Hostname: page-component-78c5997874-ndw9j Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-11-20T01:12:56.926Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Cross-ownership and strategic environmental corporate social responsibility under price competition

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  11 March 2024

Mingqing Xing
Affiliation:
School of Economics and Management, Weifang University, Weifang, China
Sang-Ho Lee*
Affiliation:
Graduate School of Economics, Chonnam National University, Gwangju, Republic of Korea
*
*Corresponding author. E-mail: [email protected]
Rights & Permissions [Opens in a new window]

Abstract

This paper examines the impact of cross-ownership on the strategic incentive of environmental corporate social responsibility (ECSR) within a green managerial delegation contract in a triopoly market engaged in price competition. It demonstrates that bilateral cross-ownership between insiders provides weak incentives to undertake ECSR, which has a non-monotone relationship with cross-ownership shares, while it provides strong incentives for outsiders, which increases the ECSR level as cross-ownership increases. It also compares unilateral cross-ownership and finds that a firm that owns shares in its rival has a greater incentive to undertake ECSR than its partially-owned rival, while an outsider has more incentive than firms in bilateral scenarios. These findings reveal that a firm's incentive to increase a market price through ECSR critically depends on its cross-ownership share, while it decreases environmental damage and increases social welfare when the environmental damage is serious.

Type
Research Article
Copyright
Copyright © The Author(s), 2024. Published by Cambridge University Press

1. Introduction

Cross-ownership is common in many industries and thus has become a subject of business strategy and policy discussion in numerous economies.Footnote 1 As evidenced in real-world cases, several high-pollution industries under cross-ownership were observed. For example, Sinopec, the worst polluter among oil industries in China, holds a 40 per cent stake in Repsol YPF Brasil and 30 per cent in Petrogal Brasil. In the airline industry, Delta Air Lines and China Eastern Airlines each hold 8.8 per cent stakes in the Air France KLM Group, and Iberia holds a 9.49 per cent stake in the low-cost carrier Vueling and a 0.95 per cent stake in Royal Air Maroc. In the automobile industry, a significant pollution contributor, Korean automobile producer Hyundai, owns 33.9 per cent of Kia, and Nissan holds a 34 per cent stake in Mitsubishi Motors. Additionally, Toyota acquired a 5 per cent stake in the Chinese iron and steel company BFS in 2015 to help expand the market for hybrid cars in China.

A firm may be interested in acquiring a strategic stake in its rival because it can consider the effect of its output decision on the rival's profits. This is because cross-ownership can reduce competition in product and service markets and raise prices as a collusive device (Reynolds and Snapp, Reference Reynolds and Snapp1986). However, it may lead firms to internalize industry-wide externalities such as research spillover and emissions through horizontal and vertical relations, which can improve social welfare (Bayona and López, Reference Bayona and López2018; López and Vives, Reference López and Vives2019; Sato and Matsumura, Reference Sato and Matsumura2020; Anton et al., Reference Anton, Ederer, Gine and Schmalz2021; Chen et al., Reference Chen, Matsumura and Zeng2023). This indicates that cross-ownership might significantly influence environmental management and business strategy, especially in high-pollution industries.

In contrast, due to public awareness of environmental and climate damage and financial pressure from institutional investors, firm owners in these industries have also adopted environmental incentives as an alternative form of performance evaluation in their managerial delegation contracts.Footnote 2 According to PwC's global investor survey 2022 and OCEG-ESG-survey 2021,Footnote 3 52 per cent of 530 corporate executives plan to base or are already basing executive compensation on ESG (environmental, social, and governance) factors, and 45 per cent of the companies listed on the FTSE 100 have an ESG factor in their annual bonuses, long-term incentive plans (LTIPs), or both. The most common LTIP is linked to environmental issues such as decarbonization and energy transition.

In the literature focused on green managerial delegation contracts, owners establish environmental incentives while managers engage in emission reduction, known as environmental corporate social responsibility (ECSR). Several studies have examined firms' voluntary ECSR initiatives targeting abatement activities under price competition (Liu et al., Reference Liu, Wang and Lee2015; Hirose et al., Reference Hirose, Lee and Matsumura2017; Lee and Park, Reference Lee and Park2019, Reference Lee and Park2021; Park and Lee, Reference Park and Lee2023a). Hirose et al. (Reference Hirose, Lee and Matsumura2017) examined the simultaneous choice of ECSR under sequential price competition and revealed that only the price follower adopts ECSR, increasing market prices and firm profits. Lee and Park (Reference Lee and Park2019) also examined the sequential choice of ECSR under simultaneous price competition and showed that firms adopt ECSR to mitigate competition when the products are more substitutable. Park and Lee (Reference Park and Lee2023a) generalized the endogenous ECSR timing choice under price competition and confirmed that ECSR-induced higher costs increase firm profits. That is, there exists a cost pass-through effect under price competition.

Recent research has also incorporated emission tax policies and examined theoretical linkages between governmental regulations and firm performance in green delegation models (Poyago-Theotoky and Yong, Reference Poyago-Theotoky and Yong2019; Buccella et al., Reference Buccella, Fanti and Gori2021, Reference Buccella, Fanti and Gori2022, Reference Buccella, Fanti and Gori2023; Xu et al., Reference Xu, Chen and Lee2022; Park and Lee, Reference Park and Lee2023b). Notably, Poyago-Theotoky and Yong (Reference Poyago-Theotoky and Yong2019) compared a standard managerial delegation contract with sales incentives to an environmental delegation contract that rewards abatement activities. They determined that firm profits are greater under the environmental incentive-based contract. Buccella et al. (Reference Buccella, Fanti and Gori2023) demonstrated that sales delegation might emerge as the Pareto-inefficient equilibrium under Cournot competition, while Park and Lee (Reference Park and Lee2023b) combined the two compensation schemes and identified an optimal combination of double delegation contracts with ECSR. However, they investigated Cournot duopoly under quantity competition and thus the ECSR-induced cost pass-through effect under price competition was not fully incorporated.

Furthermore, some studies have considered strategic associations between ECSR and industrial cooperation, such as cross-ownership or common ownership, in a green delegation model (Hirose et al., Reference Hirose, Lee and Matsumura2020; Bárcena-Ruiz and Sagasta, Reference Bárcena-Ruiz and Sagasta2021; Hirose and Matsumura, Reference Hirose and Matsumura2022; Xing and Lee, Reference Xing and Lee2023; Cho and Lee, Reference Cho and Lee2024). For example, Hirose et al. (Reference Hirose, Lee and Matsumura2020) and Xu and Lee (Reference Xu and Lee2022) examined whether ECSR was adopted by joint-profit-maximizing industrial associations under quantity and price competitions with or without government regulations, respectively, and showed that ECSR decisions are determined by the market competition modes. Hirose and Matsumura (Reference Hirose and Matsumura2022) investigated the social welfare-improving effect of common ownership when the common owner promotes ECSR. Bárcena-Ruiz and Sagasta (Reference Bárcena-Ruiz and Sagasta2021) analyzed the international coordination of environmental policies when there is cross-ownership between polluting firms that adopt ECSR. Ning et al. (Reference Ning, Wang and Sun2022) compared two timings of the game with green delegation contracts under cross-ownership and examined whether the government should pre-commit to an emission tax or delay the tax decision. Finally, Cho and Lee (Reference Cho and Lee2024) considered environmental cooperation between ECSR commitment and environmental R&D under price competition and then indicated the importance of cross-ownership in a coordination game. However, the existing literature focuses mostly on duopoly competition and rarely discusses green managerial delegation in an oligopolistic competition with an asymmetric financial network of cross-ownership.

This paper seeks to elucidate the effects of cross-ownership on ECSR in a triopoly market within a green delegation contract under price competition. It considers bilateral cross-ownership where two firms form a financially networked group and finds that insiders under cross-ownership have incentives to undertake ECSR while outsiders are more motivated to undertake ECSR than insiders. Thus, cross-ownership will provide strong (weak) incentives to undertake ECSR among outsiders (insiders) since increased ECSR causes higher prices via the cost pass-through effect, which is more profitable to outsiders through increased competitive prices. This also implies that outsiders have more reason to engage in collusive pricing with rivals through ECSR, which can increase profits. Outsiders are also observed to increase their ECSR levels as insiders' cross-ownership shares increase, while insiders have non-monotone relationships between ECSR and the degree of cross-ownership. This is because an insider already has addressed its rival firm through cross-ownership and thus, collusive incentives through ECSR are lessened, especially when the cross-ownership share is sufficiently large. As a result, cross-ownership can decrease environmental damage and increase social welfare when environmental damage is severe.

Finally, this study further considers an asymmetric ownership structure under unilateral cross-ownership where only one firm holds a share of its rival firm and compares the results with those under a bilateral cross-ownership case. Nearly all the present findings reflect a bilateral cross-ownership hold, but a firm's incentive to adopt ECSR depends on the degree of ownership asymmetry between insiders. In particular, a firm that owns a share in its rival has a stronger incentive to undertake ECSR than does a partially-owned rival or an outsider. Therefore, a firm's incentive to collude through ECSR critically depends on the share of cross-ownership and the degree of product substitutability. Additionally, cross-ownership may or may not improve welfare, depending on the degree of environmental damage. These findings have important policy implications, especially since modern enterprises are reformulating green delegation contracts; thus, antitrust authorities should also develop appropriate guidelines for shares of cross-ownership to improve both environmental quality and social welfare, especially when environmental damage is severe.

The remainder of this paper is structured as follows. Section 2 introduces the basic model. A bilateral cross-ownership case is examined in section 3. It is then compared with a unilateral cross-ownership case in section 4. Finally, section 5 concludes the paper.

2. The basic model

A triopoly market where three firms (firms 0, 1, and 2) provide differentiated products and compete with prices is considered. Following Singh and Vives (Reference Singh and Vives1984), the utility function of the representative consumer is:

\[U({{q_0},\, {q_1},{q_2}} )= a({{q_0} + {q_1} + {q_2}} )- \frac{1}{2}({q_0^2 + q_1^2 + q_2^2 + 2r{q_0}{q_1} + 2r{q_1}{q_2} + 2r{q_0}{q_2}} ),\]

where ${q_i}$ is the output of firm $i\, ({i = 0, 1,2} ),Q = {q_0} + {q_1} + {q_2},$ and $r\,(0 < r < 1)$ denotes product substitutability between product i and product $j\, ({i \ne j} )$. Utilizing the utility maximization problem, the following inverse demand function is obtained:Footnote 4

(1)\begin{equation}{p_i} = a - {q_1} - r ({Q - {q_i}} ),\, i = 0,\, 1,\, 2.\end{equation}

Next, the following demand function is obtained:

(2)\begin{equation}{q_i} = \frac{1}{{1 + r - 2{r^2}}}\left[ {({1 - r} )a - ({1 + r} ){p_i} + r\left( {\mathop \sum \limits_{j = 0}^2 {p_j} - {p_i}} \right)} \right],\quad i = 0,1,2.\end{equation}

Firms' production processes cause pollutant emissions. Here, one output unit is assumed to result in one pollution unit when the pollutant emission of firm i is given by ${e_i} = {q_i} - {y_i}$ under end-of-pipe technology. Thus, firm i realizes the emission reduction of ${y_i}$ by bearing the abatement cost ${I_i} = (\xi y_i^2/2)$ where $\xi (\xi > 0$) measures abatement efficiency. The greater $\xi$ is, the lower the abatement efficiency. We employ $\xi = 1$ for simplicity, which does not affect the validity of the analysis. The corresponding environmental damage is assumed to be a quadratic function of total pollutants: $D = (d/2){\left( {\sum\nolimits_{i = 0}^2 {{e_i}} } \right)^2}$, where $d\, (d > 0)$ measures the seriousness of environmental damage generated by pollution.

The profit function of each firm is:

(3)\begin{equation}{\pi _i} = ({{p_i} - c} ){q_i} - \frac{{y_i^2}}{2}, \quad i = 0,\, 1,\, 2,\end{equation}

where c denotes the marginal production cost and satisfies $0 < c < a$.

Therefore, social welfare is defined as the sum of profits and consumer surplus minus total environmental damage:

(4)\begin{equation}SW = \mathop \sum \limits_{i = 0}^2 {\pi _i} + CS - D,\end{equation}

where $CS = \frac{1}{2}({q_0^2 + q_1^2 + q_2^2 + 2r{q_0}{q_1} + 2r{q_0}{q_2} + 2r{q_1}{q_2}} ).$

We assume that two firms (firms 1 and 2) form a financially networked group of bilateral cross-ownership where both firms hold k shares of the other, and $0 < k < 0.5$. Thus, the total profit of insider i (i.e., firm $i$) is: ${\mathop \prod \nolimits _i} = ({1 - k} ){\pi _i} + k{\pi _j}$ $(i \ne j, i,j = 1,\, 2)$. However, firm 0 is an outsider and does not hold shares of other firms. That is, its total profit is: ${\mathop \prod \nolimits _0} = {\pi _0}$.

We also assume that the firms are organized with separations between ownership and management. A green managerial delegation model is considered where the owner of firm i chooses the strategic level of ECSR to maximize its total profit ${\prod_i}$, but the manager of firm i chooses abatement level ${y_i}$ and price ${p_i}$ to maximize the following objective function (Buccella et al., Reference Buccella, Fanti and Gori2021; Xing and Lee, Reference Xing and Lee2023; Cho and Lee, Reference Cho and Lee2024):

(5)\begin{equation}{V_i} = {\mathop \prod \nolimits _i} - {h_i}{e_i},\quad i = 0,1,2,\end{equation}

where ${h_i}$ $({h_i} \ge 0)$ represents the strategic degree of ECSR for firm i as chosen by the owner. Firm i undertakes ECSR when ${h_i} > 0$, but it does not undertake ECSR when ${h_i} = 0$. Notably, the upper bound of ${h_i} \in [{0,1} ]$ is not restricted. This implies that a firm may be more concerned about environmental damage than that which is directly caused by the firm.

The timing of the game is as follows. In the first stage, owner i chooses ${h_i}$ to maximize total profits ${\mathop \prod \nolimits _i}$ non-cooperatively and simultaneously. In the second stage, after observing ${h_i}$, manager i determines ${p_i}$ (price) and ${y_i}$ (abatement level) to maximize ${V_i}$ non-cooperatively and simultaneously.Footnote 5 The subgame perfect equilibrium is solved using backward induction.

3. Analysis

In the second stage, manager i chooses the price and abatement level. Solving the first-order conditions gives the following equilibrium price and abatement level:Footnote 6

(6)\begin{equation}{p_0} = \frac{1}{{2[{3r + 2 - ({{r^2} + 4r + 2} )k} ]}}\left( {\begin{array}{*{20}{@{}c@{}}} {({1 + r} )[{r + 2 - 2({1 + r} )k} ]{h_0} + r({1 + r} )({h_1}}\\ { + {h_2}) + ({1 - r} )[{3r + 2 - 2({2r + 1} )k} ]w} \end{array}} \right)\end{equation}
(7)\begin{align} {p_j} & = \frac{{1}}{{2[{3r + 2 - ({{r^2} + 4r + 2} )k} ][{3r + 2 - 2({1 + r} )k} ]}}\nonumber\\ & \quad \times \left( {\begin{array}{*{20}{@{}c@{}}} {r({1 + r} )({1 - k} )[{3r + 2 - 2({1 + r} )k} ]{h_0} + ({3r + 2} )({r + 2} )({1 + r} )({1 - k} ){h_j}}\\ { + r({1 + r} )({3r + 2 - rk} ){h_l} + ({3r + 2} )({1 - r} )({1 - k} )[{3r + 2 - 2({1 + r} )k} ]w} \end{array}} \right)\end{align}
(8)\begin{equation}{y_0} = {h_0}\ \textrm{and}\ {y_j} = \frac{{{h_j}}}{{1 - k}},\ j,l = 1,2,\ j \ne l,\end{equation}

where $w = a - c$. Notably, as the degree of ECSR increases, abatement activities increase in (8). Then, due to the increase of abatement costs, prices increase along with ECSR; thus, $(\partial {p_0}/\partial {h_0}) = ((1 + r)[r + 2 - 2(1 + r)k]/2[3r + 2 - ({r^2} + 4r + 2)k]) > 0$ and $(\partial {p_1}/\partial {h_1}) = (\partial {p_2}/\partial {h_2}) = ((3r + 2)(r + 2)(1 + r)(1 - k)/2[3r + 2 - ({r^2} + 4r + 2)k][3r + 2 - 2(1 + r)k]) > 0$. This implies that there is a cost pass-through effect of ECSR under price competition (Hirose et al., Reference Hirose, Lee and Matsumura2017; Lee and Park, Reference Lee and Park2019; Park and Lee, Reference Park and Lee2023a).

In the first stage, owner i chooses the optimal ${h_i}$ to maximize its total profits ${\mathop \prod \nolimits _i}$. Putting (6)–(8) into (3) yields ${\mathop \prod \nolimits _i}({{h_0},{h_1},{h_2}} )$. From the first-order conditions, the following reaction function is obtained, with ${A_{0b}}$ and ${A_{1b}}$ given in appendix A:

(9)\begin{align}{h_0} & = R({{h_1},{h_2}} )= \frac{1}{{{A_{0b}}}}({1 - k} )({r + 1} ){r^2}\{r({r + 1} )({{h_1} + {h_2}} )\nonumber\\ & \quad + ({1 - r} )[{ - 2({2r + 1} )k + 3r + 2} ]w \}\end{align}
(10)\begin{align}& {h_j} = R({h_0},{h_l}) = {\textstyle{1 \over {{A_{\textrm{1b}}}}}}r(r + 1)(1 - k) \nonumber\\ & \quad \times \left( \begin{array}{@{}l@{}} {r^2}(r + 1)[ - 2(r + 1)k + 3r + 2][(2r + 1){k^2} - (3r + 2)(2k - 1)]{h_0} + (3r + 2)\\ \times (r + 1)[(2{r^3} + 7{r^2} + 10r + 4){k^2} - (4{r^3} + 8{r^2} + 10r + 4)k + 3{r^3} + 2{r^2}]{h_l}\\ + r(1 - r)(3r + 2)[ - 2(r + 1)k + 3r + 2] [(2r + 1){k^\textrm{2}} - (3r + 2)(2k - 1)]w \end{array} \right)\end{align}

where $j,l = 1,2,\ j \ne l$. Thus, we have the following lemma:Footnote 7

Lemma 1 (i) ${h_0}$ increases with ${h_j}$ $(j = 1,2)$; (ii) ${h_j}$ increases with ${h_0}$ $(j = 1,2)$; (iii) ${h_j}$ increases (decreases) with ${h_l}$ if k is small (large) $(j,\ l = 1,\,2,\,j \ne l)$.

Lemma 1 represents the strategic relations of ECSR choices between insiders and outsiders when they compete on pricing under bilateral cross-ownership. First, lemma 1 (i) and (ii) state that firms' ECSR choices between insiders and outsiders are always strategic complements under price competition. This also confirms the results in a duopolistic price competition (Hirose et al., Reference Hirose, Lee and Matsumura2017; Lee and Park, Reference Lee and Park2019). However, lemma 1 (iii) states that the strategic relations between the insiders depend critically on the level of cross-ownership. When k is small, the insiders' ECSR choices remain strategic complements, due to the weak effects of cross-ownership, and thus each firm within the same financial network of cross-ownership increases its responsive pricing as its rival's price increases. However, when k is large, insiders take more care of their rival firm due to cross-ownership, and thus both firms can pursue collusive pricing without causing additional costs associated with increased abatement activities. Therefore, the strategic relations of ECSR between insiders become strategic substitutes when they share the strong effects of cross-ownership. These properties cause significant changes in the strategic decisions related to ECSR between insiders and outsiders in the following analysis.

Solving the first-order conditions gives the following optimal ECSR levels:

(11)\begin{equation}h_0^B = \frac{{{r^2}({1 - k} )({1 - {r^2}} ){\mathrm{\Phi }_b}w}}{{{\vartheta _b}}}\end{equation}
(12)\begin{equation}h_1^B = h_2^B=\frac{{{r^2}({1 - k} )({1 - {r^2}} )[{({2r + 1} ){k^2} + ({3r + 2} )({1 - 2k} )} ]{\psi _b}w}}{{{\vartheta _b}}},\end{equation}

where ${\Phi _b},{\psi _b}$, and ${\vartheta _b}$ are given in appendix A.

Proposition 1 (i) $h_i^B > 0(i = 0,\, 1,\,2)$; (ii) $h_0^B > h_j^B > 0\,(j = 1,2)$.

Proposition 1 (i) states that all firms are incentivized to undertake ECSR in a triopoly market with price competition. This is because there is a cost pass-through effect between ECSR and pricing as a collusive device to increase equilibrium prices. Proposition 1 (ii) further states that an outsider has greater motivation to undertake ECSR than an insider. That is, cross-ownership will provide strong (weak) incentives to undertake ECSR for outsiders (insiders). This is because insiders already take care of their rival firms due to cross-ownership and thus collusive incentives through cross-ownership lessen collusive incentives through ECSR since abatement activities are costly (see lemma 1 (iii)). In response, the outsider has more incentive to engage in strategic collusion with its rivals through ECSR, as ECSR choices are always strategic complements to the outsider, which increases equilibrium prices and thus profits.

By submitting (11) and (12) into (6)–(8) and (2), we obtain equilibrium prices, abatement levels and outputs: ${p_i}({h_0^B,\, h_1^B,\, h_2^B} )$, $y_i^B = {y_i}({h_i^B} )$, and $q_i^B = {q_i}({h_0^B,\, h_1^B,\, h_2^B} ),\,(i = 0,\, 1,\, 2)$. Then, we identify the resulting environmental damage and social welfare in equilibrium as functions of parameters r, k and $d$:Footnote 8

(13)\begin{equation}{D^B} = \frac{d}{2} {\left[ {\mathop \sum \limits_{i = 0}^2 (q_i^B - y_i^B)} \right]^2}\end{equation}
(14)\begin{align}S{W^B} & =\mathop \sum \limits_{i = 0}^2 \left\{ {\left[ {w - ({1 - r} )q_i^B - r\mathop \sum \limits_{j = 0}^2 q_j^B} \right]q_i^B - \dfrac{{{{({y_i^B} )}^2}}}{2}} \right\}\nonumber\\ & \quad + \dfrac{1}{2}\left[ {\mathop \sum \limits_{j = 0}^2 {{({q_j^B} )}^2} + 2r({q_0^Bq_1^B + q_0^Bq_2^B + q_1^Bq_2^B} )} \right] - \dfrac{d}{2}{\left[ {\mathop \sum \limits_{i = 0}^2 ({q_i^B - y_i^B} )} \right]^2}. \end{align}

Proposition 2 (i) $(\partial h_0^B/\partial k) > 0$; (ii) There exists $\overline k (r )$, resulting in $(\partial h_j^B/\partial k) > (\!{\lt})0\,(j = 1,2)$ if $0 < k < \overline k (r )(\overline k (r )< k < 0.5)$.

Proposition 2 implies that the outsider increases its ECSR level as the share of insider cross-ownership increases, while insiders have non-monotone relationships between the ECSR level and the share of cross-ownership. First, proposition 2 (i) states that an outsider increases its ECSR level as the share of cross-ownership by insiders grows. That is, as insiders take more care of their rival firm through cross-ownership, the strategic collusive incentive through ECSR by an outsider increases. The causes will be explained by examining insider responses. Second, proposition 2 (ii) states that insiders increase (decrease) the ECSR level as the share of cross-ownership increases if k is small (large). This adverse outcome of ECSR comes from the findings in lemma 1 (iii) that an insider has already taken care of its rival firm due to cross-ownership; thus, collusive incentives through ECSR are lessened when the share of cross-ownership is sufficiently large. If k is small, the cross-ownership effect is weak, which increases the incentive for ECSR to form a strategic collusion with its rivals. In that case, firms' ECSR choices between insiders and outsider are strategic complements and thus, a larger share of cross-ownership increases the outsider's ECSR as well. However, if k is large, an insider's incentive to engage in strategic collusion with its rivals through cross-ownership is already strong, which decreases ECSR. In this case, an increase of k has two effects on ${h_0}$.Footnote 9 A direct effect on ${h_0}$ is always positive and moves the reaction function of ${h_0}$ upward, while an indirect effect through changing ${h_1}$ and ${h_2}$ depends on the relative share of cross-ownership. If k is relatively small, an indirect effect is always positive due to the strategic complement effect between ${h_0}$ and ${h_j}$ $({j = 1,\, 2} )$, which moves the reaction function of ${h_j}$ upward, and thus k increases ${h_0}$. However, if k is relatively large, the indirect effect is negative due to the strategic substitute effect between ${h_0}$ and ${h_j}$ $({j = 1,\, 2} ),$ which moves the reaction function of ${h_j}$ downward. In this case, a direct effect always outweighs an indirect effect, irrespective of k; thus k always increases ${h_0}$. Therefore, as k increases, the strategic collusive incentives associated with ECSR by an outsider always increase, regardless of the responses of cross-ownership insiders. Notably, product substitutability also affects the effects of cross-ownership on the strategic level of ECSR, especially when the share of cross-ownership is small. Figure 1 shows that if k is not high, as the degree of product substitutability increases, market competition becomes more intense; thus k increases insider ECSR levels.

Lemma 2 (i) $(\partial p_0^B/\partial k) > 0$ and $(\partial p_1^B/\partial k) = (\partial p_2^B/\partial k) > 0$; (ii) $(\partial {Q^B}/\partial k) < 0$ where ${Q^B} = \sum\nolimits_{i = 0}^2 {q_i^B}$; (iii) $(\partial y_0^B/\partial k) > 0$ and $(\partial y_1^B/\partial k) = (\partial y_2^B/\partial k) > ( < )0$ if k is small (large) where ${Y^B} = \sum\nolimits_{i = 0}^2 {y_i^B}$; and (iv) $(\partial ({E^B})/\partial k) < 0$ where ${E^B} = \sum\nolimits_{i = 0}^2 {e_i^B}$.

Figure 1. The sign of $(\partial h_j^B/\partial k)\,(j = 1,\, 2)$ under bilateral cross shareholding.

Lemma 2 represents the effects of cross-ownership on equilibrium outcomes. First, lemma 2 (i) states that cross-ownership always increases equilibrium prices. There are two effects of the change of cross-ownership: a direct collusive effect between the insiders involved in cross-ownership and an indirect cost pass-through effect between ECSR and price. For an outsider, according to proposition 2 (i) and lemma 1, both effects are positive and therefore the outsider has a strong incentive to increase its price. However, for insiders, a direct collusive effect is positive but an indirect effect depends on the cross-ownership share (proposition 2 (ii)). Thus, it reveals that a direct effect always outweighs an indirect effect, irrespective of k. As a result, increased market prices decrease total industry outputs and also provide lemma 2 (ii). Furthermore, an outsider always enhances its abatement activities as it always increases its ECSR (proposition 2 (i)), but the insider increases ECSR only when the share of cross-ownership is small. This results in lemma 2 (iii). Finally, lemma 2 (iv) reveals that the decrease in total industry outputs is sufficient to reduce total industry emissions, irrespective of cross-ownership share. These results result in proposition 3.

Proposition 3 (i) $(\partial {D^B}/\partial k) < 0$; (ii) There exists $\overline d ({r,k} )\,(\overline d ({r,k} )> 0)$, resulting in $(\partial S{W^B}/\partial k) < ( > )0$ if $d < ( > )\overline d ({r,k} )$.

Proposition 3 (i) states that cross-ownership can decrease environmental damage and improve environmental quality. This is a direct result of lemma 2 (iv). Proposition 3 (ii) shows that cross-ownership decreases social welfare only when environmental damage is minimal; however, it increases social welfare when environmental damage is severe. This is because a trade-off exists between the price-increasing effect (lemma 2 (i)), which decreases consumer surplus, and the environmental quality-improving effect (lemma 2 (iv)). Therefore, the latter effect outweighs the former effect only when environmental damage is significant. Figure 2 shows that more serious levels of environmental damage or higher degrees of product substitutability are required to improve social welfare when the cross-ownership share is sufficiently large. Therefore, cross-ownership may or may not improve social welfare, depending on the level of environmental damage. These findings have important policy implications because they indicate that as modern enterprises reformulate green delegation contracts, antitrust authorities should also develop guidelines for appropriate shares of cross-ownership to improve both environmental quality and social welfare, especially when environmental damage is severe.

Figure 2. The sign of $(\partial S{W^B}/\partial k)$ under bilateral cross-shareholding.

4. Comparisons with unilateral cross-shareholding

In this section, an asymmetric cross-ownership structure between private firms is considered and compared with the previous findings under symmetric bilateral cross-shareholding. Specifically, a unilateral cross-shareholding case is examined where only firm 1 holds k $(0 < k < 0.5)$ shares of firm 2, while the reverse is not true. The objective functions of owners are: ${\mathop \prod \nolimits _0} = {\pi _0}$, ${\mathop \prod \nolimits _1} = {\pi _1} + k{\pi _2}$ and ${\mathop \prod \nolimits _2} = ({1 - k} ){\pi _2}$. Other assumptions are the same as for the basic model.

Using a similar procedure, optimal ECSR levels can be obtained as follows:Footnote 10

(15)\begin{equation}h_0^U = \frac{{{r^2}({1 - {r^2}} )({kr + 4 + 6r} ){\mathrm{\Phi }_u}w}}{{{\vartheta _u}}}\end{equation}
(16)\begin{equation}h_1^U = \frac{{{r^2}({1 - {r^2}} ){\psi _u}w}}{{{\vartheta _u}}}\end{equation}
(17)\begin{equation}h_2^U = \frac{{{r^2}({k + 2} )({1 - k} )({1 - {r^2}} ){\rho _u}w}}{{{\vartheta _u}}}\end{equation}

where ${\mathrm{\Phi }_u}$, ${\psi _u}$, ${\rho _u}$, and ${\vartheta _u}$ are given in appendix A. Note that ECSR choices are strategic complements for all firms in most cases, while ${h_1}$ decreases with ${h_2}$ if k is large. Furthermore, comparing equilibrium results, similar results are observed in propositions 1 and 2 under bilateral cross-ownership.

Proposition 4 (i) $h_i^U > 0(i = 0,\, 1,2)$; (ii) $h_2^U < h_0^U < h_1^U$; (iii) $h_1^U - h_0^U < h_0^U - h_2^U$.

Proposition 5 (i) $(\partial h_0^U/\partial k) > 0$; (ii) $(\partial h_1^U/\partial k) > 0$; (iii) $(\partial h_2^U/\partial k) < 0$.

As shown in proposition 4 (i), all firms are incentivized to undertake ECSR under price competition, that is, there still exists a cost pass-through effect between ECSR and price. However, due to the asymmetry of cross-ownership under unilateral cross-shareholding, firm 1 (which owns a share of firm 2), has the most incentive to undertake ECSR under collusive motivation, while firm 2 has the least incentive to undertake ECSR. This is because firm 1 (firm 2) holds larger (smaller) shares of the collusion-induced profits in the networked group and thus, adverse profit returns yield the opposite result in which firm 1 (firm 2) has more (less) motivation to engage in collusion through ECSR. Proposition 4 (ii) and (iii) further reveal that under unilateral cross-shareholding, firm 2's decreased level of ECSR is larger than firm 1's increased level. This difference induces a lower ECSR for the outsider and thus firm 0's ECSR is intermediate. Additionally, as shown in proposition 5 (i), an outsider's ECSR increases with the share of unilateral cross-ownership. However, although firm 1's ECSR level increases with the share of unilateral cross-ownership, firm 2's ECSR level decreases, contrasting with the bilateral cross-shareholding case. This is because adverse profit returns also increase as the share of cross-ownership grows. Notably, most of these findings in lemma 2 and proposition 3 under the bilateral cross-ownership hold with some modifications (see the online appendix).

Next, unilateral cross-ownership and bilateral cross-ownership are compared.

Proposition 6 (i) $h_0^B > h_0^U$; (ii) $h_1^B < h_1^U$; (iii) When k is small, $h_2^B > h_2^U$; When k is large, $h_2^B > ( < )h_2^U$ if $k < ( > )\tilde{k}(r )$.Footnote 11

Proposition 6 (i) states that an outsider has more incentive to undertake ECSR under bilateral cross-ownership. This is because the insiders' ECSR choices are reversed under the asymmetry of cross-ownership. That is, as shown in proposition 4 (ii), under unilateral cross-ownership, firm 1 (firm 2) has more (less) incentive to undertake ECSR than the outsider firm 0; thus, unilateral cross-ownership reduces the outsider's ECSR. In particular, as shown in proposition 4 (ii) and (iii), firm 2's decreased level of ECSR is larger than firm 1's increased level, which induces a lower ECSR for firm 0 under unilateral cross-ownership. Additionally, proposition 6 (iii) states that firm 2's incentive to adopt ECSR depends on the share of cross-ownership and the degree of product substitutability. Figure 3 shows that firm 2 has more incentive under bilateral cross-ownership when firm 1 owns a small share of the profits, while the reverse is true under less severe price competition when firm 1 owns a large share of the profits.

Proposition 7 (i) ${D^B} < {D^U};$ (ii) There exists $\mathord{\buildrel{\lower3pt\hbox{$\scriptscriptstyle\smile$}} \over d} ({r,k} )(\mathord{\buildrel{\lower3pt\hbox{$\scriptscriptstyle\smile$}} \over d} ({r,k} )> 0)$ making that $S{W^B} > (< )S{W^U}$ if $d > ( < )\mathord{\buildrel{\lower3pt\hbox{$\scriptscriptstyle\smile$}} \over d} ({r,k} )$.

Figure 3. The sign of $h_2^B - h_2^U$.

Proposition 7 (i) states that, compared with the unilateral cross-ownership case, bilateral cross-ownership can increase environmental quality. That is, the impacts of ECSR on emissions under symmetric cross-ownership are stronger; thus, total emissions under bilateral cross-ownership are more reduced. This also implies that the greater the financial networking through cross-ownership, the better the resulting environmental quality. This can be explained by the finding that industry-wide ECSR is lessened under unilateral cross-ownership, as shown in proposition 6 (i), $h_0^B > h_0^U$, and proposition 4 (iii), $h_1^U - h_0^U < h_0^U - h_2^U$. That is, firm 0 decreases ECSR level and firm 2's decreased ECSR level is larger than firm 1's increased ECSR level under unilateral cross-ownership. However, proposition 7 (ii) reveals that the welfare comparisons depend on the share of cross-ownership and the level of environmental damage. Figure 4 shows that social welfare is improved under bilateral cross-ownership when environmental damage is severe because cross-ownership improves environmental quality. Otherwise, the result can be reversed, since there is a trade-off between the price-increasing effect of stronger ECSR and the environmental quality-improving effect.

Figure 4. The sign of $S{W^B} - S{W^U}$.

5. Concluding remarks

This paper examined the impact of cross-ownership on profitable ECSR incentives within a green delegation contract in a triopoly market. It revealed that the ECSR-induced cost pass-through effect under price competition in which the share of cross-ownership affects different incentives of financially networked firms to engage in collusive pricing through ECSR. It also demonstrated that bilateral cross-ownership provides strong incentives to undertake ECSR for outsiders but weak incentives for insiders in a financial cross-ownership network. Additionally, an outsider increases the ECSR level as the share of cross-ownership increases, while the insiders' ECSR has a non-monotone relationship. Further comparison with unilateral cross-ownership revealed that a firm that owns a share of its rival is more incentivized to undertake ECSR than its partially-owned rival under unilateral cross-ownership, while an outsider is more incentivized under bilateral cross-ownership. Furthermore, a firm's incentive to increase a market price through ECSR was revealed to critically depend on the share of cross-ownership and the degree of product substitutability. This could decrease environmental damage; thus increasing social welfare when the environmental damage is significant. Therefore, cross-ownership may or may not improve social welfare, depending on the severity of environmental damage. These findings have important policy implications as modern enterprises are reformulating green delegation contracts. Additionally, antitrust authorities should develop guidelines for appropriate shares of cross-ownership to improve environmental quality and social welfare, especially when environmental damage is severe.

Regarding future research, the robustness of these results must be confirmed using more general demand functions under oligopolistic competition. It is also important to examine strategic decisions through financial analysis in which the optimal share of cross-ownership is endogenously determined in association with green managerial delegation contracts and ECSR.

Supplementary material

The supplementary material for this article can be found at https://doi.org/10.1017/S1355770X24000032.

Acknowledgement

This work is financially supported by the Natural Science Foundation of Shandong Province (ZR2020MG072), the Ministry of Education of the Republic of Korea and the National Research Foundation of Korea (NRF-2023S1A5C2A07096111), and the Shandong Province Key Research and Development Program (Soft science) (2023RKY01019).

Competing interest

The authors declare none.

Appendix A

\begin{align*}{A_{0b}} & = [ - 2(2{\mkern 1mu} r + 1)({r^5} + 7{\mkern 1mu} {r^4} + 10{\mkern 1mu} {r^3} - 10{\mkern 1mu} {r^2} - 18{\mkern 1mu} r - 6){k^2}\\ & \quad + (26{\mkern 1mu} {r^5} + 96{\mkern 1mu} {r^4} + 10{\mkern 1mu} {r^3} - 136{\mkern 1mu} {r^2} - 108{\mkern 1mu} r - 24)\;k\\ & \quad - ({r^5} + 37{\mkern 1mu} {r^4} + 21{\mkern 1mu} {r^3} - 47{\mkern 1mu} {r^2} - 48{\mkern 1mu} r - 12)],\end{align*}
\[{A_{1b}} = \left( \begin{array}{l} - (16{\mkern 1mu} {r^8} + 148{\mkern 1mu} {r^7} + 460{\mkern 1mu} {r^6} + 460{\mkern 1mu} {r^5} - 316{\mkern 1mu} {r^4} - 1056{\mkern 1mu} {r^3}\\ \quad - \,896{\mkern 1mu} {r^2} - 336{\mkern 1mu} r - 48){k^4} + (48{\mkern 1mu} {r^8} + 526{\mkern 1mu} {r^7}\\\quad +\, 1821{\mkern 1mu} {r^6} + 1944{\mkern 1mu} {r^5} - 1167{\mkern 1mu} {r^4} - 4200{\mkern 1mu} {r^3} - 3584{\mkern 1mu} {r^2} - 1344{\mkern 1mu} r - 192){k^3}\\ \quad -\, (36{\mkern 1mu} {r^8} + 609{\mkern 1mu} {r^7} + 2631{\mkern 1mu} {r^6}\\\quad +\, 3189{\mkern 1mu} {r^5} - 1369{\mkern 1mu} {r^4} - 6124{\mkern 1mu} {r^3} - 5348{\mkern 1mu} {r^2} - 2016{\mkern 1mu} r - 288){k^2} + (234{\mkern 1mu} {r^7}\\ \quad +\, 1617{\mkern 1mu} {r^6} + 2348{\mkern 1mu} {r^5} - 539{\mkern 1mu} {r^4}\\\quad -\, 3892{\mkern 1mu} {r^3} - 3532{\mkern 1mu} {r^2} - 1344{\mkern 1mu} r - 192)k - (9{\mkern 1mu} {r^7} + 345{\mkern 1mu} {r^6} + 637{\mkern 1mu} {r^5} - 23{\mkern 1mu} {r^4}\\ \quad -\, 912{\mkern 1mu} {r^3} - 872{\mkern 1mu} {r^2} - 336{\mkern 1mu} r - 48) \end{array} \right),\]
\[{\Phi _b} = \left( \begin{array}{l} 4(2r + 1)(r + 1)(4{\mkern 1mu} {r^2} - 3{\mkern 1mu} r - 3)({r^2} + 4{\mkern 1mu} r + 2){k^3}\\ \quad -\, (72{\mkern 1mu} {r^6} + 430{\mkern 1mu} {r^5} + 376{\mkern 1mu} {r^4} - 438{\mkern 1mu} {r^3} - 808{\mkern 1mu} {r^2} - 416{\mkern 1mu} r - 72){k^2}\\\quad +\, (3{\mkern 1mu} r + 2)(12{\mkern 1mu} {r^5} + 119{\mkern 1mu} {r^4} + 52{\mkern 1mu} {r^3} - 155{\mkern 1mu} {r^2} - 148{\mkern 1mu} r - 36)k\\ \quad -\, (3{\mkern 1mu} r + 2)(35{\mkern 1mu} {r^4} + 20{\mkern 1mu} {r^3} - 47{\mkern 1mu} {r^2} - 48{\mkern 1mu} r - 12) \end{array} \right),\]
\[{\psi _b} = [2(2{\mkern 1mu} r + 1)(3{\mkern 1mu} {r^4} + 10{\mkern 1mu} {r^3} - 4{\mkern 1mu} {r^2} - 15{\mkern 1mu} r - 6)k - 35{\mkern 1mu} {r^4} - 20{\mkern 1mu} {r^3} + 47{\mkern 1mu} {r^2} + 48{\mkern 1mu} r + 12],\]
\[{\vartheta _b} = \left( \begin{array}{l} 4(2{\mkern 1mu} r + 1)(r + 1)({r^2} + 4{\mkern 1mu} r + 2)(4{\mkern 1mu} {r^2} - 3{\mkern 1mu} r - 3)({r^5} + 7{\mkern 1mu} {r^4}\\ \quad +\, 10{\mkern 1mu} {r^3} - 10{\mkern 1mu} {r^2} - 18{\mkern 1mu} r - 6){k^4}\\\quad - \, (48{\mkern 1mu} {r^{11}} + 868{\mkern 1mu} {r^{10}} + 4658{\mkern 1mu} {r^9} + 7996{\mkern 1mu} {r^8} - 4922{\mkern 1mu} {r^7} - 27578{\mkern 1mu} {r^6}\\ \quad - \, 22428{\mkern 1mu} {r^5} + 9426{\mkern 1mu} {r^4} + 25892{\mkern 1mu} {r^3}\\\quad +\, 16992{\mkern 1mu} {r^2} + 5016{\mkern 1mu} r + 576){k^3} + (500{\mkern 1mu} {r^{10}} + 4762{\mkern 1mu} {r^9}\\ \quad +\, 12112{\mkern 1mu} {r^8} - 696{\mkern 1mu} {r^7} - 34250{\mkern 1mu} {r^6} - 35020{\mkern 1mu} {r^5}\\\quad +\, 6786{\mkern 1mu} {r^4} + 33298{\mkern 1mu} {r^3} + 23676{\mkern 1mu} {r^2} + 7296{\mkern 1mu} r + 864){k^2}\\ \quad -\, (3{\mkern 1mu} r + 2)[(12{\mkern 1mu} {r^9} + 553{\mkern 1mu} {r^8} + 2089{\mkern 1mu} {r^7} - 316{\mkern 1mu} {r^6}\\\quad - \, 5764{\mkern 1mu} {r^5} - 3977{\mkern 1mu} {r^4} + 2779{\mkern 1mu} {r^3} + 4452{\mkern 1mu} {r^2} + 1932{\mkern 1mu} r + 288)k\\ \quad -\, (35{\mkern 1mu} {r^4} + 20{\mkern 1mu} {r^3} - 47{\mkern 1mu} {r^2} - 48{\mkern 1mu} r - 12)\\ \quad ({r^4} + 13{\mkern 1mu} {r^3} - {r^2} - 15{\mkern 1mu} r - 6)] \end{array} \right),\]
\[{\beta _{0b}} = \left( \begin{array}{l} [(4{\kern 1pt} {r^4} + 12{\kern 1pt} {r^3} - 8{\kern 1pt} {r^2} - 18{\kern 1pt} r - 6)k + 6 + 15{\kern 1pt} r + 2{\kern 1pt} {r^2}\\ \quad -\, 11{\kern 1pt} {r^3}][(8{\kern 1pt} r + 4)(r + 1)({r^2} + 4{\kern 1pt} r + 2)(4{\kern 1pt} {r^2}\\\quad -\, 3{\kern 1pt} r - 3){k^3} + ( - 376{\kern 1pt} {r^4} + 808{\kern 1pt} {r^2} + 416{\kern 1pt} r - 72{\kern 1pt} {r^6} + 438{\kern 1pt} {r^3}\\ \quad +\, 72 - 430{\kern 1pt} {r^5}){k^2} + (3{\kern 1pt} r + 2)(12{\kern 1pt} {r^5}\\\quad +\, 119{\kern 1pt} {r^4} + 52{\kern 1pt} {r^3} - 155{\kern 1pt} {r^2} - 148{\kern 1pt} r - 36)k\\ \quad -\, (3{\kern 1pt} r + 2)(35{\kern 1pt} {r^4} + 20{\kern 1pt} {r^3} - 47{\kern 1pt} {r^2} - 48{\kern 1pt} r - 12)] \end{array} \right),\]
\[{\beta _{1b}} = \left( \begin{array}{l} (1 - k)[(4{\kern 1pt} r + 2)(3{\kern 1pt} {r^4} + 10{\kern 1pt} {r^3} - 4{\kern 1pt} {r^2} - 15{\kern 1pt} r - 6)k\\ \quad -\, 35{\kern 1pt} {r^4} - 20{\kern 1pt} {r^3} + 47{\kern 1pt} {r^2} + 48{\kern 1pt} r + 12][( - 2{\kern 1pt} r - 2)({r^2} + 4{\kern 1pt} r + 2)(4{\kern 1pt} {r^2} \\\quad-\, 3{\kern 1pt} r - 3){k^2} + (3{\kern 1pt} r + 2)(4{\kern 1pt} {r^4} + 21{\kern 1pt} {r^3} - 4{\kern 1pt} {r^2} - 29{\kern 1pt} r - 12)k\\ \quad -\, (3{\kern 1pt} r + 2)(11{\kern 1pt} {r^3} - 2{\kern 1pt} {r^2} - 15{\kern 1pt} r - 6)] \end{array} \right),\]
\[{\lambda _b} = \left( \begin{array}{l} (8{\kern 1pt} r + 8)(4{\kern 1pt} {r^2} - 3{\kern 1pt} r - 3)({r^2} + 4{\kern 1pt} r + 2)(4{\kern 1pt} {r^4} + 14{\kern 1pt} {r^3} - 4{\kern 1pt} {r^2}\\ \quad -\, 21{\kern 1pt} r - 9){(2{\kern 1pt} r + 1)^2}{k^4} - (8{\kern 1pt} r + 4)(132{\kern 1pt} {r^{10}} + 1471{\kern 1pt} {r^9}\\\quad +\, 4429{\kern 1pt} {r^8} + 938{\kern 1pt} {r^7} - 11987{\kern 1pt} {r^6} - 14832{\kern 1pt} {r^5} + 748{\kern 1pt} {r^4} + 13117{\kern 1pt} {r^3}\\ \quad +\, 10386{\kern 1pt} {r^2} + 3438{\kern 1pt} r + 432){k^3} + (176390{\kern 1pt} {r^3}\\\quad -\, 219976{\kern 1pt} {r^6} + 2592 - 93210{\kern 1pt} {r^7} + 432{\kern 1pt} {r^{11}} + 10316{\kern 1pt} {r^{10}} + 50328{\kern 1pt} {r^8}\\ \quad +\, 118968{\kern 1pt} {r^4} + 50188{\kern 1pt} {r^9} + 24912{\kern 1pt} r + 95724{\kern 1pt} {r^2}\\\quad -\, 100696{\kern 1pt} {r^5}){k^2} - (3{\kern 1pt} r + 2)(888{\kern 1pt} {r^9} + 7651{\kern 1pt} {r^8} + 7339{\kern 1pt} {r^7} - 16810{\kern 1pt} {r^6}\\ \quad - \, 30466{\kern 1pt} {r^5} - 4973{\kern 1pt} {r^4} + 21635{\kern 1pt} {r^3} + 19428{\kern 1pt} {r^2}\\\quad +\, 6732{\kern 1pt} r + 864)k + (9{\kern 1pt} r + 6)(r + 1)(13{\kern 1pt} {r^3} - 15{\kern 1pt} r - 6)(35{\kern 1pt} {r^4}\\ \quad +\, 20{\kern 1pt} {r^3} - 47{\kern 1pt} {r^2} - 48{\kern 1pt} r - 12) \end{array} \right), \]
\[{\alpha _{0b}} = (1 - k)\left( \begin{array}{l} (8{\kern 1pt} r + 4)(r + 1)({r^2} + 4{\kern 1pt} r + 2)(4{\kern 1pt} {r^2} - 3{\kern 1pt} r - 3){k^3} + ( - 376{\kern 1pt} {r^4}\\ \quad +\, 808{\kern 1pt} {r^2} + 416{\kern 1pt} r - 72{\kern 1pt} {r^6} + 438{\kern 1pt} {r^3} + 72 - 430{\kern 1pt} {r^5}){k^2}\\\quad +\, (3{\kern 1pt} r + 2)(12{\kern 1pt} {r^5} + 119{\kern 1pt} {r^4} + 52{\kern 1pt} {r^3} - 155{\kern 1pt} {r^2}\\ \quad -\, 148{\kern 1pt} r - 36)k - (3{\kern 1pt} r + 2)(35{\kern 1pt} {r^4} + 20{\kern 1pt} {r^3} - 47{\kern 1pt} {r^2} - 48{\kern 1pt} r - 12) \end{array} \right),\]
\begin{align*}{\alpha _{1b}} & = [(4{\kern 1pt} r + 2)(3{\kern 1pt} {r^4} + 10{\kern 1pt} {r^3} - 4{\kern 1pt} {r^2} - 15{\kern 1pt} r - 6)k - 35{\kern 1pt} {r^4} - 20{\kern 1pt} {r^3} + 47{\kern 1pt} {r^2}\\ & \quad +\, 48{\kern 1pt} r + 12][(2{\kern 1pt} r + 1){k^2} + ( - 6{\kern 1pt} r - 4)k + 3{\kern 1pt} r + 2],\end{align*}
\[{\varsigma _b} = \left( \begin{array}{l} (8{\kern 1pt} r + 8)(4{\kern 1pt} {r^2} - 3{\kern 1pt} r - 3)({r^2} + 4{\kern 1pt} r + 2)(3{\kern 1pt} {r^4} + 14{\kern 1pt} {r^3} - 3{\kern 1pt} {r^2}\\ \quad - \, 21{\kern 1pt} r - 9){(2{\kern 1pt} r + 1)^2}{k^4} - (8{\kern 1pt} r + 4)(56{\kern 1pt} {r^{10}} + 1076{\kern 1pt} {r^9} + 4205{\kern 1pt} {r^8}\\\quad +\, 1772{\kern 1pt} {r^7} - 10961{\kern 1pt} {r^6} - 14913{\kern 1pt} {r^5} + 82{\kern 1pt} {r^4} + 12759{\kern 1pt} {r^3} + 10326{\kern 1pt} {r^2}\\ \quad +\, 3438{\kern 1pt} r + 432){k^3} + (42654{\kern 1pt} {r^9} + 2592 - 112182{\kern 1pt} {r^5} - 211988{\kern 1pt} {r^6}\\ \quad +\, 3416{\kern 1pt} {r^{10}} - 576{\kern 1pt} {r^{11}} + 107256{\kern 1pt} {r^4} + 24912{\kern 1pt} r + 172254{\kern 1pt} {r^3}\\ \quad +\, 95196{\kern 1pt} {r^2} + 61480{\kern 1pt} {r^8} - 69046{\kern 1pt} {r^7}){k^2} + (3{\kern 1pt} r + 2)(144{\kern 1pt} {r^{10}}\\ \quad +\, 728{\kern 1pt} {r^9} - 6383{\kern 1pt} {r^8} - 10739{\kern 1pt} {r^7} + 12362{\kern 1pt} {r^6} + 30778{\kern 1pt} {r^5}\\ \quad +\, 7769{\kern 1pt} {r^4} - 20163{\kern 1pt} {r^3} - 19188{\kern 1pt} {r^2} - 6732{\kern 1pt} r - 864)k\\ \quad -\, (9{\kern 1pt} r + 6)(r + 1)(4{\kern 1pt} {r^2} - 3{\kern 1pt} r - 3)(35{\kern 1pt} {r^4}\\ \quad +\, 20{\kern 1pt} {r^3} - 47{\kern 1pt} {r^2} - 48{\kern 1pt} r - 12)({r^2} - 3{\kern 1pt} r - 2) \end{array} \right),\]
\[{Z_b} = \left( \begin{array}{l} 8{\mkern 1mu} (r + 1){(2{\mkern 1mu} r + 1)^2}({r^2} + 4{\mkern 1mu} r + 2)(4{\mkern 1mu} {r^2} - 3{\mkern 1mu} r - 3)(3{\mkern 1mu} {r^4}\\ \quad +\, 14{\mkern 1mu} {r^3} - 3{\mkern 1mu} {r^2} - 21{\mkern 1mu} r - 9){k^4} - 4(2{\mkern 1mu} r + 1)(56{\mkern 1mu} {r^{10}} + 1076{\mkern 1mu} {r^9}\\\quad +\, 4205{\mkern 1mu} {r^8} + 1772{\mkern 1mu} {r^7} - 10961{\mkern 1mu} {r^6} - 14913{\mkern 1mu} {r^5} + 82{\mkern 1mu} {r^4} + 12759{\mkern 1mu} {r^3}\\ \quad +\, 10326{\mkern 1mu} {r^2} + 3438{\mkern 1mu} r + 432){k^3} + (24912{\mkern 1mu} r\\\quad +\, 107256{\mkern 1mu} {r^4} + 3416{\mkern 1mu} {r^{10}} - 69046{\mkern 1mu} {r^7} + 42654{\mkern 1mu} {r^9}\\ \quad +\, 95196{\mkern 1mu} {r^2} - 211988{\mkern 1mu} {r^6} + 61480{\mkern 1mu} {r^8} + 2592 + 172254{\mkern 1mu} {r^3}\\\quad -\, 576{\mkern 1mu} {r^{11}} - 112182{\mkern 1mu} {r^5}){k^2} + (3{\mkern 1mu} r + 2)[(144{\mkern 1mu} {r^{10}} + 728{\mkern 1mu} {r^9}\\ \quad - \, 6383{\mkern 1mu} {r^8} - 10739{\mkern 1mu} {r^7} + 12362{\mkern 1mu} {r^6} + 30778{\mkern 1mu} {r^5} + 7769{\mkern 1mu} {r^4}\\\quad -\, 20163{\mkern 1mu} {r^3} - 19188{\mkern 1mu} {r^2} - 6732{\mkern 1mu} r - 864)k\\ \quad -\, 3(r + 1)(4{\mkern 1mu} {r^2} - 3{\mkern 1mu} r - 3)({r^2} - 3{\mkern 1mu} r - 2)(35{\mkern 1mu} {r^4} + 20{\mkern 1mu} {r^3} - 47{\mkern 1mu} {r^2} - 48{\mkern 1mu} r - 12)] \end{array} \right),\]
\begin{align*}\small{G_b} = (2{\kern 1pt} r + 1)\left( \begin{array}{@{}l@{}} - 32{(r + 1)^2}{(2{\kern 1pt} r + 1)^3}{({r^2} + 4{\kern 1pt} r + 2)^2}{(4{\kern 1pt} {r^2} - 3{\kern 1pt} r - 3)^2}(5{\kern 1pt} {r^9} - 7{\kern 1pt} {r^8}\\ \quad -\, 240{\kern 1pt} {r^7} - 466{\kern 1pt} {r^6} + 578{\kern 1pt} {r^5} + 1490{\kern 1pt} {r^4} + 201{\kern 1pt} {r^3} - 1119{\kern 1pt} {r^2}\\\quad -\, 792{\kern 1pt} r - 162){k^8} + 32(r + 1){(2{\kern 1pt} r + 1)^2}({r^2} + 4{\kern 1pt} r + 2)(4{\kern 1pt} {r^2} - 3{\kern 1pt} r\\ \quad -\, 3)(240{\kern 1pt} {r^{15}} + 1744{\kern 1pt} {r^{14}} - 6758{\kern 1pt} {r^{13}} - 81214{\kern 1pt} {r^{12}} - 173251{\kern 1pt} {r^{11}}\\\quad +\, 129878{\kern 1pt} {r^{10}} + 790848{\kern 1pt} {r^9} + 586263{\kern 1pt} {r^8} - 780191{\kern 1pt} {r^7} - 1459520{\kern 1pt} {r^6}\\ \quad - \, 520784{\kern 1pt} {r^5} + 594909{\kern 1pt} {r^4} + 740028{\kern 1pt} {r^3} + 352548{\kern 1pt} {r^2}\\\quad + \, 82188{\kern 1pt} r + 7776){k^7} - 8(2{\kern 1pt} r + 1)(16128{\kern 1pt} {r^{21}} + 274240{\kern 1pt} {r^{20}}\\ \quad + \, 1020624{\kern 1pt} {r^{19}} - 5501796{\kern 1pt} {r^{18}} - 50093010{\kern 1pt} {r^{17}} - 113402684{\kern 1pt} {r^{16}}\\\quad +\, 51424378{\kern 1pt} {r^{15}} + 601002264{\kern 1pt} {r^{14}} + 750530633{\kern 1pt} {r^{13}} - 504119609{\kern 1pt} {r^{12}}\\ \quad -\, 2065106995{\kern 1pt} {r^{11}} - 1489174341{\kern 1pt} {r^{10}} + 1027522973{\kern 1pt} {r^9}\\\quad +\, 2488948621{\kern 1pt} {r^8} + 1494335661{\kern 1pt} {r^7} - 270505747{\kern 1pt} {r^6} - 1011610848{\kern 1pt} {r^5}\\ \quad -\, 751354860{\kern 1pt} {r^4} - 307797048{\kern 1pt} {r^3} - 75892680{\kern 1pt} {r^2}\\\quad -\, 10622016{\kern 1pt} r - 653184){k^6} + 8(27648{\kern 1pt} {r^{22}} + 740928{\kern 1pt} {r^{21}} + 5203552{\kern 1pt} {r^{20}}\\ \quad -\, 563676{\kern 1pt} {r^{19}} - 136132646{\kern 1pt} {r^{18}} - 499086362{\kern 1pt} {r^{17}}\\\quad - \, 304785428{\kern 1pt} {r^{16}} + 1815531781{\kern 1pt} {r^{15}} + 4002092862{\kern 1pt} {r^{14}} + 764324384{\kern 1pt} {r^{13}}\\ \quad -\, 7366871736{\kern 1pt} {r^{12}} - 9778949650{\kern 1pt} {r^{11}} - 749056290{\kern 1pt} {r^{10}}\\\quad +\, 9814393406{\kern 1pt} {r^9} + 10266080684{\kern 1pt} {r^8} + 2630593761{\kern 1pt} {r^7} - 3579135958{\kern 1pt} {r^6}\\ \quad -\, 4417222140{\kern 1pt} {r^5} - 2510698512{\kern 1pt} {r^4} - 868511520{\kern 1pt} {r^3}\\\quad -\, 187636176{\kern 1pt} {r^2} - 23470560{\kern 1pt} r - 1306368){k^5} - 2(31104{\kern 1pt} {r^{22}}\\ \quad + \, 1791360{\kern 1pt} {r^{21}} + 21008952{\kern 1pt} {r^{20}} + 51263636{\kern 1pt} {r^{19}} - 354951580{\kern 1pt} {r^{18}}\\\quad -\, 2065866769{\kern 1pt} {r^{17}} - 2455181381{\kern 1pt} {r^{16}} + 5863178696{\kern 1pt} {r^{15}}\\ \quad +\, 18150476174{\kern 1pt} {r^{14}} + 8694879726{\kern 1pt} {r^{13}} - 27815151602{\kern 1pt} {r^{12}}\\\quad -\, 45999100572{\kern 1pt} {r^{11}} - 11195963304{\kern 1pt} {r^{10}} + 38971494395{\kern 1pt} {r^9}\\ \quad +\, 47425004543{\kern 1pt} {r^8} + 15830953016{\kern 1pt} {r^7} - 13542015522{\kern 1pt} {r^6}\\\quad -\, 19332226608{\kern 1pt} {r^5} - 11524319784{\kern 1pt} {r^4} - 4105143072{\kern 1pt} {r^3}\\ \quad -\, 906671232{\kern 1pt} {r^2} - 115499520{\kern 1pt} r - 6531840){k^4} + 4(3{\kern 1pt} r + 2)(70848{\kern 1pt} {r^{20}}\\\quad +\, 1646136{\kern 1pt} {r^{19}} + 7985374{\kern 1pt} {r^{18}} - 19013012{\kern 1pt} {r^{17}} - 193611731{\kern 1pt} {r^{16}}\\ \quad - \, 260052490{\kern 1pt} {r^{15}} + 577983491{\kern 1pt} {r^{14}} + 1702159766{\kern 1pt} {r^{13}}\\\quad + \, 475846390{\kern 1pt} {r^{12}} - 2918208952{\kern 1pt} {r^{11}} - 3659625248{\kern 1pt} {r^{10}}\\ \quad +\, 195127436{\kern 1pt} {r^9} + 3844050453{\kern 1pt} {r^8} + 3198629194{\kern 1pt} {r^7} + 228007967{\kern 1pt} {r^6}\\\quad - \, 1458647262{\kern 1pt} {r^5} - 1274624904{\kern 1pt} {r^4} - 560251152{\kern 1pt} {r^3}\\ \quad -\, 144176976{\kern 1pt} {r^2} - 20785248{\kern 1pt} r - 1306368){k^3} - (3{\kern 1pt} r + 2)(10368{\kern 1pt} {r^{20}}\\\quad +\, 1368864{\kern 1pt} {r^{19}} + 14640376{\kern 1pt} {r^{18}} + 7402961{\kern 1pt} {r^{17}} - 274460046{\kern 1pt} {r^{16}}\\ \quad -\, 608824921{\kern 1pt} {r^{15}} + 593911918{\kern 1pt} {r^{14}} + 3008178018{\kern 1pt} {r^{13}}\\\quad +\, 1746262420{\kern 1pt} {r^{12}} - 4390284866{\kern 1pt} {r^{11}} - 7020780764{\kern 1pt} {r^{10}} - 871208475{\kern 1pt} {r^9}\\ \quad +\, 6343418986{\kern 1pt} {r^8} + 6122067675{\kern 1pt} {r^7} + 956195126{\kern 1pt} {r^6}\\\quad - \, 2397592296{\kern 1pt} {r^5} - 2300870928{\kern 1pt} {r^4} - 1052524944{\kern 1pt} {r^3} - 278034336{\kern 1pt} {r^2}\\ \quad - \, 40891392{\kern 1pt} r - 2612736){k^2} + 2{(3{\kern 1pt} r + 2)^2}(35{\kern 1pt} {r^4} + 20{\kern 1pt} {r^3}\\\quad - \, 47{\kern 1pt} {r^2} - 48{\kern 1pt} r - 12)(288{\kern 1pt} {r^{14}} + 12064{\kern 1pt} {r^{13}} + 30795{\kern 1pt} {r^{12}} - 245306{\kern 1pt} {r^{11}}\\ \quad -\, 470232{\kern 1pt} {r^{10}} + 601968{\kern 1pt} {r^9} + 1700810{\kern 1pt} {r^8} + 203828{\kern 1pt} {r^7}\\\quad -\, 2042652{\kern 1pt} {r^6} - 1646712{\kern 1pt} {r^5} + 268323{\kern 1pt} {r^4} + 1018326{\kern 1pt} {r^3} + 595548{\kern 1pt} {r^2}\\ \quad + \, 154008{\kern 1pt} r + 15552)k - 3(r + 1)({r^2} - 3{\kern 1pt} r - 2)(3{\kern 1pt} r\\\quad +\, 2{)^2}{(35{\kern 1pt} {r^4} + 20{\kern 1pt} {r^3} - 47{\kern 1pt} {r^2} - 48{\kern 1pt} r - 12)^2}(8{\kern 1pt} {r^6} + 137{\kern 1pt} {r^5} - 92{\kern 1pt} {r^4}\\ \quad -\, 276{\kern 1pt} {r^3} + 30{\kern 1pt} {r^2} + 171{\kern 1pt} r + 54) \end{array} \right),\end{align*}
\begin{align*}{\Phi _u} & = [{r^2}(r - 1)(2 + 3{\kern 1pt} r)(2{\kern 1pt} r + 1)k - 35{\kern 1pt} {r^4} - 20{\kern 1pt} {r^3} + 47{\kern 1pt} {r^2}\\ & \quad +\, 48{\kern 1pt} r + 12][{r^2}(6{\kern 1pt} {r^3} - 7{\kern 1pt} r - 3)k - 35{\kern 1pt} {r^4} - 20{\kern 1pt} {r^3} + 47{\kern 1pt} {r^2} + 48{\kern 1pt} r + 12],\end{align*}
\[{\psi _u} = \left( \begin{array}{@{}l@{}} [{r^2}(2{\kern 1pt} r + 1)(9{\kern 1pt} {r^3} + {r^2} - 12{\kern 1pt} r - 6)k - (2 + 3{\kern 1pt} r)(35{\kern 1pt} {r^4}\\ \quad +\, 20{\kern 1pt} {r^3} - 47{\kern 1pt} {r^2} - 48{\kern 1pt} r - 12)][r(10{\kern 1pt} {r^4} - 4{\kern 1pt} {r^3} - 15{\kern 1pt} {r^2}\\\quad -\, 9{\kern 1pt} r - 2){k^2} + (12{\kern 1pt} {r^5} - 61{\kern 1pt} {r^4} - 42{\kern 1pt} {r^3} + 59{\kern 1pt} {r^2} + 56{\kern 1pt} r + 12)k\\ \quad - \, 70{\kern 1pt} {r^4} - 40{\kern 1pt} {r^3} + 94{\kern 1pt} {r^2} + 96{\kern 1pt} r + 24] \end{array} \right),\]
\begin{align*}{\rho _u} = \left( \begin{array}{@{}l@{}} [{r^2}(r - 1)(2 + 3{\kern 1pt} r)(2{\kern 1pt} r + 1)k + 12 - 35{\kern 1pt} {r^4} - 20{\kern 1pt} {r^3} + 47{\kern 1pt} {r^2} + 48{\kern 1pt} r][{r^2}(2{\kern 1pt} r\\\quad +\, 1)(9{\kern 1pt} {r^3} + {r^2} - 12{\kern 1pt} r - 6)k - (2 + 3{\kern 1pt} r)(35{\kern 1pt} {r^4} + 20{\kern 1pt} {r^3} - 47{\kern 1pt} {r^2} - 48{\kern 1pt} r - 12)] \end{array} \right) \quad {\rm and}\end{align*}
\[{\vartheta _u} = \left( \begin{array}{@{}l@{}} - {r^8}(9{\kern 1pt} {r^3} + {r^2} - 12{\kern 1pt} r - 6){(1 - r)^2}{(2{\kern 1pt} r + 1)^3}{k^4} + 2{\kern 1pt} {r^6}(2{\kern 1pt} r + 1)(390{\kern 1pt} {r^8}\\ \quad -\, 210{\kern 1pt} {r^7} - 1201{\kern 1pt} {r^6} + 116{\kern 1pt} {r^5} + 1419{\kern 1pt} {r^4} + 430{\kern 1pt} {r^3} - 555{\kern 1pt} {r^2}\\\quad -\, 384{\kern 1pt} r - 69){k^3} - {r^4}(216{\kern 1pt} {r^{11}} + 13802{\kern 1pt} {r^{10}} + 5271{\kern 1pt} {r^9} - 52381{\kern 1pt} {r^8} - 44668{\kern 1pt} {r^7}\\ \quad + \, 56358{\kern 1pt} {r^6} + 86007{\kern 1pt} {r^5} + 9775{\kern 1pt} {r^4} - 43066{\kern 1pt} {r^3}\\ \quad- \, 31930{\kern 1pt} {r^2} - 9360{\kern 1pt} r - 1032){k^2} + 2{\kern 1pt} {r^2}( - 12 - 48{\kern 1pt} r - 47{\kern 1pt} {r^2} + 20{\kern 1pt} {r^3}\\ \quad +\, 35{\kern 1pt} {r^4})(36{\kern 1pt} {r^8} + 842{\kern 1pt} {r^7} + 327{\kern 1pt} {r^6} - 2184{\kern 1pt} {r^5} - 1950{\kern 1pt} {r^4}\\\quad +\, 950{\kern 1pt} {r^3} + 1895{\kern 1pt} {r^2} + 864{\kern 1pt} r + 132)k - 2(2 + 3{\kern 1pt} r)({r^4} + 13{\kern 1pt} {r^3} - {r^2}\\ \quad -\, 15{\kern 1pt} r - 6){(35{\kern 1pt} {r^4} + 20{\kern 1pt} {r^3} - 47{\kern 1pt} {r^2} - 48{\kern 1pt} r - 12)^2} \end{array} \right).\]

Appendix B

Proofs

Proof of lemma 1

We set ${M_{1b}} ={-} 2({\mkern 1mu} r + 1)k + 3{\mkern 1mu} r + 2][(2{\mkern 1mu} r + 1){k^2} + (3{\mkern 1mu} r + 2)(\textrm{1} - 2k)$ and ${M_{2b}} = (2{\mkern 1mu} {r^3} + 7{\mkern 1mu} {r^2} + 10{\mkern 1mu} r + 4){k^2} - (4{\mkern 1mu} {r^3} + 8{\mkern 1mu} {r^2} + 10{\mkern 1mu} r + 4)k + 3{\mkern 1mu} {r^3} + 2{\mkern 1mu} {r^2}$. We can prove ${A_{0b}} > 0,\;{A_{1b}} > 0,\;{M_{1b}} > 0$ and ${M_{2b}} > ( < )0$ if $k < ( > ){k_b}(r)$ (where ${k_b}(r) = (2{\kern 1pt} {r^3} + 4{\kern 1pt} {r^2} + 5{\kern 1pt} r + 2 - \sqrt {(2{\kern 1pt} r + 1)(r + 1)(1 + r - {r^2}){{(r + 2)}^2}} /(2{\kern 1pt} {r^3} + 7{\kern 1pt} {r^2} + 10{\kern 1pt} r + 4)) \in (0,0.5)$). Thus, $(\partial {h_0}/\partial {h_j}) = (\partial R({h_1},{h_2})/\partial {h_j}) = ({(r + 1)^2}{r^3}(1 - k)/{A_{0b}}) > 0$, $(\partial {h_j}/\partial {h_0}) = (\partial R({h_0},{h_l})/\partial {h_0}) = ((1 - k){(r + 1)^2}{r^3}{M_{1b}}/{A_{1b}}) > 0$ and $(\partial {h_j}/\partial {h_l}) = (\partial R({h_0},{h_l})/\partial {h_l}) = (r{(r + 1)^2}(3{\mkern 1mu} r + 2)(1 - k) {M_{2b}}/{A_{1b}}) > ( < )0$ if $k < ( > ){k_b}(r)\;(j,\;l = 1,2,\;j \ne l)$.

Proof of lemma 2

We can obtain $p_0^B =((1 - r){\beta _{0b}}w/2{\vartheta _b}),\;p_1^B = p_2^B = ((1 - r){\beta _{1b}}w/2{\vartheta _b}),\;{Q^B} = ({\lambda _b}w/2 (2r + 1){\vartheta _b}),\;y_0^B = ({r^2}(1 - {r^2}){\alpha _{0b}}w/{\vartheta _b})$, $y_1^B = y_\textrm{2}^B = ({r^2}(1 - {r^2}){\alpha _{1b}}w/{\vartheta _b}), {E^B} \,= \,({\varsigma _b}w/2 (2r + 1){\vartheta _b})$, where ${\beta _{0b}},\;{\beta _{1b}},\;{\lambda _b},\;{\alpha _{0b}},\;{\alpha _{1b}},\;{\alpha _b},\;{\varsigma _b}$ and ${\vartheta _b}$ are given in appendix A. Then, we can prove:

  1. (i) $(\partial p_0^B/\partial k) = ((1 - r)({\beta _{0b}}^{\prime}{\vartheta _b} - {\beta _{0b}}{\vartheta _b}^{\prime})w/2\vartheta _b^2) > 0$ and $(\partial p_1^B/\partial k) = (\partial p_2^B/\partial k) = ((1 - r)({\beta _{1b}}^{\prime}{\vartheta _b} - {\beta _{1b}}{\vartheta _b}^{\prime})w/2\vartheta _b^2) > 0;$

  2. (ii) $(\partial {Q^B}/\partial k) = ((1 - r)({\lambda _b}^{\prime}{\vartheta _b} - {\lambda _b}{\vartheta _b}^{\prime})w/2(2r + 1)\vartheta _b^2) < 0;$

  3. (iii) $(\partial y_0^B/\partial k) = ({r^2}(1 - {r^2})({\alpha _{0b}}^{\prime}{\vartheta _b} - {\alpha _{0b}}{\vartheta _b}^{\prime})w/\vartheta _b^2) > 0$ and $(\partial y_1^B/\partial k) = (\partial y_2^B/\partial k) = ({r^2}(1 - {r^2})({\alpha _{1b}}^{\prime}{\vartheta _b} - {\alpha _{1b}}{\vartheta _b}^{\prime})w/\vartheta _b^2) > ( < )0$ if $k < ( > ){k_{1b}}(r)$ (where ${k_{1b}}(r)$ satisfies $0 < {k_{1b}}(r) < 0.5$ and ${ {({\alpha_{1b}}^{\prime}{\vartheta_b} - {\vartheta_b}^{\prime}{\alpha_{1b}})} |_{k = {k_{1b}}(r)}} = 0$);

  4. (iv) $(\partial ({E^B})/\partial k) = (({\varsigma _b}^{\prime}{\vartheta _b} - {\varsigma _b}{\vartheta _b}^{\prime})w/2(2r + 1)\vartheta _b^2) < 0$.

Proof of proposition 1

  1. (i) We can show that ${\vartheta _b} > 0,\;{r^2}(1 - k)(1 - {r^2}){\Phi _b} > 0$ and ${r^2}(1 - k)(1 - {r^2})[(2{\mkern 1mu} r + 1){k^2} + (3{\mkern 1mu} r + 2)(1 - 2k)]{\psi _b} > 0$ for $0 < k < 0.5$ and $0 < r < 1$. Therefore, $h_0^B > 0$ and $h_1^B = h_2^B > 0$;

  2. (ii) $h_\textrm{0}^B - h_1^B = h_\textrm{0}^B - h_2^B\textrm{ = }({r^2}(1 - k)(1 - {r^2})\{ {\Phi _b} - [(2{\mkern 1mu} r + 1){k^2} + (3{\mkern 1mu} r + 2)(1 - 2k)]{\psi _b}\} w/{\vartheta _b}) > 0$.

Proof of proposition 2

  1. (i) $(\partial h_\textrm{0}^B/\partial k) = ({r^2}(1 - {r^2})\{ [ - {\Phi _b} + (1 - k){\Phi _b}^{\prime}]{\vartheta _b} - (1 - k){\Phi _b}{\vartheta _b}^{\prime}\} w/{\vartheta _b}^2) > 0;$

  2. (ii) $(\partial h_1^B/\partial k) \!=\! (\partial h_2^B/\partial k) \!=\! ({r^2}(1 - {r^2})Lw/{\vartheta _b}^2)$, where $L \!=\! \left( \begin{array}{@{}l@{}} [(2{\mkern 1mu} r + 1)(2 - 3k)k\\ \quad +\, (3{\mkern 1mu} r + 2)( - 3\\ \quad +\, 4k)]{\psi_b}{\vartheta_b}+ (1 \\\quad - \,k)[(2{\mkern 1mu} r + 1){k^2}\\ \quad +\, (3{\mkern 1mu} r + 2)(1 - 2k)]\\ \quad ({\psi_b}^{\prime}{\vartheta_b} + {\psi_b}{\vartheta_b}^{\prime}) \end{array} \right)$. There exists $\bar{k}(r)$ ($\bar{k}(r)$ meets ${ L |_{k = \bar{k}(r)}} = 0$) making $L > ( < )0$ if $0 < k < \bar{k}(r)$ ($\bar{k}(r) < k < 0.5$). Thus, $(\partial h_j^B/\partial k) > ( < )\;0\;(j = 1,2)$ if $0 < k < \bar{k}(r)\;(\bar{k}(r) < k < 0.5)$.

Proof of proposition 3

  1. (i) From (13), we can obtain ${D^B} = ({Z_b}^2d{w^2}/8{(2{\kern 1pt} r + 1)^2}{\vartheta _b}^2){\kern 1pt}$ where ${Z_b}$ is given in appendix A. Then, we obtain $(\partial {D^B}/\partial k) = ({Z_b}({Z_b}^{\prime}{\vartheta _b} - {Z_b}{\vartheta _b}^{\prime})d{w^2}/4{(2{\kern 1pt} r + 1)^2}{\vartheta _b}^3) < 0$;

  2. (ii) From (14), we can obtain $S{W^B} = (({G_b} - {Z_b}^2d){w^2}/8{(2{\kern 1pt} r + 1)^2}{\vartheta _b}^2)$ where ${G_b}$ is given in appendix A. Then, we obtain $(\partial S{W^B}/\partial k) = ([2({Z_b}^2{\vartheta _b}^{\prime} - {Z_b}{Z_b}^{\prime}{\vartheta _b})d - (2{G_b}{\vartheta _b}^{\prime} - {G_b}^{\prime}{\vartheta _b})]{w^2}/8{(2{\kern 1pt} r + 1)^2}{\vartheta _b}^3)$. We can prove that ${\vartheta _b} > 0$, ${Z_b}^2{\vartheta _b}^{\prime} - {Z_b}{Z_b}^{\prime}{\vartheta _b} > 0$ and $2{G_b}{\vartheta _b}^{\prime} - {G_b}^{\prime}{\vartheta _b} > 0$. We set $\bar{d}(r,k) = ((2{G_b}{\vartheta _b}^{\prime} - {G_b}^{\prime}{\vartheta _b})/2({Z_b}^2 {\vartheta _b}^{\prime} - {Z_b}{Z_b}^{\prime}{\vartheta _b}))$ and thus obtain $(\partial S{W^B}/\partial k) < ( > )0$ if $d < ( > )\bar{d}(r,k)$.

Proof of proposition 4

  1. (i) Because ${\vartheta _u} > 0,\;{r^2}(1 - {r^2})(kr + 4 + 6{\kern 1pt} r){\Phi _u} > 0,\;{r^2}(1 - {r^2}){\psi _u} > 0$ and ${r^2}(k + 2)(1 - k)(1 - {r^2}){\rho _u} > 0$ for $0 < k < 0.5$ and $0 < r < 1,\;h_0^U > 0,\;h_1^U > 0$ and $h_2^U > 0$;

  2. (ii) $h_\textrm{0}^U - h_\textrm{2}^U = ({r^2}(1 - {r^2})[(kr + 4 + 6{\kern 1pt} r){\Phi _u} - (k + 2)(1 - k){\rho _u}]w/{\vartheta _u}) > 0$ and $h_\textrm{1}^U - h_\textrm{0}^U = ({r^2}(1 - {r^2})[{\psi _u} - (kr + 4 + 6{\kern 1pt} r){\Phi _u}]w/{\vartheta _u}) > 0$;

  3. (iii) Because $(h_\textrm{1}^U - h_0^U) - (h_0^U - h_2^U) = ({r^2}(1 - {r^2})[{\psi _u} + (k + 2)(1 - k){\rho _u} - 2(kr + 4 + 6{\kern 1pt} r){\Phi _u}]w/{\vartheta _u}) < 0,\;h_\textrm{1}^U - h_0^U < h_0^U - h_2^U$.

Proof of proposition 5

  1. (i) $(\partial h_\textrm{0}^U/\partial k) = ({r^2}(1 - {r^2})[r{\Phi _u}{\vartheta _u} + (kr + 4 + 6{\kern 1pt} r)({\Phi _u}^{\prime}{\vartheta _u} - {\Phi _u}{\vartheta _u}^{\prime})]w/{\vartheta _u}^2) > 0$;

  2. (ii) $(\partial h_\textrm{1}^U/\partial k) = ({r^2}(1 - {r^2})({\psi _u}^{\prime}{\vartheta _u} - {\psi _u}{\vartheta _u}^{\prime})w/{\vartheta _u}^2) > 0$;

  3. (iii) $(\partial h_\textrm{2}^U/\partial k) = ({r^2}(1 - {r^2})[ - (2k + 1){\rho _u}{\vartheta _u} + (k + 2)(1 - k)({\rho _u}^{\prime}{\vartheta _u} - {\rho _u}{\vartheta _u}^{\prime})] w/{\vartheta _u}^2) < 0$.

Proof of proposition 6

  1. (i) $h_0^B - h_0^U = ({r^2}(1 - {r^2})[(1 - k){\Phi _b}{\vartheta _u} - (kr + 4 + 6{\kern 1pt} r){\Phi _u}{\vartheta _b}]w/{\vartheta _b}{\vartheta _u}) > 0$;

  2. (ii) $h_1^B - h_1^U = ({r^2}(1 - {r^2})\{ (1 - k)[(2{\mkern 1mu} r + 1){k^2} + (3{\mkern 1mu} r + 2)(1 - 2k)]{\psi _b}{\vartheta _u} - {\psi _u}{\vartheta _b}\} w/ {\vartheta _b}{\vartheta _u}) < 0$;

  3. (iii) We can obtain $h_2^B - h_2^U = ({r^2}(1 - {r^2})(1 - k)\{ [(2{\mkern 1mu} r + 1){k^2} + (3{\mkern 1mu} r + 2)(1 - 2k)] {\psi _b}{\vartheta _u} - (k + 2){\rho _u}{\vartheta _b}\} w/{\vartheta _b}{\vartheta _u})$. When $\tilde{r} < r < 1\;(\tilde{r} \approx 0.434),\;h_2^B - h_2^U > 0$. In addition, when $0 < r < \tilde{r}$, there exists $\tilde{k}(r )$ ($\tilde{k}(r )$ satisfies $0 < \tilde{k}(r )< 0.5$ and ${ {({h_2^B - h_2^U} )} |_{k = \tilde{k}(r )}} = 0$) making $h_2^B - h_2^U > (\!{\lt})0$ if $k < ( > )\tilde{k}(r )$.

Proof of proposition 7

  1. (i) ${D^B} - {D^U} = (({Z_b}^2{\vartheta _u}^2 - 4Z_u^2{\vartheta _b}^2)d{w^2}/8{(2{\kern 1pt} r + 1)^2}{\vartheta _b}^2{\vartheta _u}^2) < 0$;

  2. (ii) We can obtain $S{W^B} - S{W^U} = ([(4Z_u^2{\vartheta _b}^2 - Z_b^2{\vartheta _u}^2)d - (4{G_u}{\vartheta _b}^2 - {G_b}{\vartheta _u}^2)]{w^2}/ 8{(2{\kern 1pt} r + 1)^2}{\vartheta _b}^2{\vartheta _u}^2)$. We can prove that $4Z_u^2{\vartheta _b}^2 - Z_b^2{\vartheta _u}^2 > 0$ and $4{G_u}{\vartheta _b}^2 - {G_b}{\vartheta _u}^2 > 0$. We set ${\breve {d}} ({r,k} )= ((4{G_u}{\vartheta_b}^2 - {G_b}{\vartheta_u}^2)/(4Z_u^2{\vartheta_b}^2 - Z_b^2{\vartheta_u}^2))$. Obviously, ${\breve {d}} ({r,k} )> 0$. Then, we obtain $S{W^B} - S{W^U} > ( < )0$ if $d > ( < ){\breve {d}} ({r,k} )$.

Footnotes

1 Cross-ownership is the situation in which firms undertake passive investments in rival firms, obtaining a share in the profit but not in the decision-making. For practical examples of cross-ownership in the real world, see Liker and Choi (Reference Liker and Choi2004), Li et al. (Reference Li, Ma and Zeng2015), Liu et al. (Reference Liu, Lin and Qin2018), Bárcena-Ruiz and Sagasta (Reference Bárcena-Ruiz and Sagasta2021), Fanti and Buccella (Reference Fanti and Buccella2021), Cho et al. (Reference Cho, Kim and Lee2022), and Xing et al. (Reference Xing, Wang and Zhou2024), among others.

2 In a managerial delegation contract, firm owners delegate strategic decisions to managers and determine the compensatory managerial incentives. Since the pioneering works of Vickers (Reference Vickers1985), Fershtman (Reference Fershtman1985), Fershtman and Judd (Reference Fershtman and Judd1987) and Sklivas (Reference Sklivas1987), many studies have examined different types of managerial incentives, including sales (Nakamura, Reference Nakamura2015; Fanti et al., Reference Fanti, Gori and Sodini2017; Wang and Wang, Reference Wang and Wang2021), revenue (Colombo, Reference Colombo2022; Heywood et al., Reference Heywood, Wang and Ye2022), market share (Ritz, Reference Ritz2008; Jansen et al., Reference Jansen, van Lier and van Witteloostuijn2009; Heywood and Wang, Reference Heywood and Wang2020), rival profits (van Witteloostuijn et al., Reference van Witteloostuijn, Jansen and van Lier2007; Pal, Reference Pal2015; Xu and Matsumura, Reference Xu and Matsumura2022), consumer surplus (Brand and Grothe, Reference Brand and Grothe2015; Leal et al., Reference Leal, Garcia and Lee2018; Kim et al., Reference Kim, Lee and Matsumura2019; Garcia et al., Reference Garcia, Leal, Lee and Park2024), and environmental activities (Liu et al., Reference Liu, Wang and Lee2015; Hirose et al., Reference Hirose, Lee and Matsumura2017; Xing and Lee, Reference Xing and Lee2023; Xu and Lee, Reference Xu and Lee2023).

4 Specifically, the utility maximization problem with the budget constraint yields the following maximization of consumer net surplus problem: $CS({{q_0},{q_1},{q_2}} )= U({{q_0},{q_1},{q_2}} )- \mathop \sum \limits_{i = 0}^2 {p_i}{q_i}$, where the product's price is exogenously given to the consumers. Using $\frac{{\partial CS({{q_0},{q_1},{q_2}} )}}{{\partial {q_i}}} = \frac{{\partial U({{q_0},{q_1},{q_2}} )}}{{\partial {q_i}}} - {p_i} = 0 ({i = 0,\, 1,\, 2} )$ results in the inverse demand function.

5 Note that due to the separability of the end-of-pipe technology, the results with the sequential choices between ${p_i}$ and ${y_i}$ yield the same results with simultaneous choices.

6 Note that the second-order conditions for the entire analysis are satisfied.

7 All proofs of lemmas and propositions are given in appendix B.

8 Note that to ensure $S{W^B} \ge 0$, d cannot be too high and satisfy $0 < d \le ({G_b}/Z_b^2)$ where ${G_b}$ and ${Z_b}$ are given in appendix A.

9 Using the reaction functions in (9) and (10), we obtain ${h_0} = R({{h_1},{h_2}} )= {f_0}({r,k} )({{h_1} + {h_2}} )+ {g_0}({r,k} )$ and ${h_1} + {h_2} = R({{h_0}} )= {f_{\textrm{12}}}({r,k} ){h_0} + {g_{\textrm{12}}}({r,k} )$ at the symmeric equilibrium. Then, we can prove: (i) ${f_0} > 0; {g_0} > 0;\,\frac{{\partial {f_0}}}{{\partial k}} > 0;$ and $\frac{{\partial {g_0}}}{{\partial k}} > 0$; (ii) ${f_{12}} > 0;\,{g_{\textrm{12}}} > 0$. Additionally, there exists $\mathord{\buildrel{\lower3pt\hbox{$\scriptscriptstyle\leftrightarrow$}} \over k} (r )(0 < \mathord{\buildrel{\lower3pt\hbox{$\scriptscriptstyle\leftrightarrow$}} \over k} (r )< 0.5)$ making $\frac{{\partial {f_{\textrm{12}}}}}{{\partial k}} > ( < )0$ and $\frac{{\partial {g_{\textrm{12}}}}}{{\partial k}} > ( < )0$ if $k < ( > )\mathord{\buildrel{\lower3pt\hbox{$\scriptscriptstyle\leftrightarrow$}} \over k} (r )$.

10 The detailed analysis and main findings under unilateral cross ownership are provided in the online appendix.

11 We find that $\tilde{k}(r )$ satisfies $0 < \tilde{k}(r )< 0.5$ and ${ {({h_2^B - h_2^U} )} |_{k = \tilde{k}(r )}} = 0$.

References

Anton, M, Ederer, F, Gine, M and Schmalz, MC (2021) Innovation: the bright side of common ownership? Available at https://ssrn.com/abstract=3099578Google Scholar
Bárcena-Ruiz, JC and Sagasta, A (2021) Environmental policies with consumer-friendly firms and cross-ownership. Economic Modelling 103, 105612.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bayona, A and López, AL (2018) Silent financial interests and product innovation. Economics Letters 170, 109112.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Brand, B and Grothe, M (2015) Social responsibility in a bilateral monopoly. Journal of Economics 115, 275289.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Buccella, D, Fanti, L and Gori, L (2021) To abate, or not to abate? A strategic approach on green production in Cournot and Bertrand duopolies. Energy Economics 96, 105164.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Buccella, D, Fanti, L and Gori, L (2022) ‘Green’ managerial delegation theory. Environment and Development Economics 27, 223249.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Buccella, D, Fanti, L and Gori, L (2023) Environmental delegation versus sales delegation: a game-theoretic analysis. Environment and Development Economics 28, 469485.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Chen, L, Matsumura, T and Zeng, CH (2023) Welfare consequence of common ownership in a vertically related market. Journal of Industrial Economics, https://doi.org/10.1111/joie.12380CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cho, S and Lee, SH (2024) Cross ownership and environmental corporate social responsibility with environmental cooperation. Managerial and Decision Economics 45, 446468.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cho, S, Kim, D and Lee, SH (2022) Free licensing strategy and ex post privatization policy with passive ownership. Economic Modelling 106, 105676.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Colombo, S (2022) Prisoner dilemma in a vertical duopoly with managerial delegation. Managerial and Decision Economics 43, 14761481.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fanti, L and Buccella, D (2021) Strategic trade policy with interlocking cross-ownership. Journal of Economics 134, 147174.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fanti, L, Gori, L and Sodini, M (2017) Managerial delegation theory revisited. Managerial and Decision Economics 38, 490512.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fershtman, C (1985) Managerial incentives as a strategic variable in duopolistic environment. International Journal of Industrial Organization 3, 245253.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fershtman, C and Judd, KL (1987) Equilibrium incentives in oligopoly. American Economic Review 77, 927940.Google Scholar
Garcia, A, Leal, M, Lee, SH and Park, CH (2024) Merger incentive and strategic CSR by a multiproduct corporation. International Review of Economics and Finance, https://doi.org/10.1016/j.iref.2024.01.010CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Heywood, JS and Wang, Z (2020) Delivered pricing and endogenous delegation of contract type. Australian Economic Papers 59, 232249.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Heywood, JS, Wang, Z and Ye, G (2022) Strategic delegation in an international mixed oligopoly. Managerial and Decision Economics 43, 18881898.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hirose, K and Matsumura, T (2022) Common ownership and environmental corporate social responsibility. Energy Economics 114, 106269.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hirose, K, Lee, SH and Matsumura, T (2017) Environmental corporate social responsibility: a note on the first-mover advantage under price competition. Economics Bulletin 37, 214221.Google Scholar
Hirose, K, Lee, SH and Matsumura, T (2020) Noncooperative and cooperative environmental corporate social responsibility. Journal of Institutional and Theoretical Economics 176, 549571.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Jansen, T, van Lier, A and van Witteloostuijn, A (2009) On the impact of managerial bonus systems on firm profit and market competition: the cases of pure profit, sales, market share and relative profits compared. Managerial and Decision Economics 30, 141153.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kim, SL, Lee, SH and Matsumura, T (2019) Corporate social responsibility and privatization policy in a mixed oligopoly. Journal of Economics 128, 6789.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Leal, M, Garcia, A and Lee, SH (2018) The timing of environmental tax policy with a consumer-friendly firm. Hitotsubashi Journal of Economics 59, 2543.Google Scholar
Lee, SH and Park, CH (2019) Eco-firms and the sequential adoption of environmental corporate social responsibility in the managerial delegation. The B.E. Journal of Theoretical Economics 19, 20170043.Google Scholar
Lee, SH and Park, CH (2021) Corporate environmentalism in a managerial delegation and abatement subsidy policy. Asia-Pacific Journal of Accounting & Economics 28, 546561.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Li, S, Ma, H and Zeng, C (2015) Passive cross holdings as a strategic entry deterrence. Economics Letters 134, 3740.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Liker, JK and Choi, TY (2004) Building deep supplier relationships. Harvard Business Review 82, 104113.Google Scholar
Liu, CC, Wang, LFS and Lee, SH (2015) Strategic environmental corporate social responsibility in a differentiated duopoly market. Economics Letters 129, 108111.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Liu, L, Lin, J and Qin, C (2018) Cross-holdings with asymmetric information and technologies. Economics Letters 166, 8385.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
López, A and Vives, X (2019) Overlapping ownership. R&D spillovers and antitrust policy. Journal of Political Economy 127, 23942436.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Nakamura, Y (2015) Price versus quantity in a mixed duopoly: the case of relative profit maximization. Economic Modelling 44, 3743.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ning, HK, Wang, LFS and Sun, J (2022) Cross ownership, “green” delegation and emission taxation. Available at https://ssrn.com/abstract=4210300Google Scholar
Pal, R (2015) Cournot vs. Bertrand under relative performance delegation: implications of positive and negative network externalities. Mathematical Social Sciences 75, 94101.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Park, CH and Lee, SH (2023 a) Environmental corporate social responsibility under price competition and the second-mover advantage: an endogenous timing approach. International Journal of Economic Theory 19, 817829.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Park, CH and Lee, SH (2023 b) Emission taxation, green R&D, and managerial delegation contracts with environmental and sales incentives. Managerial and Decision Economics 44, 23662377.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Poyago-Theotoky, J and Yong, SK (2019) Managerial delegation contracts, “green” R&D and emissions taxation. The B.E. Journal of Theoretical Economics 19, 20170128.Google Scholar
Reynolds, R and Snapp, B (1986) The competitive effects of partial equity interests and joint ventures. International Journal of Industrial Organization 4, 141153.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ritz, RA (2008) Strategic incentives for market share. International Journal of Industrial Organization 26, 586597.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ritz, RA (2022) Linking executive compensation to climate performance. California Management Review 64, 124140.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sato, S and Matsumura, T (2020) Free entry under common ownership. Economics Letters 195, 109489.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Singh, N and Vives, X (1984) Price and quantity competition in a differentiated duopoly. Rand Journal of Economics 15, 546554.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sklivas, S (1987) The strategic choice of managerial incentives. RAND Journal of Economics 18, 452458.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
van Witteloostuijn, A, Jansen, T and van Lier, A (2007) Bargaining over managerial contracts in delegation games: managerial power, contract disclosure and cartel behavior. Managerial and Decision Economics 28, 897904.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Vickers, J (1985) Delegation and the theory of the firm. Economic Journal Supplement 95, 138147.Google Scholar
Wang, X and Wang, LFS (2021) Vertical product differentiation, managerial delegation and social welfare in a vertically-related market. Mathematical Social Sciences 113, 149159.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Xing, MQ and Lee, SH (2023) Non-cooperative and cooperative environmental R&D under environmental corporate social responsibility with green managerial coordination. Managerial and Decision Economics 44, 26842696.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Xing, MQ, Wang, LFS and Zhou, C (2024) Cross-ownership on R&D and social welfare in mixed oligopoly. Economics of Innovation and New Technology 33, 206217.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Xu, LL and Lee, SH (2022) Non-cooperative and cooperative environmental corporate social responsibility with emission taxes. Managerial and Decision Economics 43, 28462862.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Xu, LL and Lee, SH (2023) Cournot-Bertrand comparisons under double managerial delegation contracts with sales and environmental incentives. Managerial and Decision Economics 44, 34093421.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Xu, LL and Matsumura, T (2022) Welfare-reducing price competition under relative performance delegation with convex costs. Economic Modelling 112, 105871.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Xu, LL, Chen, YY and Lee, SH (2022) Emission tax and strategic environmental corporate social responsibility in a Cournot-Bertrand comparison. Energy Economics 107, 105846.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Figure 0

Figure 1. The sign of $(\partial h_j^B/\partial k)\,(j = 1,\, 2)$ under bilateral cross shareholding.

Figure 1

Figure 2. The sign of $(\partial S{W^B}/\partial k)$ under bilateral cross-shareholding.

Figure 2

Figure 3. The sign of $h_2^B - h_2^U$.

Figure 3

Figure 4. The sign of $S{W^B} - S{W^U}$.

Supplementary material: File

Xing and Lee supplementary material

Xing and Lee supplementary material
Download Xing and Lee supplementary material(File)
File 236.3 KB