-quantity (35.3 per cent) were the most frequently adopted, followed by financing (17.7 per cent) and tax incentives (5.9 per cent). PRH-general and PRH-specific adopted all six sub-types of policy instrument. For PRH-general, housing-quantity (35.9 per cent) and administrative instruments (28.3 per cent) were the most frequently used instruments, whereas in PRH-specific, price-based MBIs such as financing (34.6 per cent), tax incentives (25.0 per cent) and subsidies (23.1 per cent) were more likely to be used. In commercial rental housing, 64.3 per cent of the instruments were subsidies and 28.6 per cent were tax incentives. The policy tools adopted in urban village were mostly administrative instruments (71.4 per cent), followed by land-quantity instruments (28.6 per cent). Dormitory used all policy instruments except housing-quantity; administrative instruments constituted around half of the instruments used, followed by 19.1 per cent in financing and 19.1 per cent in land-quantity.

Panel C shows the summary statistics of policy scores by policy area. The average overall policy score was 8.44. The three policy areas with the highest policy scores were commercial ownership housing (2.02), PRH-general (1.54) and PRH-specific (1.47). The policy scores of commercial rental housing and dormitory were 1.02 and 1.14, respectively. Urban village, subsidized ownership housing and LRH had the lowest policy scores. As the construction of policy scores was based on intensity-weighted density, the summary statistics of policy density weighted by policy intensity are presented in Table A4 in the Appendix.

Results from cluster analysis

A four-cluster solution was selected based on the diagnostic statistics.Footnote 63 Table 2 presents the standardized policy scores of the four clusters – residual approach, public and private rental approach, collective rental approach, and citizenship-oriented approach. The cities in each cluster are shown in Table A6 in the Appendix. As shown in Table 2, 18.6 per cent of the cities fell into the residual group, in which the overall score was low and the scores in each policy area were all at low levels. Most cities (62.9 per cent) belonged to the public and private rental group, characterized by relatively high scores in PRH-specific and commercial rental housing areas. A small number (6.2 per cent) of the cities belonged to the collective rental group, characterized by high scores in collective rental housing types such as LRH, in the form of “migrant worker apartments” and employer-provided dormitories, and 12.4 per cent of cities fell into the citizenship-oriented group. These cities had higher scores in ownership housing, including subsidized and commercial ownership housing, and PRH-general.Footnote 64 We labelled this group as “citizenship-oriented” because it provides both ownership housing and PRH that is able to meet the diverse housing needs of migrant workers and promote their citizenization. Moreover, housing ownership substantially shapes migrant workers’ long-term settlement decisions in host cities.Footnote 65

Table 2: Standardized Policy Scores by Policy Clusters (N=97)

Determinants of housing policies on migrant workers

Table 3 reports our regression results.Footnote 66 Economic development stages were significantly associated with migrant housing policies. Cities with higher GDP per capita tended to have lower overall policy scores. A 1,000-yuan increase in GDP per capita reduced the overall policy score by 0.099 (Model 1). Compared to cities adopting public and private rental approaches, cities with higher per capita GDPs were more likely to adopt the residual approach (coefficient = 0.036, see Model 2). Cities with a higher rate of increase in number of workers in secondary industry were more likely to adopt citizenship-oriented approaches (coefficient = 0.311, Model 3). Thus, H1 was supported. Among political concerns, residential property prices and fiscal dependency were significantly associated with migrant housing policies. Cities with higher residential property prices were more likely to fall into the residual group than into the public and private rental group (coefficient = 0.664, Model 2). Cities with greater fiscal dependency tended to adopt citizenship-oriented approaches (coefficient=0.317, see Model 3). Neither reliance on land revenue nor mayoral/CCP secretarial tenure significantly predicted migrant housing policies. Therefore, we endorse H2.1 and H2.3, but H2.2 and H2.4 were not supported. In terms of problem-solving function, migrant workers’ housing problems did not significantly predict migrant housing policies. Thus, we endorse H3.1. Urban issue salience indicators were significantly associated with migrant housing policies. Cities with higher urbanization levels and larger migrant populations tended to fall into the citizenship-oriented group (coefficients = 0.057 and 0.317, respectively, see Model 3). H3.2 was thus supported. Cities with greater welfare generosity, as measured by dibao replacement rate, were more likely to adopt citizenship-oriented approaches (coefficient=0.400, see Model 3). Therefore, H4 was supported.

Table 3: OLS and Multinomial Logistic Regressions on the Determinants of Housing Policies

Notes: * p < 0.05; ** p < 0.01.

Robustness Check

We conducted sensitivity analyses to corroborate our cluster analysis results. First, we calculated the policy scores based on policy density unweighted by policy intensity. Second, we constructed a new measure of policy intensity ranging from 1 to 4. Cities were divided into quartile groups according to the ratio of housing expenditure to total fiscal expenditure in 2013.Footnote 67 Higher ratios indicated higher levels of policy intensity. The results of the two sensitivity analyses showed a four-cluster solution similar to our main results: residual, public and public rental, collective rental, and citizenship-oriented approaches (see Table A7 in Appendix).

We also conducted sensitivity analyses to corroborate our regression results. First, we used an alternative indicator – fiscal autonomy (ratio of budgetary revenues to expenditure in 2014) – to measure cities’ fiscal dependency levels. Greater fiscal autonomy indicated lower fiscal dependency. Similar to our main findings, cities with higher fiscal autonomy were significantly less likely to adopt citizenship-oriented approaches. Second, we created an alternative rental unaffordability measure by calculating the proportion of migrants who bore a rent-to-income ratio greater than 30 per cent. Similar to our main results, rental unaffordability was not significantly associated with migrant housing policies. Third, we adopted alternative measures of welfare generosity: first, the proportion of government social expenditure (employment and social security) over total expenditures; then, the percentage of migrant workers covered by social insurance and the housing provident fund (wuxianyijin 五险一金). Neither of these measures was significantly associated with migrant housing policies.

Discussion

By systematically coding prefecture-level policy documents in response to the 2014 Opinions, we examined local variations in housing policies for migrant workers in China and the forces driving these variations. We found that 18.6 per cent of the cities adopted a residual approach that devoted only limited resources and efforts to address migrant workers’ housing needs. Most cities that devoted more resources adopted a rental-based approach (public and private rental and collective rental) that could only meet migrants’ short-term housing needs. Only a few cities (12.4 per cent) adopted a citizenship-oriented approach, providing both ownership housing and PRH that could meet migrant workers’ short-term and long-term housing needs. Such an approach best fits the Chinese central government's overarching goals of enhancing migrant workers’ citizenization and facilitating their long-term settlement in the host cities.

We found that local-level migrant housing policies were driven by economic and political concerns. Because migrant workers are the vital engine for sustained economic growth in labour-intensive sectors, cities at an economic development stage requiring more low-skilled workers devoted more resources and effort towards migrant housing. In contrast, cities at the economic development stage that demands less low-skilled workers, such as Beijing, Shanghai and Nanjing, were more likely to adopt a residual approach. Under the current fiscal and performance appraisal systems, local leaders endeavour to boost immediate GDP growth and fiscal revenue. As providing migrant housing is regarded as a revenue-draining measure that competes with the real estate sector for land resources and productive investment for financial resources, cities with higher residential property prices or with less fiscal dependence were less committed to migrant housing. In addition, our study showed that local leaders’ tenure had no significant association with migrant housing policies. Because housing construction occurs over a long period of time which may exceed the typical tenure of local leaders, policy preferences towards migrant housing did not differ based on local political leaders’ length of tenure. To summarize, our findings echo previous studies’ assertion that welfare provision in China, such as urban workers’ basic pension systemFootnote 68 and low-income housing,Footnote 69 serve economic and political functions.

Our study explored beyond economic and political factors to enrich understanding on the problem-solving function and path dependence tendency of migrant housing policy in China. We found that although migrant housing policies did not respond directly to migrant workers’ housing problems, they responded to the salience of urban issues. Housing for migrant workers is only one of the many urban issues that cities face, and migrant workers have little influence over local policymaking. Urban issues brought on by urbanization and influxes of migration (such as overcrowding and environmental degradation) affect not only migrants but also local residents, who have more influence over policymaking. As for path dependence, we found evidence that local governments’ migrant housing policy choices were contingent on their welfare legacy. This finding echoes previous studies that found local governments in China tend to reinforce their policy paths in areas such as environmental policy, township reform and financing urban infrastructure.Footnote 70

Since housing provision for migrant workers is regarded as an instrumental tool for sustaining economic growth and political goals, it is not surprising to find that even among cities that devote relatively more resources to migrant housing, temporary rental approaches are preferred to the citizenship-oriented approach. To incentivize local governments to provide housing and other services for migrant workers, reform is required to restructure central–local fiscal relations as well as local leaders’ performance evaluation system.

First, to ease their fiscal pressures, local governments should be granted more discretion over revenue collection. For example, local governments’ share of revenue, relative to that of the central government, could be increased. Local governments could be granted the power to set local tax rates within a defined range. Such reform could provide local governments with additional resources to invest in welfare measures, such as housing for migrant workers. Second, the performance evaluation system should consider including assessments on local governments’ social welfare and public service provision to migrant workers. Previous research reveals that local leaders tend to pursue performance targets that are explicitly included in the performance evaluation system yet ignore other policy objectives related to performance targets that cannot be conveniently achieved.Footnote 71 This behavioural tendency suggests that tailoring policy objectives to precise personnel performance criteria can be a viable means to realize a specific policy vision. The new performance evaluation system,Footnote 72 promulgated to replace the earlier one,Footnote 73 stipulates that a comprehensive assessment should take into account local people's subjective evaluation of social and economic development. Performance appraisals should consider not only the GDP growth rate but also its quality; not only the achievement but also the cost; not only the subjective effort but also the objective circumstances. This marks an important step towards reforming the current incentive structure guiding policy considerations among local leaders. The impact of this reform on policy adoption or citizens’ well-being requires further investigation.

This study has limitations. First, coverage was limited to those prefecture-level cities that promulgated the 2014 Opinions and thus the sample size was relatively small. Second, we depicted the policy variations based on policy documents. The gap between policy documentation and implementation cannot be captured. Despite these limitations, however, our study is the first to systematically examine local patterns of migrant housing policies in China covering a large number of cities. We also developed a theoretical framework that can be applied to examine housing policymaking in other countries and to investigate the underlying economic, political, housing-related and social factors that shape housing policy. In sum, we identified four types of approaches, residual, public and private rental, collective rental and citizenship-oriented, developed by local governments to accommodate migrant workers in China and revealed that the variations were driven not only by economic and political considerations but also by the problem-solving function and welfare legacy.

Acknowledgements

We acknowledge the funding support of the Contemporary China Research Cluster Postdoctoral Fellow Scheme at the Faculty of Social Sciences, the University of Hong Kong.

Conflict of interest

None.

Appendix

Table A1: Logistic Regression on Policy Document Availability

Table A2: Descriptive Statistics on Explanatory and Control Variables

Table A3: Distribution of Policy Instruments (Supply-Demand) by Policy Area

Table A4: Descriptive Statistics of Policy Density Weighted by Policy Intensity

Table A5: CH and DH Indices of Cluster Analysis

Table A6: List of Cities in Each Cluster

Table A7: Sensitivity Analysis on Policy Cluster

Figure A1: Policy Coding Process

Chenhong PENG is an assistant professor at the department of social work and social administration at the University of Hong Kong. Her research interests include social policy (social protection, housing and old-age income protection) and poverty alleviation. Her research has been published in The China Quarterly, Journal of Social Policy, Social Science and Medicine and Health Policy and Planning.

Julia Shu-Huah WANG is an associate professor at the department of social work, National Taiwan University, and an honorary associate professor at the department of social work and social administration, the University of Hong Kong. Her research focuses on social welfare policies, immigration policies and the well-being of families. She is currently investigating the design and impacts of social safety nets in East Asia and beyond as well as the patterns and effects of hukou reforms in mainland China.

Footnotes

1 Jin, Qian and Weingast Reference Jin, Qian and Weingast2005.

2 NBS 2020.

3 Chan and Buckingham Reference Chan and Buckingham2008.

4 Niu and Zhao Reference Niu and Zhao2018; Zhang, Li, and Wang Reference Zhang and Wang2010.

6 Zhou, Jing Reference Zhou2018, 5.

7 Shi, Chen and Wang Reference Shi, Chen and Wang2016, 232.

8 Lieberthal and Oksenberg Reference Lieberthal and Oksenberg1988.

9 Eaton and Kostka Reference Eaton and Kostka2014.

10 Huang, Xian Reference Huang2015.

17 Chiu-Shee and Zheng Reference Chiu-Shee and Zheng2019; Zhou, Jing, and Ronald Reference Zhou and Ronald2017.

19 Wang and Li Reference Wang and Li2019; Zhou, Jing, and Ronald Reference Zhou and Ronald2017.

21 NBS 2017.

22 Examples of subsidized-ownership housing include economically affordable housing (jingji shiyong fang) and shared ownership housing (gongyou chanquan fang).

23 Lü, Zhen and Ding Reference Lü, Zhen and Ding2012.

25 Zhou, Jing, and Musterd Reference Zhou and Musterd2018.

26 Huang, Youqin, and Tao Reference Huang and Tao2015.

27 Li, Bingqin, and Duda Reference Li and Duda2010.

28 Lin, Liyue, and Zhu Reference Lin and Zhu2010.

29 Although official national statistics are not available, a territory-wide study conducted in Shenzhen (Li, Tao, Wong and Hui Reference Li, Wong and Hui2014) showed that among migrant workers who rented private housing, 60% lived in rental housing in urban villages.

30 Wu, Zhang and Webster Reference Wu, Zhang and Webster2013.

31 Li, Bingqin, and Zhang Reference Li and Zhang2011.

32 Wu, Zhang and Webster Reference Wu, Zhang and Webster2013.

35 Zhou, Jing Reference Zhou2018, 6.

36 Chiu-Shee and Zheng Reference Chiu-Shee and Zheng2019.

37 Wang and Li Reference Wang and Li2019; Zhou, Jing, and Ronald Reference Zhou and Ronald2017.

38 Shen, Jin and Zou Reference Shen, Jin and Zou2012.

39 Zhou, Li'an Reference Zhou2007.

40 Peng, Wensheng, Tam and Yiu Reference Peng, Tam and Yiu2008.

41 Shen, Jin and Zou Reference Shen, Jin and Zou2012.

43 Shen, Jin and Zou Reference Shen, Jin and Zou2012.

44 Huang, Bihong, and Chen Reference Huang and Chen2012.

45 Zheng, Yu Reference Zheng2006.

46 Hu and Qian Reference Hu and Qian2017; Peng, Zhaiwen Reference Peng2017.

47 Chiu-Shee and Zheng Reference Chiu-Shee and Zheng2019, 22.

48 Duan and Zhan Reference Duan and Zhan2011.

49 Guo, Feng, and Hu Reference Guo and Hu2014; Cao, Ma and Shen Reference Cao, Ma and Shen2014.

50 Guo, Ping, and Lin Reference Guo and Lin2018.

53 Huang, Yanfen, and Ding Reference Huang and Ding2013.

55 Torfing Reference Torfing2009, 71.

56 The term prefecture-level city here includes all the administration divisions at prefecture-level, including cities (shi), prefectures (zhou), leagues (meng) and regions (diqu).

57 Notable cities, such as Shenzhen, Guangzhou and Chengdu, were not included in the analysis owing to the unavailability of their policies.

58 Huang, Youqin, and Tao Reference Huang and Tao2015.

60 Schaffrin, Sewerin and Seubert Reference Schaffrin, Sewerin and Seubert2015, 261.

61 Highly skilled rural–urban migrants, including civil servants, technicians and businesspeople, were excluded from the calculations of the percentage living in informal housing and rent unaffordability.

62 Our informal housing indicator captured the percentage of migrant workers not covered by any of the eight policy areas. Those living in urban villages were not classified as living in informal housing.

63 The choice of the number of clusters was determined by the stopping rules of Calinski and Harabasz (CH) pseudo-F, Duda and Hart (DH) Je (2)/Je (1) and DH pseudo-T2 indices. Large values of the CH pseudo-F, large values of DH Je(2)/Je(1) and small values of pseudo-T2 indicate more distinct clustering. As shown in Table A5, a four-cluster solution satisfied the stopping rules.

64 The urban village score was also high among the citizenship-oriented group, primarily driven by high scores in five cities in Guangdong province where urban villages accommodated large numbers of migrant workers.

66 The collective rental approach group was not included in the multinomial logistic regression owing to the small sample size (n = 6). Descriptive statistics of explanatory and control variables by cluster membership are presented in Table A2 in the Appendix.

67 The latest available housing expenditure data at the city level are in the 2013 China Statistical Yearbook for Regional Economy.

69 Chen, Yang and Wang Reference Chen, Yang and Wang2014; Zhou, Jing, and Ronald Reference Zhou and Ronald2017.

70 Li, Linda Chelan Reference Li2009; Zhan, de Jong and de Bruijn, Reference Zhan, de Jong and de Bruijn2017; Zhang, Pan, and Wu Reference Zhang and Wu2020.

71 Kahn, Li and Zhao Reference Kahn, Li and Zhao2015.

72 General Office of the CCP Central Committee 2019.

73 Organization Department of the CCP Central Committee 1998.

Notes: * p < 0.05; ** p < 0.01.

Notes: Mean is reported. The number in parentheses is standard deviation. The last column reports the F-statistics of analysis of variance (ANOVA). * p < 0.05; ** p < 0.01.

References

Cao, Chunfang, Ma, Lianfu and Shen, Xiaoxiu. 2014. “Caizheng yali, jinsheng yali, guanyuan renqi yu defang guoqi guodu touzi” (Fiscal pressure, promotion pressure, tenure and over-investment in state-owned enterprises). Jingjixue jikan 13(4), 1416–36.Google Scholar
Chan, Kam Wing, and Buckingham, Will. 2008. “Is China abolishing the hukou system?The China Quarterly 195, 582606.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Chen, Jie, Yang, Zan and Wang, Ya Ping. 2014. “The new Chinese model of public housing: a step forward or backward?Housing Studies 29(4), 534550.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Chiu-Shee, Colleen, and Zheng, Siqi. 2019. “A burden or a tool? Rationalizing public housing provision in Chinese cities.Housing Studies 36(4), 500543.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Chu, Yongqiang. 2022. “City government's adoption of housing adaptation policy innovation for older adults: evidence from China.The Journals of Gerontology: Series B 77(2), 429434.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
David, Paul A. 1994. “Why are institutions the ‘carriers of history’? Path dependence and the evolution of conventions, organizations and institutions.Structural Change and Economic Dynamics 55(2), 205220.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Duan, Haiyan, and Zhan, Jing Vivian. 2011. “Fiscal transfer and local public expenditure in China: a case study of Shanxi province.China Review 11(1), 5788.Google Scholar
Eaton, Sarah, and Kostka, Genia. 2014. “Authoritarian environmentalism undermined? Local leaders’ time horizons and environmental policy implementation in China.The China Quarterly 218, 359380.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fang, Li, Tian, Chuanhao, Yin, Xiaohong and Song, Yan. 2018. “Political cycles and the mix of industrial and residential land leasing.Sustainability 10(9), 3077.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gao, Yuan, Tian, Li, Cao, Yandong, Zhou, Lin, Li, Zhibin and Hou, Deyi. 2019. “Supplying social infrastructure land for satisfying public needs or leasing residential land? A study of local government choices in China.Land Use Policy 87, 104088.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
General Office of the CCP Central Committee. 2019. “Dangzheng lingdao ganbu kaohe gongzuo tiaoli” (Regulations on the evaluation of the work of Party and government leading cadres), http://www.gov.cn/zhengce/2019-04/21/content_5384955.htm.Google Scholar
Guo, Feng, and Hu, Jun. 2014. “Guanyu renqi, zhengji yali he fangjia” (Tenure, promotion pressure and property prices). Zhengfu jingji guanli 36(4), 918.Google Scholar
Guo, Ping, and Lin, Xiaofei. 2018. “Difang guanyuan tezheng yu minsheng caizheng zhichu” (The characteristics of local leaders and social expenditure). Difang caizheng yanjiu 3, 7077.Google Scholar
Hu, Fox Z.Y., and Qian, Jiwei. 2017. “Land-based finance, fiscal autonomy and land supply for affordable housing in urban China: a prefecture-level analysis.Land Use Policy 69, 454460.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Huang, Bihong, and Chen, Kang. 2012. “Are intergovernmental transfers in China equalizing?China Economic Review 23(3), 534551.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Huang, Xian. 2015. “Four worlds of welfare: understanding subnational variation in Chinese social health insurance.The China Quarterly 222, 449474.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Huang, Yanfen, and Ding, Li. 2013. “Zhongguo chengshihua jinchengzhong de shehui fenxi” (The social issues arising from urbanization in China). Hebei xuekan 33(1), 116121.Google Scholar
Huang, Youqin, and Tao, Ran. 2015. “Housing migrants in Chinese cities: current status and policy design.Environment and Planning C: Government and Policy 33(3), 640660.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Jin, Hehui, Qian, Yingyi and Weingast, Barry R.. 2005. “Regional decentralization and fiscal incentives: federalism, Chinese style.Journal of Public Economics 89(9–10), 1719–42.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kahn, Matthew E., Li, Pei and Zhao, Daxuan. 2015. “Water pollution progress at borders: the role of changes in China's political promotion incentives.American Economic Journal: Economic Policy 7(4), 223242.Google Scholar
Li, Bingqin, and Duda, Mark. 2010. “Employers as landlords for rural-to-urban migrants in Chinese cities.Environment and Urbanization 22(1), 1331.Google Scholar
Li, Bingqin, and Zhang, Yongmei. 2011. “Housing provision for rural–urban migrant workers in Chinese cities: the roles of the state, employers and the market.Social Policy & Administration 45(6), 694713.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Li, Linda Chelan. 2009. “Decision-making in Chinese local administrative reform: path dependence, agency and implementation.Public Administration and Development 29(1), 7987.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Li, Tao, Wong, Francis K.W. and Hui, Eddie C.M.. 2014. “Residential satisfaction of migrant workers in China: a case study of Shenzhen.Habitat International 42, 193202.Google Scholar
Lieberthal, Kenneth, and Oksenberg, Michel. 1988. Policy Making in China: Leaders, Structures, and Processes. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lin, Liyue, and Zhu, Yu. 2010. “The diverse housing needs of rural to urban migrants and policy responses in China: insights from a survey in Fuzhou.IDS Bulletin 41(4), 1221.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lin, Yanliu, De Meulder, Bruno, Cai, Xiaoxiao, Hu, Haodong and Lai, Yani. 2014. “Linking social housing provision for rural migrants with the redevelopment of ‘villages in the city’: a case study of Beijing.Cities 40, 111119.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
, Ping, Zhen, Hui and Ding, Fujun. 2012. “Chayihua nongmingong zhufang zhengce goujian shexiang” (Diversification of housing policy for migrant workers). Jingji dili 32(10), 108113.Google Scholar
Meng, Ke. 2020. “Promotion tournament, labor market tightening and pension generosity: a comparative public policy analysis of pension system for urban workers in China (1997–2013).Journal of Comparative Policy Analysis: Research and Practice 22(4), 383404.Google Scholar
NBS (National Bureau of Statistics of China). 2017. “2016 Nongmingong jiance diaocha baogao” (Monitoring and investigative report on rural migrant workers), http://www.stats.gov.cn/tjsj/zxfb/201704/t20170428_1489334.html.Google Scholar
NBS. 2020. “2019 Nongmingong jiance diaocha baogao” (Monitoring and investigative report on rural migrant workers), http://www.stats.gov.cn/tjsj/zxfb/202004/t20200430_1742724.html. Accessed 25 February 2021.Google Scholar
Niu, Geng, and Zhao, Guochang. 2018. “Living conditions among China's rural–urban migrants: recent dynamics and the inland–coastal differential.Housing Studies 33(3), 476493.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Organization Department of the CCP Central Committee. 1998. “Dangzheng lingdao ganbu kaohe gongzuo zanxing guiding” (Tentative regulations on the evaluation of the work of Party and government leading cadres), http://newkjxy.jlufe.edu.cn/__local/6/03/6D/4087650C54804D031AC73DDA88D_F8B38312_4C078.pdf?e=.pdf.Google Scholar
Peng, Wensheng, Tam, Dickson C. and Yiu, Matthew S.. 2008. “Property market and the macroeconomy of mainland China: a cross region study.Pacific Economic Review 13(2), 240258.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Peng, Zhaiwen. 2017. “Caizheng zhuanyi zhifu, difang zhili yu chengshi dibao fazhan” (Fiscal transfer, local governance and development of urban dibao). Gonggong xingzheng pinglun 3, 7198.Google Scholar
Ratigan, Kerry. 2017. “Disaggregating the developing welfare state: provincial social policy regimes in China.World Development 98, 467484.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Schaffrin, André, Sewerin, Sebastian and Seubert, Sibylle. 2015. “Toward a comparative measure of climate policy output.Policy Studies Journal 43(2), 257282.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
She, Xiaoye. 2021. “Asset-based welfare or public rental? Local agency in affordable housing.” In She, Xiaoye, Understanding Local Agency in China's Policy Reform. Cham: Palgrave Macmillan, 155196.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Shen, Chunli, Jin, Jing and Zou, Heng-fu. 2012. “Fiscal decentralization in China: history, impact, challenges and next steps.Annals of Economics and Finance 13(1), 151.Google Scholar
Shi, Wei, Chen, Jie and Wang, Hongwei. 2016. “Affordable housing policy in China: new developments and new challenges.Habitat International 3(54), 224233.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Stavins, Robert N. 2003. “Experience with market-based environmental policy instruments.” In Bromley, Daniel W. (ed.), Handbook of Environmental Economics. Elsevier, 355435.Google Scholar
Torfing, Jacob. 2009. “Rethinking path dependence in public policy research.Critical Policy Studies 3(1), 7083.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wang, June, and Li, Mingye. 2019. “Mobilising the welfare machine: questioning the resurgent socialist concern in China's public rental housing scheme.International Journal of Social Welfare 28(3), 318332.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wu, Fulong, Zhang, Fangzhu and Webster, Chris. 2013. “Informality and the development and demolition of urban villages in the Chinese peri-urban area.Urban Studies 50(10), 1919–34.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Yang, Sisi, and Guo, Fei. 2018. “Breaking the barriers: how urban housing ownership has changed migrants’ settlement intentions in China.Urban Studies 55(16), 36893707.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Zhan, Changjie, de Jong, Martin and de Bruijn, Hans. 2017. “Path dependence in financing urban infrastructure development in China: 1949–2016.Journal of Urban Technology 24(4), 7393.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Zhang, Li, and Wang, Gui-xin. 2010. “Urban citizenship of rural migrants in reform-era China.Citizenship Studies 14(2), 145166.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Zhang, Pan, and Wu, Jiannan. 2020. “Performance targets, path dependence, and policy adoption: evidence from the adoption of pollutant emission control policies in Chinese provinces.International Public Management Journal 23(3), 405420.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Zheng, Yu. 2006. “Fiscal federalism and provincial foreign tax policies in China.Journal of Contemporary China 15(48), 479502.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Zhou, Jing. 2018. “Migrants and the New Stage of Public Housing Reform in China.” PhD diss., Universiteit van Amsterdam.Google Scholar
Zhou, Jing, and Musterd, Sako. 2018. “Housing preferences and access to public rental housing among migrants in Chongqing, China.Habitat International 79, 4250.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Zhou, Jing, and Ronald, Richard. 2017. “The resurgence of public housing provision in China: the Chongqing programme.Housing Studies 32(4), 428448.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Zhou, Li-an. 2007. “Zhongguo difang guanyuan de jinsheng jinbiaosai moshi yanjiu(Governing China's local officials: an analysis of the promotion tournament model). Jingji yanjiu 7, 3650.Google Scholar
Zou, Yonghua, Meng, Fanxing, Zhong, Ni and Zhao, Wanxiao. 2021. “The diffusion of the housing purchase restriction policy in China.Cities 120, 103401.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Figure 0

Figure 1: Theoretical Framework on Housing Policymaking

Figure 1

Figure 2: Typology of Policy Area

Figure 2

Figure 3: Typology and Examples of Policy Instruments

Figure 3

Figure 4: Assignment of Intensity Score to Policy Instruments

Figure 4

Table 1: Summary Statistics of Policy Area, Policy Instrument and Policy Score (N=97)

Figure 5

Table 2: Standardized Policy Scores by Policy Clusters (N=97)

Figure 6

Table 3: OLS and Multinomial Logistic Regressions on the Determinants of Housing Policies

Figure 7

Table A1: Logistic Regression on Policy Document Availability

Figure 8

Table A2: Descriptive Statistics on Explanatory and Control Variables

Figure 9

Table A3: Distribution of Policy Instruments (Supply-Demand) by Policy Area

Figure 10

Table A4: Descriptive Statistics of Policy Density Weighted by Policy Intensity

Figure 11

Table A5: CH and DH Indices of Cluster Analysis

Figure 12

Table A6: List of Cities in Each Cluster

Figure 13

Table A7: Sensitivity Analysis on Policy Cluster

Figure 14

Figure A1: Policy Coding Process