Hostname: page-component-586b7cd67f-tf8b9 Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-11-22T00:28:15.489Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Commentary on Perspective Article: ‘Institutional Logics: Motivating Action and Overcoming Resistance to Change’ – Heather A. Haveman, David Joseph-Goteiner, and Danyang Li

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  05 January 2024

Mia Raynard*
Affiliation:
University of British Columbia, Vancouver, BC, Canada
Royston Greenwood
Affiliation:
University of Alberta, Edmonton, AB, Canada
*
Corresponding author: Mia Raynard ([email protected])
Rights & Permissions [Opens in a new window]

Abstract

Haveman, Joseph-Goteiner, and Li's (2023) perspective article contributes important insights into China's transition away from central planning and redistribution toward greater market coordination of economic exchange. In our commentary on their insightful article, we build on and extend their arguments in three main ways. First, we discuss how future studies might extend the authors’ work by leveraging the ‘messiness’ of institutional change to explore the cross-level dynamics involved in transforming institutional logics. Second, we build on the authors’ call for more historically grounded, contextualized research on institutional logics to argue that the conditions surrounding logic emergence have important implications for inter-logic dynamics and organizational responses. Third, we build on the authors’ suggestions for future research to underscore the broader consequences of institutional logics and their potential to perpetuate or exacerbate social inequalities and other societal challenges.

摘要

摘要

Haveman等学者 (2023) 的文章对中国从计划经济向市场经济转型背后遵循的制度逻辑提出了重要的见解。本文主要从三个方面评论并扩展他们的论点。首先,我们认为未来的研究可以关注制度变革中所蕴含混乱性, 来探索制度逻辑转型中所涉及的跨层级的动态表现。第二,我们响应作者的呼吁,即对制度逻辑研究要更多基于历史和语境,同时指出制度逻辑出现的条件对逻辑间的动态表现和组织反应具有重要影响。第三,我们强调制度逻辑可能产生的更广泛影响,及其延续或加剧社会不平等和其他社会挑战的可能性。

Type
Dialogue, Debate, and Discussion
Creative Commons
Creative Common License - CCCreative Common License - BY
This is an Open Access article, distributed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution licence (http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/), which permits unrestricted re-use, distribution and reproduction, provided the original article is properly cited.
Copyright
Copyright © The Author(s), 2024. Published by Cambridge University Press on behalf of International Association for Chinese Management Research

The perspective article by Haveman, Joseph-Goteiner, and Li (Reference Haveman, Joseph-Goteiner and Li2023) contributes important insights into one of the most significant social transformations in recent history: China's shift away from central planning and redistribution toward greater market coordination of economic exchange (Keister & Zhang, Reference Keister and Zhang2009; Nee, Reference Nee1992; Peng, Reference Peng2003). The article begins by surveying and synthesizing the literature on institutional logics, as studied in organizations in Western capitalist economies. It then contrasts and extends insights from this work to the Chinese context, detailing how China's dramatic transition triggered a concomitant shift in the institutional logics that guide organizational decision-making, activities, structures, and goals. Taking stock of empirical research on institutional logics in Chinese firms, the authors then outline how the partial supplanting of the old Maoist-era state logic by a new market logic has differentially manifested in Chinese firms with different governance and ownership forms. The authors conclude by discussing how the market logic in China differs from the one that prevails in Western capitalist economies and call for further research that better appreciates the distinctiveness of the Chinese context and how the complexity of its changing socio-economic landscape has spawned variations in the institutional logics guiding business firms.

In this commentary, we aim to further interrogate and expand on the arguments developed in Haveman et al.'s (Reference Haveman, Joseph-Goteiner and Li2023) perspective article in three main ways. First, we seek to integrate insights from research on institutional change to the authors’ illuminating discussion of shifts and changes in institutional logics. Specifically, we pick up from the authors’ recognition that their brief description of China's historical trajectory necessarily ‘glossed over many changes’; and highlight how future studies might leverage the ‘messiness’ of institutional change to explore the cross-level dynamics involved in transforming institutional logics. Second, we echo Haveman et al.'s (Reference Haveman, Joseph-Goteiner and Li2023) call for more historically grounded, contextualized research on institutional logics, and argue that the conditions surrounding logic emergence may have important implications for inter-logic dynamics and how organizations might experience and prioritize logics. Third, we build on the authors’ suggestions for future research to spotlight the importance of broader consequences of institutional logics – particularly, their potential to perpetuate or exacerbate social inequalities and other societal challenges.

Institutional Change and the Transformation of Societal-Level Institutional Logics

Institutional theory scholars have long recognized the complexity and messiness of institutional change – be it change that unfolds within and across levels of analysis, the different coalitions of change agents that form, evolve, and dissolve over time, or change efforts that succeed or fail depending on a range of factors, places, and historical conditions (Dacin, Goodstein, & Scott, Reference Dacin, Goodstein and Scott2002; Mahoney & Thelen, Reference Mahoney and Thelen2010; North, Reference North and Sjostrand1993; Seo & Creed, Reference Seo and Creed2002). Research examining institutional change in the Chinese context has significantly expanded our understanding and perspective of how societal institutions and logics evolve over time (Child, Reference Child2009; Keister & Zhang, Reference Keister and Zhang2009; Marquis & Qiao, Reference Marquis and Qiao2020; Peng, Reference Peng2003). This is, in large part, due to the unique and unrivaled power and authority of the Chinese Communist Party (CCP) (He & Warren, Reference He and Warren2011; Stern & Hassid, Reference Stern and Hassid2012). The presence of this powerful central actor could reasonably be assumed to simplify or smooth the process of effecting institutional change. Such an assumption seems plausible when comparing China's well-controlled and incremental process of economic transition – which prioritized political and social stability – with the revolutionary ‘shock therapy’ approach undertaken by countries in Eastern Europe and the former Soviet Union (Nee, Reference Nee1992; Tan, Reference Tan2005). While, comparatively, China's economic transition was smooth; in practice, it involved complex entwined social and political processes as well as disparate groups of actors that operated at different levels, with different interests and agendas (Lieberthal, Reference Lieberthal2004; Padgett & Powell, Reference Padgett, Powell, Padgett and Powell2012). As Haveman et al. (Reference Haveman, Joseph-Goteiner and Li2023) and others point out, the transition – and the concomitant transformation of institutional logics – involved a long series of regulatory changes and controlled experiments that started in the late 1970s and continues to the present day (Clarke, Murrell, & Whiting, Reference Clarke, Murrell, Whiting, Brandt and Rawski2008; Keister & Zhang, Reference Keister and Zhang2009; Xu, Reference Xu2011).

What is especially noteworthy is that the complexity (and orchestrated messiness) of China's economic transformation departs from the common ‘pathways’ of institutional change documented in prior organizational research (Micelotta, Lounsbury, & Greenwood, Reference Micelotta, Lounsbury and Greenwood2017). Looking across the literature on institutional change, one can see that shifts in dominant institutional logics have been shown to follow from exogenous changes (Berman, Reference Berman2012; Sine & David, Reference Sine and David2003), institutional entrepreneurship (Hardy & Maguire, Reference Hardy, Maguire, Greenwood, Oliver, Lawrence and Meyer2017; Misangyi, Weaver, & Elms, Reference Misangyi, Weaver and Elms2008), and gradual accumulation of new practices (Smets, Aristidou, & Whittington, Reference Smets, Aristidou, Whittington, Greenwood, Oliver, Lawrence and Meyer2017). Changing societal and political conditions, for example, can create opportunities for ‘challengers’ to mobilize and potentially upend longstanding institutional arrangements that privilege ‘incumbents’ (Fligstein & McAdam, Reference Fligstein and McAdam2012; Levy & Scully, Reference Levy and Scully2007; Maguire & Hardy, Reference Maguire and Hardy2009). Similarly, institutional entrepreneurs have been shown to strategically negotiate the constraints and affordances of the institutional context to effect change at various levels (Battilana, Leca, & Boxenbaum, Reference Battilana, Leca and Boxenbaum2009; Garud, Hardy, & Maguire, Reference Garud, Hardy and Maguire2007). In other studies, endogenous sources of change are foregrounded: with small changes and improvisations emerging and gradually accumulating into macro-social change (Seo & Creed, Reference Seo and Creed2002; Smets et al., Reference Smets, Aristidou, Whittington, Greenwood, Oliver, Lawrence and Meyer2017). While China's transition bears some traces of the above triggers, it also differs significantly because of the role played by the Chinese state and CCP. Exogenous change and influences from capitalist economic systems, for example, were made possible in large part by the government's ‘opening’ of China's door to the rest of East Asia and the West (Boisot & Child, Reference Boisot and Child1996; Nee, Reference Nee1992; Peng & Heath, Reference Peng and Heath1996; Vogel, Reference Vogel2011). Likewise, institutional entrepreneurship and the accumulation of practices in the Chinese context took the form of top-down orchestration and controlled experimentation, as opposed to bubbling up from the bottom (e.g., Garud et al., Reference Garud, Hardy and Maguire2007; Maguire, Hardy, & Lawrence, Reference Maguire, Hardy and Lawrence2004).

The profound role played by the Chinese state and Communist Party underscores the importance of appreciating how institutional infrastructures differentially shape the way that institutional logics emerge, evolve, and change (Hinings, Logue, & Zietsma, Reference Hinings, Logue, Zietsma, Greenwood, Oliver, Lawrence and Meyer2017; Raynard, Kodeih, & Greenwood, Reference Raynard, Kodeih and Greenwood2021; Zietsma, Groenewegen, Logue, & Hinings, Reference Zietsma, Groenewegen, Logue and Hinings2017). Unlike the overt contentious dynamics commonly documented between incumbents and challengers, the partial supplanting of the old state logic in China involved ‘compromises among top CCP leaders’ and calculated experimentation (Xu, Reference Xu2011): beginning in specific sectors of the economy (e.g., peripheral sectors like peasant farming, handicrafts, repair work, and food stalls) and selected geographic areas (e.g., rural and township villages and Special Economic Zones) before being rolled out across other sectors and regions nationwide (Fan, Reference Fan1995). This calculated and coordinated approach may help explain why China's transition and the profound transformation of societal-level institutional logics was less disruptive than that which occurred in Eastern Europe and the former Soviet Union (Tan, Reference Tan2007; Xu, Reference Xu2011).

In contexts where a powerful government actor has the legitimacy and authority to define and channel institutional change processes, the institutional logics guiding decision-making and behavior are likely to be especially ‘sticky’ (North, Reference North and Sjostrand1993), persisting ‘even in the face of powerful forces propelling change’ (Haveman et al., Reference Haveman, Joseph-Goteiner and Li2023). This situation extends beyond authoritarian regimes to include fields and industries where a central actor or organization can dictate or define how logics should be prioritized and how they manifest in structures, practices, and governance mechanisms (Greenwood, Raynard, Kodeih, Micelotta, & Lounsbury, Reference Greenwood, Raynard, Kodeih, Micelotta and Lounsbury2011; Raynard, Reference Raynard2016). Such actors include ‘institutional guardians’ (DeJordy, Reference DeJordy2010) like the Catholic Church or professional associations that have the vested authority to influence how logics emerge, take form, and manifest. The presence of uniquely powerful actors has important theoretical and methodological implications. One such implication is that the complexity and messiness of institutional change may be less overt than portrayed in much of the literature (e.g., Fligstein & McAdam, Reference Fligstein and McAdam2012; Maguire & Hardy, Reference Maguire and Hardy2009). An example from China's transition can be seen in the decade-long negotiation and drafting of the Property Law, which in 2007 granted equal protection to public and private properties (Chen, Reference Chen2007; Zhang, Reference Zhang2008). The law was significant because private ownership had long been held up as the ‘essence of capitalism’ and state ownership ‘the mainstay of socialism’ (Dodds, Reference Dodds1996: 739). Despite the controversial nature of the law, conflict and tensions largely played out, away from the public eye – suggesting that data collection and access might present challenges for ‘outsiders’.

Another important implication is that the ‘tone of reform’ may be ‘constructively framed in alignment with the interests of maintaining the system’ (Raynard et al., Reference Raynard, Kodeih and Greenwood2021: 27). This suggests a different dynamic among would-be change agents than the competitive one typically emphasized in prior research. The Chinese government, as Haveman et al. (Reference Haveman, Joseph-Goteiner and Li2023) note, is not monolithic; but, instead, ‘hierarchical, with multiple administrative levels that have different powers, with influence flowing from the top to the bottom and from the bottom to the top’. Despite these actors operating at different levels, and having potentially different interests and agendas, there is a ‘thematic pull’ in the direction of incremental reform as opposed to revolutionary change (Raynard et al., Reference Raynard, Kodeih and Greenwood2021; Smets et al., Reference Smets, Aristidou, Whittington, Greenwood, Oliver, Lawrence and Meyer2017). Studying the dynamics and process underpinning the transformation of China's institutional logics, therefore, requires an appreciation of the subtle interplay of mechanisms across levels of analysis – and, importantly, situating these mechanisms in ways that account for temporal and regional variations (Fan, Reference Fan1995; Haveman et al., Reference Haveman, Joseph-Goteiner and Li2023; Raynard, Lounsbury, & Greenwood, Reference Raynard, Lounsbury and Greenwood2013; Xu, Reference Xu2011; You, Zhou, Zhou, Jia, & Wang, Reference You, Zhou, Zhou, Jia and Wang2021).

Logic Emergence and Change and the Implications for Organizations

Haveman et al.'s (Reference Haveman, Joseph-Goteiner and Li2023) call for more ‘historically sensitive’ research on institutional logics is an important one. In this section, we echo and extend this call by discussing how heeding it could provide a more nuanced understanding of the dynamics between co-existing logics, and their organizational implications. Our starting point is Haveman et al.'s (Reference Haveman, Joseph-Goteiner and Li2023) argument that: ‘the market logic, as it is manifested in China, has come to incorporate one key element of the state logic: it celebrates the central role that the state and the Communist Party continue to play in economic life’. Implicit in this argument is that there is an inherent degree of compatibility between the market and state logics in China – to the extent that they may be inextricably entwined and relatively complementary in how they guide and shape organizations. The possibility of this ‘built in’ complementarity may not have been surfaced without appreciating the historical and contextual specificities of China's transition and its changing socio-economic and political landscape (Child, Reference Child1996; Greve & Zhang, Reference Greve and Zhang2017; Tracey & Phillips, Reference Tracey and Phillips2011).

What the above suggests is that how, when, and under what circumstances an institutional logic emerges may have important implications for inter-logic dynamics and co-existence (Ocasio, Mauskapf, & Steele, Reference Ocasio, Mauskapf and Steele2016; Raynard et al., Reference Raynard, Lounsbury and Greenwood2013). As highlighted by Haveman et al. (Reference Haveman, Joseph-Goteiner and Li2023), organizational scholars have shown that the way multiple logics interact fundamentally shapes an organization's experience of ‘institutional complexity’ and how it subsequently copes with competing institutional demands (Greenwood et al., Reference Greenwood, Raynard, Kodeih, Micelotta and Lounsbury2011; see also Battilana & Lee, Reference Battilana and Lee2014). To illustrate, in contexts where the market and state logics are not compatible – yet are central to organizational functioning – organizational members are likely to experience deep-seated and perpetual tensions (Besharov & Smith, Reference Besharov and Smith2014; Pache & Santos, Reference Pache and Santos2010). In response, the organization might adopt decoupling strategies or structural compartmentalization in order to attend to incompatible prescriptions (Binder, Reference Binder2007; Raynard, Reference Raynard2016). In contrast, in contexts like China where there is some inherent degree of compatibility between the market and state logics, the experience of institutional complexity may be less ‘intense’ or problematic. In this case, organizations may adopt blended hybrid structures to accommodate different demands or even harness the potential synergies in the enactment of logic prescriptions (Chen, Reference Chen2020; Greve & Zhang, Reference Greve and Zhang2017; Liu, Zhang, & Jing, Reference Liu, Zhang and Jing2016; Nee, Reference Nee1992). The underlying implication is that how institutional logics emerge, cohere, and endure may fundamentally influence their dynamics and the ways in which organizations might manage institutional complexity (Ocasio et al., Reference Ocasio, Mauskapf and Steele2016; Zhang & Luo, Reference Zhang and Luo2013).

From a methodological standpoint, the entwining and co-evolution of institutional logics implicates potential challenges of teasing apart ‘intra’ logic change and ‘inter’ logic change. In the Chinese context, this challenge includes distinguishing how and to what extent the state logic has changed, and/or whether change lies in the rise of a new logic and the concomitant shift in the relationship between other logics. It is by taking ‘history seriously’ that organizational scholars can gain a fuller understanding of institutional logics and the interinstitutional system that guide organizational life (Clemente, Durand, & Roulet, Reference Clemente, Durand and Roulet2017; Kipping & Üsdiken, Reference Kipping and Üsdiken2014; Suddaby, Foster, & Mills, Reference Suddaby, Foster, Mills, Bucheli and Wadhwani2014).

Institutional Logics and Societal Challenges

Haveman et al. (Reference Haveman, Joseph-Goteiner and Li2023) highlight some important areas for future research including the need to examine other societal-level institutional logics such as religion and family. This is an important suggestion that could help deepen theorizations of interinstitutional systems and their implications (Hinings & Raynard, Reference Hinings, Raynard, Phillips, Lounsbury and Tracey2014; Ocasio et al., Reference Ocasio, Mauskapf and Steele2016). Raising the importance of other logics, prompts our final comment, which aims to provoke discussion on the potential for logics to perpetuate and exacerbate societal problems. Put simply, institutional logics can have extreme implications. The material manifestations associated with the market logic in some Western capitalist countries, for example, have led to major social inequalities – especially in the US (Amis, Brickson, Haack, & Hernandez, Reference Amis, Brickson, Haack and Hernandez2021; Amis, Mair, & Munir, Reference Amis, Mair and Munir2020; Burgin, Reference Burgin2012).

In effect, allowing a particular logic to dominate, rather than being complemented and balanced by other logics (such as a community care logic) can allow that logic to become an extreme version – e.g., allowing shareholder value to be prioritized over the interests of all other stakeholders can lead to a widening of social disparities. Arrangements and practices that focus narrowly on shareholder wealth can create incentives for corporate ‘irresponsible’ behavior and ‘wrongdoing’ (Burgis, Reference Burgis2020; Lewis, Reference Lewis2014; Mayer, Reference Mayer2017; Palmer, Reference Palmer2012). In a similar way, the religious logic taken to the extreme can lead to radicalization and create justifications for divisive behavior and violent extremism (Iannaccone & Berman, Reference Iannaccone and Berman2006). If a particular logic is taken to extreme lengths, a divisive populist unrest could surge and lead to an erosive disrespect for the rule of law, the institutions of justice – and, perhaps, the associated institutions of governance and social order. We need to give greater attention to how logics are (or could be) balanced and thus avoid such extreme implications – for example, countries such as Sweden have evolved a fairly balanced relationship between the market and social welfare logics. China is an interesting case as it has moved to introduce the market logic while preserving the importance of the state logic in guiding business firms. Understanding ‘grand challenges’ has become one of the central concerns of the organization and management community: our point is that understanding the balance between key societal logics is, we propose, one such grand challenge.

Mia Raynard () is an Assistant Professor at the University of British Columbia. Her research interests lie at the intersection of organization theory and societal challenges. Her current work aims to deepen understanding of processes of profound change by exploring contexts such as emerging economies, nascent occupations, and sustainability transformations.

Royston Greenwood () is a Professor Emeritus at the University of Alberta, and a Professorial Fellow at the University of Edinburgh Business School. He received his PhD from the University of Birmingham in the UK. He is a Fellow of the Academy of Management and an Honorary Member of the European Group for Organization Studies (EGOS). His current work focuses upon the application of institutional analysis to social issues – such as corruption and wrongdoing – in professional contexts.

References

Amis, J. M., Mair, J., & Munir, K. A. 2020. The organizational reproduction of inequality. Academy of Management Annals, 14(1): 195230.Google Scholar
Amis, J. M., Brickson, S., Haack, P., & Hernandez, M. 2021. Taking inequality seriously. Academy of Management Review, 46(3): 431439.Google Scholar
Battilana, J., & Lee, M. 2014. Advancing research on hybrid organizing: Insights from the study of social enterprises. Academy of Management Annals, 8(1): 397441.Google Scholar
Battilana, J., Leca, B., & Boxenbaum, E. 2009. How actors change institutions: Towards a theory of institutional entrepreneurship. Academy of Management Annals, 3(1): 65107.Google Scholar
Berman, E. P. 2012. Explaining the move toward the market in US academic science: How institutional logics can change without institutional entrepreneurs. Theory and Society, 41(3): 261299.Google Scholar
Besharov, M. L., & Smith, W. K. 2014. Multiple institutional logics in organizations: Explaining their varied nature and implications. Academy of Management Review, 39(3): 364381.Google Scholar
Binder, A. 2007. For love and money: Organizations’ creative responses to multiple environmental logics. Theory and Society, 36(6): 547571.Google Scholar
Boisot, M., & Child, J. 1996. From fiefs to clans and network capitalism: Explaining China's emerging economic order. Administrative Science Quarterly, 41(4): 600628.Google Scholar
Burgin, A. 2012. The great persuasion: Reinventing free markets since the depression. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Burgis, T. 2020. Kleptopia: How dirty money is conquering the world. London: William Collins.Google Scholar
Chen, W. 2007. Does the colour of the cat matter? The red hat strategy in China's private enterprises. Management and Organization Review, 3(1): 5580.Google Scholar
Chen, X. 2020. The state-owned enterprise as an identity: The influence of institutional logics on guanxi behavior. Management and Organization Review, 16(3): 543568.Google Scholar
Child, J. 1996. Management in China during the age of reform. Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Child, J. 2009. Context, comparison, and methodology in Chinese management research. Management and Organization Review, 5(1): 5773.Google Scholar
Clarke, D., Murrell, P., & Whiting, S. 2008. The role of law in China's economic development. In Brandt, L. & Rawski, T. G. (Eds.), China's great economic transformation: 375428. Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Clemente, M., Durand, R., & Roulet, T. 2017. The recursive nature of institutional change: An Annales School perspective. Journal of Management Inquiry, 26(1): 1731.Google Scholar
Dacin, M. T., Goodstein, J., & Scott, W. R. 2002. Institutional theory and institutional change: Introduction to the special research forum. Academy of Management Journal, 45(1): 4556.Google Scholar
DeJordy, R. 2010. Institutional guardianship: The role of agency in preserving threatened institutional arrangements. Boston, MA: Boston College.Google Scholar
Dodds, R. F. Jr. 1996. State enterprise reform in China: Managing the transition to a market economy. Law and Policy in International Business, 27(3): 695774.Google Scholar
Fan, C. C. 1995. Of belts and ladders: state policy and uneven regional development in post-Mao China. Annals of the Association of American Geographers, 85(3): 421449.Google Scholar
Fligstein, N., & McAdam, D. 2012. A theory of fields. New York: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Garud, R., Hardy, C., & Maguire, S. 2007. Institutional entrepreneurship as embedded agency: An introduction to the special issue. Organization Studies, 28(7): 957969.Google Scholar
Greenwood, R., Raynard, M., Kodeih, F., Micelotta, E. R., & Lounsbury, M. 2011. Institutional complexity and organizational responses. Academy of Management Annals, 5: 317371.Google Scholar
Greve, H. R., & Zhang, C. M. 2017. Institutional logics and power sources: Merger and acquisition decisions. Academy of Management Journal, 60(2): 671694.Google Scholar
Hardy, C., & Maguire, S. 2017. Institutional entrepreneurship and change in fields. In Greenwood, R., Oliver, C., Lawrence, T. B., & Meyer, R. (Eds.), The SAGE handbook of organizational institutionalism: 261280. London, UK: SAGE.Google Scholar
Haveman, H. A., Joseph-Goteiner, D., & Li, D. 2023. Institutional logics: Motivating action and overcoming resistance to change. Management and Organization Review, 19(6). https://doi.org/10.1017/mor.2023.22Google Scholar
He, B., & Warren, M. E. 2011. Authoritarian deliberation: The deliberative turn in Chinese political development. Perspectives on Politics, 9(2): 269289.Google Scholar
Hinings, C. R., & Raynard, M. 2014. One more time: Church, sect, denomination, ecclesia and other forms of religious organization. In Phillips, N., Lounsbury, M., & Tracey, P. (Eds.), Research in the sociology of organizations: Religion and organizational theory, vol. 41: 159186. Bingley, UK: Emerald Group Publishing Limited.Google Scholar
Hinings, C. R., Logue, D., & Zietsma, C. 2017. Fields, institutional infrastructure and governance. In Greenwood, R., Oliver, C., Lawrence, T. B., & Meyer, R. (Eds.), The SAGE handbook of organizational institutionalism, 2nd ed.: 163189. Thousand Oaks, CA: SAGE Publications Inc.Google Scholar
Iannaccone, L. R., & Berman, E. 2006. Religious extremism: The good, the bad, and the deadly. Public Choice, 128(1): 109129.Google Scholar
Keister, L. A., & Zhang, Y. 2009. Organizations and management in China. Academy of Management Annals, 3(1): 377420.Google Scholar
Kipping, M., & Üsdiken, B. 2014. History in organization and management theory: More than meets the eye. Academy of Management Annals, 8(1): 535588.Google Scholar
Levy, D., & Scully, M. 2007. The institutional entrepreneur as modern prince: The strategic face of power in contested fields. Organization Studies, 28(7): 971991.Google Scholar
Lewis, M. 2014. Flash boys: A wall street revolt. New York: WW Norton & Company.Google Scholar
Lieberthal, K. 2004. Governing China: From revolution through reform: 2nd edn. New York: W.W. Norton.Google Scholar
Liu, Y., Zhang, C., & Jing, R. 2016. Coping with multiple institutional logics: Temporal process of institutional work during the emergence of the one foundation in China. Management and Organization Review, 12(2): 387416.Google Scholar
Maguire, S., & Hardy, C. 2009. Discourse and deinstitutionalization: The decline of DDT. Academy of Management Journal, 52(1): 148178.Google Scholar
Maguire, S., Hardy, C., & Lawrence, T. B. 2004. Institutional entrepreneurship in emerging fields: HIV/AIDA treatment advocacy in Canada. Academy of Management Journal, 47(5): 657679.Google Scholar
Mahoney, J., & Thelen, K. 2010. Explaining institutional change: Ambiguity, agency, and power. New York: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Marquis, C., & Qiao, K. 2020. Waking from Mao's dream: Communist ideological imprinting and the internationalization of entrepreneurial ventures in China. Administrative Science Quarterly, 65(3): 795830.Google Scholar
Mayer, J. 2017. Dark money: The hidden history of the billionaires behind the rise of the radical right. New York: Doubleday.Google Scholar
Micelotta, E., Lounsbury, M., & Greenwood, R. 2017. Pathways of institutional change: An integrative review and research agenda. Journal of Management, 43(6): 18851910.Google Scholar
Misangyi, V. F., Weaver, G. R., & Elms, H. 2008. Ending corruption: The interplay among institutional logics, resources, and institutional entrepreneurs. Academy of Management Review, 33(3): 750770.Google Scholar
Nee, V. 1992. Organizational dynamics of market transition: Hybrid forms, property rights, and mixed economy in China. Administrative Science Quarterly, 37(1): 127.Google Scholar
North, D. C. 1993. Institutional change: A framework of analysis. In Sjostrand, S. E. (Ed.), Institutional change: Theory and empirical findings: 3546. Armonk, NY: M.E. Sharpe.Google Scholar
Ocasio, W., Mauskapf, M., & Steele, C. W. 2016. History, society, and institutions: The role of collective memory in the emergence and evolution of societal logics. Academy of Management Review, 41(4): 676699.Google Scholar
Pache, A.-C., & Santos, F. 2010. When worlds collide: The internal dynamics of organizational responses to conflicting institutional demands. Academy of Management Review, 35(3): 455476.Google Scholar
Padgett, J. F., & Powell, W. W. 2012. The politics of communist economic reform: Soviet Union and China. In Padgett, J. F. & Powell, W. W. (Eds.), The emergence of organizations and markets: 267315. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Palmer, D. 2012. Normal organizational wrongdoing: A critical analysis of theories of misconduct in and by organizations. Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Peng, M. W. 2003. Institutional transitions and strategic choices. Academy of Management Review, 28(2): 275296.Google Scholar
Peng, M. W., & Heath, P. S. 1996. The growth of the firm in planned economies in transition: Institutions, organizations, and strategic choice. Academy of Management Review, 21(2): 492528.Google Scholar
Raynard, M. 2016. Deconstructing complexity: Configurations of institutional complexity and structural hybridity. Strategic Organization, 14(4): 310335.Google Scholar
Raynard, M., Kodeih, F., & Greenwood, R. 2021. Proudly elitist and undemocratic? The distributed maintenance of contested practices. Organization Studies, 42(1): 733.Google Scholar
Raynard, M., Lounsbury, M., & Greenwood, R. 2013. Legacies of logics: Sources of community variation in CSR implementation in China. Research in the Sociology of Organizations, 39(Part A): 243276.Google Scholar
Seo, M.-G., & Creed, W. D. 2002. Institutional contradictions, praxis, and institutional change: A dialectical perspective. Academy of Management Review, 27(2): 222247.Google Scholar
Sine, W. D., & David, R. J. 2003. Environmental jolts, institutional change, and the creation of entrepreneurial opportunity in the US electric power industry. Research Policy, 32(2): 185207.Google Scholar
Smets, M., Aristidou, A., & Whittington, R. 2017. Towards a practice-driven institutionalism. In Greenwood, R., Oliver, C., Lawrence, T. B., & Meyer, R. (Eds.), The SAGE handbook of organizational institutionalism: 384411. London, UK: SAGE.Google Scholar
Stern, R. E., & Hassid, J. 2012. Amplifying silence: uncertainty and control parables in contemporary China. Comparative Political Studies, 45(10): 12301254.Google Scholar
Suddaby, R., Foster, W. M., & Mills, A. J. 2014. Historical institutionalism. In Bucheli, M. & Wadhwani, R. D. (Eds.), Organizations in time: History, theory, methods: 100123. Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Tan, J. 2005. Venturing in turbulent water: A historical perspective of economic reform and entrepreneurial transformation. Journal of Business Venturing, 20(5): 689704.Google Scholar
Tan, J. 2007. Phase transitions and emergence of entrepreneurship: The transformation of Chinese SOEs over time. Journal of Business Venturing, 22(1): 7796.Google Scholar
Tracey, P., & Phillips, N. 2011. Entrepreneurship in emerging markets: strategies for new venture creation in uncertain institutional contexts. Management International Review, 51: 2339.Google Scholar
Vogel, E. F. 2011. Deng Xiaoping and the transformation of China. Cambridge, MA: Belknap Press of Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Xu, C. 2011. The fundamental institutions of China's reforms and development. Journal of Economic Literature, 49(4): 10761151.Google Scholar
You, S., Zhou, A. J., Zhou, S. S., Jia, L., & Wang, C. 2021. Organizational learning under institutional complexity: Evidence from township clusters in China. Management and Organization Review, 17(4): 726754.Google Scholar
Zhang, M. 2008. From public to private: the newly enacted Chinese property law and the protection of property rights in China. Berkeley Business Law Journal, 5: 317.Google Scholar
Zhang, J., & Luo, X. R. 2013. Dared to care: Organizational vulnerability, institutional logics, and MNCs’ social responsiveness in emerging markets. Organization Science, 24(6): 17421764.Google Scholar
Zietsma, C., Groenewegen, P., Logue, D. M., & Hinings, C. R. 2017. Field or fields? Building the scaffolding for cumulation of research on institutional fields. Academy of Management Annals, 11(1): 391450.Google Scholar