Hostname: page-component-586b7cd67f-rdxmf Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-11-22T05:25:01.092Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Market Participation of Small-Scale Rice Farmers in Eastern Bolivia

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  03 August 2023

Diana C. Lopera
Affiliation:
Alliance of Bioversity International and CIAT, Cali, Colombia
Carolina Gonzalez
Affiliation:
Alliance of Bioversity International and CIAT, Cali, Colombia
Jose M. Martinez*
Affiliation:
Department of Agricultural, Food, and Resource Economics, Michigan State University, East Lansing, MI, USA
*
Corresponding author: Jose M. Martinez; Email: [email protected]
Rights & Permissions [Opens in a new window]

Abstract

Using a double-hurdle approach, we assess factors associated with the extent of participation in the rice market with data for small-scale farmers drawn from a nationally representative dataset. The results suggest that larger endowments and assets, animal farming and commercialization, and alternative off-farm income make farmers less likely to participate. Conversely, having access to credit, larger farm sizes, and being part of a farmers’ association all increase the likelihood of participation. Farms with better technological resources are also those with higher sales volumes. Further understanding market participation dynamics should prove useful for deriving evidence-based policy recommendations to strengthen this Bolivian sector.

Type
Research Article
Creative Commons
Creative Common License - CCCreative Common License - BY
This is an Open Access article, distributed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution licence (http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/), which permits unrestricted re-use, distribution and reproduction, provided the original article is properly cited.
Copyright
© The Author(s), 2023. Published by Cambridge University Press on behalf of the Southern Agricultural Economics Association

Introduction

Rice (Oryza sativa L.) is among the most consumed crops in Bolivia, third only to wheat and maize. Although the country evidenced an aggressive expansion of industrial crops like soybeans in the 2010s, rice kept a significant share of the national agricultural acreage by 2020 (INE, 2023). Yet, production faces several challenges of decreasing prices, low yields (FAO, 2022), limited technology adoption (Martinez et al., Reference Martinez, Labarta, Gonzalez and Lopera2021), and poor harvest and postharvest practices (Ortiz and Soliz, Reference Ortiz and Soliz2007). Furthermore, although most farmers are small-scale and their livelihoods rely on the crop heavily, the rate of market participation of rice farmers is remarkably low (Ortiz and Soliz, Reference Ortiz and Soliz2007). Limitations on transitioning into market participation are suggested by local experts as the main causes of recent reductions in the share of small-scale farmers in the sector.

Agricultural development research views the transition from subsistence to commercial agriculture as an improvement mechanism for agricultural households’ welfare and to stimulate growth within their sectors (Timmer, Reference Timmer and Timmer1998). In theory, farming households can specialize in the good for which they have a comparative advantage, thus benefiting from trade. However, market frictions and barriers to entry create inequalities of opportunity to access markets, thus disproportionately affecting small- and medium-scale farmers (Alene et al., Reference Alene, Manyong, Omanya, Mignouna, Bokanga and Odhiambo2008; Barrett, Reference Barrett2008; Boughton et al., Reference Boughton, Mather, Barrett, Benfica, Abdula, Tschirley and Cunguara2007; Gebremedhin and Jaleta, Reference Gebremedhin and Jaleta2010; Olwande et al., Reference Olwande, Smale, Mathenge, Place and Mithöfer2015). In the case of Bolivian rice farmers, however, this dynamic remains unexplored.

Studies covering the drivers of market participation have focused on transaction costs among semi-subsistence farming households (Bellemare and Barrett, Reference Bellemare and Barrett2006; Goetz, Reference Goetz1992; Holloway, Barrett, and Ehui, Reference Holloway, Barrett and Ehui2001; Jagwe, Machethe, and Ouma, Reference Jagwe, Machethe and Ouma2010; Key, Sadoulet, and De Janvry, Reference Key, Sadoulet and De Janvry2000; Makhura, Kirsten, and Delgado, Reference Makhura, Kirsten and Delgado2001; Omamo, Reference Omamo1998; Omiti et al., Reference Omiti, Otieno, Nyanamba and McCullough2009; Ouma et al., Reference Ouma, Jagwe, Obare and Abele2010). Meanwhile, another branch of the literature suggested that constrained endowments of agricultural assets are among the main factors behind market participation, that is, farmers under a certain asset threshold face a poverty trap keeping them out of trade feasibility (Boughton et al., Reference Boughton, Mather, Barrett, Benfica, Abdula, Tschirley and Cunguara2007). More recent research jointly considers transaction costs, asset endowment, and technology readiness (Achandi and Mujawamariya, Reference Achandi and Mujawamariya2016; Alene et al., Reference Alene, Manyong, Omanya, Mignouna, Bokanga and Odhiambo2008; Martey, Al-Hassan, and Kuwornu, Reference Martey, Al-Hassan and Kuwornu2012; Mather, Boughton, and Jayne, Reference Mather, Boughton and Jayne2013; Musah, Bonsu, and Seini, Reference Musah, Bonsu and Seini2014; Ohen, Etuk, and Onoja, Reference Ohen, Etuk and Onoja2013; Olwande and Mathenge, Reference Olwande and Mathenge2012; Olwande et al., Reference Olwande, Smale, Mathenge, Place and Mithöfer2015; Reyes et al., Reference Reyes, Donovan, Bernsten and Maredia2012; Woldeyohanes, Heckeley, and Surry, Reference Woldeyohanes, Heckeley and Surry2017), and some analyze how decisions on becoming sellers, buyers, or autarkic producers occur simultaneously (Muricho, Kasie, and Obare, Reference Muricho, Kasie and Obare2015; Ouma et al., Reference Ouma, Jagwe, Obare and Abele2010; Zanello, Reference Zanello2012).

However, research with a focus on small-scale rice farmers’ market participation is rather scarce (Achandi and Mujawamariya, Reference Achandi and Mujawamariya2016; Barrett and Dorosh, Reference Barrett and Dorosh1996; Ohen, Etuk, and Onoja, Reference Ohen, Etuk and Onoja2013), while there are several studies focused on maize production, especially in sub-Saharan Africa (Alene et al., Reference Alene, Manyong, Omanya, Mignouna, Bokanga and Odhiambo2008; Barrett, Reference Barrett2008; Boughton et al., Reference Boughton, Mather, Barrett, Benfica, Abdula, Tschirley and Cunguara2007; Martey, Al-Hassan, and Kuwornu, Reference Martey, Al-Hassan and Kuwornu2012; Muricho, Kasie, and Obare, Reference Muricho, Kasie and Obare2015; Musah, Bonsu, and Seini, Reference Musah, Bonsu and Seini2014; Ohen, Etuk, and Onoja, Reference Ohen, Etuk and Onoja2013; Olwande and Mathenge, Reference Olwande and Mathenge2012; Olwande et al., Reference Olwande, Smale, Mathenge, Place and Mithöfer2015; Omiti et al., Reference Omiti, Otieno, Nyanamba and McCullough2009). Despite the relevance of agriculture in South American countries, the poverty (or vulnerability to poverty) and market frictions faced by most small-scale producers, and rice farming’s potential as a crop for food security and income generation in the region, research on this intersection is still a void in the literature. Our research exploring the case of Bolivia contributes to this gap, studying the drivers of market participation of smallholder agricultural households.

With data from small-scale rice producers drawn from a nationally representative sample in Bolivia, we use a double-hurdle model to study the drivers of (1) market participation and (2) total sales of paddy rice among smallholder farming households. Our results reveal membership in a producer organization – which might work as a mechanism to decrease transaction costs – is positively correlated with both the probability of market participation and total sales. Also, the use of practices such as fertilization and mechanization is strongly correlated to market participation, suggesting that the technological gap in the sector is connected with market participation. We discuss how strategies to promote and strengthen producers’ associations should be followed, as this would foster an increase in the bargaining power of farmers. Also, agriculture policymakers should push for mechanisms to disseminate technologies and increase their adoption within the sector, thus improving productivity.

The remainder of the document is as follows: Section 2 provides a brief background on the Bolivian rice sector. Section 3 presents the theoretical framework of the analysis, while Section 4 presents the data and the empirical approach. Section 5 presents the statistical analysis results, followed by a discussion of its implications in Section 6. A seventh section concludes.

Background: Rice in Bolivia and Market Participation

By 2011, rice cultivation accounted for 6.3% of all Bolivian agricultural lands, with 95% of its production in the tropical region, specifically in the departments of Santa Cruz, Beni, and Cochabamba, which constitute the crop’s most suitable environment (Degiovanni, Martínez, and Motta, Reference Degiovanni, Martínez and Motta2010). By 2020, rice still covered roughly 5% of the national agricultural acreage (INE, 2023). Production is mainly intended for human consumption in domestic markets, with exports representing less than 1% of the overall national output (FAO, 2022). Also, rice is one of the nine prioritized for food security and rural development policies by the government (MDRyT–INE, 2012). Ultimately, rice production remains a highly relevant agricultural output in the Bolivian rural sector.

The sector is not exempt from major setbacks. Average farm gate prices for paddy rice have systematically decreased for several years now (FAO, 2022). Annual production increases were evidenced as a result of new dedicated lands, yet yields remain among the lowest on the continent (FAO, 2022). The latter follows from low technology adoption in the Bolivian rice sector, with most producers relying on manual farming and traditional crop varieties (Martinez et al., Reference Martinez, Labarta, Gonzalez and Lopera2021). Nevertheless, Bolivia has followed several steps toward the improvement of its rice sector. Since the crop is not native to the country, all available genetic resources are introduced (Nguyen and Tran, Reference Nguyen, Tran, Nguyen and Tran2002), but the country followed a process of population improvement with the objective of developing varieties more properly suited to the national conditions (Taboada, Guzmán, and Hurtado, Reference Taboada, Guzmán, Hurtado, Taboada, Guzmán and Hurtado2000). Over 15 modern improved varieties have been released in the country since 2004 (Martinez et al., Reference Martinez, Labarta, Gonzalez and Lopera2021; Taboada and Viruez, personal communication, March Reference Taboada and Viruez2023). This work is done by the Centro de Investigación Agrícola Tropical (CIAT-Bolivia), which also delivers technologies like biofortified rice varieties (Viruez et al., Reference Viruez, Yonekura, Taboada, Borrero, Grenier, Viruez, Yonekura, Taboada, Borrero and Grenier2016) and recommendations on input use (Viruez and Taboada, Reference Viruez and Taboada2013). Yet again, their adoption is not as widespread as desired (Martinez et al., Reference Martinez, Labarta, Gonzalez and Lopera2021)

Bolivian farmers participate in the market either through direct sales of unprocessed (paddy) rice or via a transformation stage in which they polish and process the rice (at their farms or their farmers’ association or by outsourcing) for the final consumption market. The latter, however, is the exception rather than the rule. Paddy rice sales can be assisted by associations or cooperatives, or rather take place as direct sales in local markets, which is the most common case. Such sales occur in major meeting points called “playas,” in which producers and buyers trade rice, soy, maize, and livestock, among many other agricultural products. The largest playas are located in Montero, San Juan de Yapacaní, Portachuelo, and Mineros, all municipalities in the department of Santa Cruz.

Paddy rice buyers are usually representatives of milling companies or private intermediaries, who bargain with the producers until a price is settled. However, conditions make the price not necessarily competitive and highly volatile (Bauguil, Reference Bauguil2003). Reports suggest that mills’ representatives push practices that place rice producers under unfavorable conditions. For instance, prices offered to farmers might be artificially decreased by claiming a need for arbitrary levels of grain humidity that do not necessarily reflect the actual quality of the rice lot. This can further increase the difference between paddy trade prices and final consumption prices, thus increasing the odds of farming households going rice-autarkic (De Janvry, Fafchamps, and Sadoulet, Reference De Janvry, Fafchamps and Sadoulet1991; Fafchamps, Reference Fafchamps1992), since their shadow price makes it optimal to neither sell nor buy.

Unable to transition from subsistence to commercial agriculture, the share of small-scale farmers has started to gradually reduce (Ortiz and Soliz, Reference Ortiz and Soliz2007). Vulnerable farmers are increasingly finding themselves forced to abandon their agricultural vocation and relocate to cities in an attempt to cover their needs (Taboada and Viruez, personal communication, March Reference Taboada and Viruez2023). Meanwhile, a few large farmers are starting to take over. Thus, agricultural policymakers are facing a highly complex scenario, in which production is further concentrated in the hands of a few, while the livelihoods of small-scale farmers are becoming increasingly vulnerable – that is, studying the factors behind market participation becomes of the utmost importance.

Theoretical Framework

Following Key, Sadoulet, and De Janvry (Reference Key, Sadoulet and De Janvry2000), we bring fixed and variable costs into the basic agricultural household model to analyze market participation. Bolivia is characterized by its slow regulatory systems and high-friction labor markets (Calvo, Reference Calvo2006). Rural markets are not exempt from labor frictions, with increasing cases of unavailability of agricultural workers (Ortiz and Soliz, Reference Ortiz and Soliz2007) that are not rare in South America (White, Labarta, and Leguía, Reference White, Labarta and Leguía2005). Hence, we expect that market failures are highly likely in this context and thus set a scenario with non-separability between decisions on production and consumption (De Janvry and Sadoulet, Reference De Janvry, Sadoulet, De Janvry and Sadoulet2006). As we take the case of rice farming, our model considers households that must decide on consumption and production levels, how much of their output to use for the next production cycle, and the extent of rice sales (or purchases). For that purpose, under an assumption of rationality, households maximize their utility subject to a series of restrictions. Focusing our analysis on rice, the representative household preferences are described by a utility function that depends on the consumption of rice (C r ), other bought goods (C i o , for i = 1, …, L), and exogenous shocks (Z u ). Specifically, the household problem is

(1) $$\max _{C_{r},{\bf C}_{o}\in \mathbb{R}_{+}^{L}}U(C_{r},{\bf C}_{o},Z_{u})$$

subject to

(2) $$\sum _{i=1}^{L} p_{i}^{o}C_{i}^{o}+S\leq p_{r}(v_{r}-C_{r})+T$$
(3) $$F(q_{r};{\bf x}_{r},Z_{r}^{p})\leq 0$$
(4) $$C_{r}+x_{r}^{{\rm *}}+v_{r}\leq q_{r}+D_{r},$$

which are budgetary, production, and resource balance restrictions. The budgetary restriction (Eq. 2) tells us that the value of rice sales net of household consumption (p r (v r C r )), with v r sales and C r consumption) plus other income (T), such as off-farm jobs, remittances, and subsidies, is large enough to cover for monetary savings (S) and the cost of other goods consumed ( $\sum _{i} p_{i}^{o}C_{i}^{o}+S$ ). As the household is capable of producing rice, the functional representation of the production plan (Eq. 3) refers to the technological capacities used in the crop, connecting the output of rice (namely, q r ) with the inputs used for its production ( ${\bf x}_{r}\in \mathbb{R}^{H}$ ) and exogenous production shocks (Z j p ). Finally, the resource equilibrium (Eq. 4) shows that the household consumption of rice, plus the amount left as productive supply (x r *) and the quantity sold, cannot exceed the quantity produced plus the initial endowment of rice (q r + D r ).

Households face different market relations as some have production surplus, hence selling part of their output (Key, Sadoulet, and De Janvry, Reference Key, Sadoulet and De Janvry2000). Conversely, others have a shortfall as they produce and must buy (net buyers), whereas others do not even participate in markets (self-sufficiency). An explanation of such differences lies in transaction costs, which can be either proportional or fixed. The first kind is the case of unit costs (e.g., transportation costs and imperfect information) that affect both the decision to participate and the trading volume. The second kind of cost does not vary with the amount of the purchased good, as in the case of searching for buyers, infrastructure, credit, etc. Hence, the latter affects only the decision to participate in markets. Finally, another important effect of transaction costs on market participation is the degree of specialization or diversification. Agricultural households facing high transaction costs are usually more diversified, hence having less surplus for sale. Otherwise, they will become more specialized in a specific crop to become market-oriented (Larochelle and Alwang, Reference Larochelle and Alwang2015).

We consider market participation as a choice variable, thus introducing transaction costs into the household’s maximization problem. Now, the decisions solve not only for optimal consumption, inputs, and production but also for market participation (and thus the optimal level of sales or purchases). Following Zanello (Reference Zanello2012), we introduce proportional (t p q ) and fixed (t f q ) transaction costs, where q ∈ {s, b} for seller or buyer, so the budget constraint now follows:

(5) $$\sum _{i=1}^{L} p_{i}^{o}C_{i}^{o}+S-[\delta ^{s}[(p_{r}-t_{p}^{s}(z^{s}))v_{r}-t_{f}^{s}(z^{s})]-\delta ^{b}[(p_{r}+t_{p}^{b}(z^{b}))C_{r}+t_{f}^{b}(z^{b})]]-T\leq 0$$

hence maintaining purchases and sales as separate. Note that, in the specification of equation (5), market participation as a seller or a buyer of rice is a choice variable represented by δ s and δ b , respectively. Hence, δ s = 1 if a strictly positive amount of rice is sold (i.e., whenever v r > 0), and zero otherwise. Likewise, δ b = 1 whenever C r > 0, and zero otherwise. The presence of proportional transaction costs causes the price perceived by the seller to be lower than the market price (by an amount of t p s ), whereas the real price paid by the buyer is higher than the market price (by an amount of t p b ). On the other hand, t f s and t f b are fixed sale and purchase transaction costs, respectively. Note that the transaction costs are not directly observable by the researcher. Nonetheless, these can be represented as a function of external characteristics that can be observed (e.g., transportation costs, labor supervision costs, and travel time), hence allowing them to be proxied by other related variables. In the model, these external characteristics are represented by z s and z b for sellers and buyers, respectively.

Therefore, the final household’s problem is to determine whether to participate in the market, and with how much to participate (as seller or buyer), thus obtaining its maximum feasible utility, under restrictions (3), (4), and (5). For that purpose, the household compares the expected utility between selling or buying rice to the expected utility of being in autarky (self-sufficiency). Formally, assuming a well-behaved utility and production plans, the household’s problem is the Karush–Kuhn–Tucker (KKT) solution to

(6) $$\begin{gathered} \mathcal{L}({C_r},{v_r},{\delta ^b},{\delta ^s},{{\mathbf{C}}_o}) = U({C_r},{{\mathbf{C}}_o},{Z_u}) + \mu ({q_r} - x_r^{\text{*}} + {D_r} - {v_r} - {C_r}) \hfill \\ + \psi F({q_r};{{\mathbf{x}}_r},Z_r^p) + \lambda \left\{ {\sum\limits_{i = 1}^L {p_i^o} C_i^o + S - \left[ {{\delta ^s}\left[ {\left( {{p_r} - t_p^s({z^s})} \right){v_r} - t_f^s({z^s})} \right]} \right.} \right. \hfill \\ -\left.\delta ^{b}\left[\left(p_{r}+t_{p}^{b}(z^{b})\right)C_{r}+t_{f}^{b}(z^{b})]\right]-T\right\} \end{gathered}$$

where μ, ψ, and λ are, respectively, the Lagrange multipliers associated with the resource equilibrium (Eq. 4), technological (Eq. 3), and budgetary constraints (Eq. 5).

Introducing fixed costs creates a discontinuity in the optimization (Key, Sadoulet, and De Janvry, Reference Key, Sadoulet and De Janvry2000), which must be broken down into two steps. First, an optimal conditional solution to the market participation regime (seller, buyer, or autarkic) follows from the KKT conditions with respect to C r , q r , x r *, and v r (Key, Sadoulet, and De Janvry, Reference Key, Sadoulet and De Janvry2000; Ouma et al., Reference Ouma, Jagwe, Obare and Abele2010). Then, the second step is the decision on participation that makes the farmer better off, comparing the achievable indirect utility function under each regime. In our study, we are interested in market participation and total sales, so, from utility maximization, it follows that with δ s* ∈ {0, 1} an index of participation:

(7) $$\matrix{ {{\delta ^{s{\rm{*}}}} = {\delta ^s}({p_r},t_f^s({z^s}),Z_r^p,{Z_u})} \cr {v_r^{\rm{*}} = {\delta ^{s{\rm{*}}}} \times f({p_r},t_p^s({z^s}),t_f^s({z^s}),Z_r^p,{Z_u})} \cr } $$

so that sales are nonzero if and only if participation occurs. More importantly, participation depends only on fixed transaction costs, whereas total sales depend on fixed and proportional costs. Thus, we are interested in modeling how a factor h can affect market participation (i.e., ∂δ s /∂h) and total sales (i.e., ∂v r /∂h), where the latter effect can be either be unconditional (i.e., including the potential changes on participation) or strictly focused among those participating in the market ( $\partial v_{r}/\partial h| \delta ^{s}=1$ ).

From the non-separability of the setting, we would expect demographic and non-production farm-level variables to affect participation and total sales significantly.Footnote 1 Also, we would expect that factors associated with transaction costs are strongly correlated with market participation and total sales. Since participation in the paddy market follows a rational decision, whenever a farm does not engage in trade, we are in a situation of corner solution (sales are zero) instead of sample selection for the outcome of the total sales (sales are unobserved). Therefore, corner solution methods such as truncated regression should be preferred. We further discuss our data and empirical methods in the following section.

Materials and Methods

Data

We use information from a cross-sectional collected across the rice-producing regions of Bolivia in 2013–2014 to measure the adoption of improved rice varieties. These surveys were collected at the farm level after interviewing the members of the household in charge of managing the rice crops and other agricultural activities done on the farm. This allowed us to capture information both from the household and from the productive activities at the plot level. We used a multistage sampling framework across the rice-producing regions, so that:

  1. a. communities were selected as the primary sampling unit (PSU);

  2. b. within every PSU, a sample of farming households was selected (optimal cluster size aimed at 12–15 households per community);

  3. c. via a clustered sampling strategy, a design effect was estimated to correct the minimum sample size to compensate for the loss of variance from collecting data within communities (clusters);

  4. d. finally, we used a design effect-adjusted, simple random sampling to determine the minimum number of observations needed to achieve national representativeness.

Although medium- and large-scale producers were also interviewed, we focus our attention on small-scale rice farmers as they represent the vast majority of farmers and are the ones facing the most barriers to linking to markets (Ortiz and Soliz, Reference Ortiz and Soliz2007). Bolivian experts’ definition of small-scale farmers covers all farmers with farms under 50 ha and rice production under 20 ha (Ortiz and Soliz, Reference Ortiz and Soliz2007). After selecting farms with under 50 ha (462 observations), we keep in our subsample farmers with up to 5 ha of rice since this is the largest rice area found in the sample among non-sellers,Footnote 2 thus keeping a sample of 358 cases (133 sellers and 225 non-sellers) out of a national sample of 802 observations. Following what we previously discussed, our response variables of interest are a binary variable that takes the value of 1 if the household is a net seller of rice (zero otherwise) and tons of paddy rice sold for the 2012–2013 season.

In Table 1, we summarize the covariates included in the model. We include household demographics based on the head of the household and other household-level covariates, like the number of working-age persons and the number of dependents. We also bring in variables reflecting financial capital and tangible assets, including sales of animals or other crops, off-farm employment, and the total size of the farm. We add a Household Asset Index proposed by Filmer and Pritchett (Reference Filmer and Pritchett2002), a standardized, principal component analysis index based on the household ownership of durable goods like television, fridge, and backpack sprayer, among other appliances for household and farming activities. In addition, following Barrett (Reference Barrett2008), we include binary variables of technology adoption for rice production, namely agrochemical use (for pest, weed, or disease control), fertilization, and the use of improved rice varieties. Improved varieties follow the definition of modern improved rice varieties (Martinez et al., Reference Martinez, Labarta, Gonzalez and Lopera2021), which are materials selected or developed by the national crop improvement initiative. Other varieties were introduced in the country without validation of their suitability. Also, we consider the use of mechanization as a technology enhancement measure. This determines whether a farm used (rented) a mechanized (service) for either establishing or harvesting the crop. Finally, we add variables related to transaction costs, namely the membership in a rice farmers’ association, having received extension or training in rice production, and an adjusted measure of distance to markets.

Table 1. Explanatory variables included in the double-hurdle model of market participation and rice sales of small-scale rice farmers in Eastern Bolivia, 2014

Based on our theoretical framework, we expect participation in the market to be welfare-enhancing. As a proxy for this, we consider the Poverty Probability Index, which measures the probability of a household falling under the national poverty line. We summarize this measure in Table 2, along with rice acreage and yield metrics. The average farm has a probability of poverty of 43.7%, but non-sellers are roughly 5 percentage points more likely to be poor than market participants, thus consistent with our rationale. Although the range of rice acreage is the same between groups, we find that average non-sellers dedicate roughly 1 ha of land to rice production. On the other hand, their counterparts dedicate an average of 2.23 ha to production. Differences also translate to productivity, with market participants having yields of 2.41 tons/ha, thus closer to the national averageFootnote 3 than non-sellers who report a yield of 1.62 tons/ha.

Table 2. Acreage, productivity, and poverty vulnerability of small-scale rice farmers in Eastern Bolivia, 2014

a Reporting p-values of difference in means test. The null hypothesis is no difference in means.

b The PPI measures the probability that a surveyed household falls below the poverty line.

Descriptive Statistics of Variables included in the Model

Of the 358 selected small-scale rice farming households, 37.2% participate in the paddy market, and on average, they sold 4.29 tons of rice in the previous season (2013). We report the mean and median of the variables part of the analysis in Table 3. There are no statistical differences in most household demographics and human capital variables between sellers and non-sellers. The share of female-led households, age of the household head, schooling, incidence of food scarcity, number of working-age persons, and number of dependants are statistically the same between groups. Interestingly, net sellers have fewer years of experience with the crop on average (13 years vis-à-vis 18.8 years among non-sellers), which could be connected to newer farmers being more likely to adopt technologies, thus being more productive. Although the number of dependents, on average, is statistically equivalent between sellers and non-sellers, the latter have a slightly larger mean, which translates into additional food demand pressures.

Table 3. Descriptive statistics of variables included in the double-hurdle model of market participation and rice sales of small-scale farmers in Eastern Bolivia, 2014

* p-Value for test for difference in means between net sellers and non-sellers. Pearson Chi-square test for binary covariates.

In terms of tangible assets and financial capital, we observe that, as expected, the average farm size differs significantly between sellers and non-sellers (24.31 vis-à-vis to 14.3 ha). Likewise, the former nearly double the likelihood of having their land titled (45.9% of the cases vs. 23.6%), whereas the latter are more likely to have income perceived from off-farm employment (50.2% vs. 36.8%). Non-seller households reported acquiring credit in 4% of the cases, whereas the figure is 15% among those who engage in the paddy rice market. This difference is not unexpected, considering the previously mentioned differences in land endowments and titling. Nevertheless, we do not observe any significant difference in the cases of the Household Asset Index or income-generating animal sales. Also, sellers have a more likely diversified production schedule, with 36.1% of households earning income from other crops, while non-sellers only reported sales of other crops on 18.7% of the cases.

There are strong asymmetries on most dimensions of technology adoption except that of improved varietal use, depending on whether the household engages in rice trade – with non-sellers being on the less intensive side of adoption. Some of the detected differences, however, are stronger than others. For instance, net sellers are more likely to use agrochemicals than non-sellers by roughly 19.5 percentage points, while that change is about 9 percentage points for fertilization. Meanwhile, mechanization reports a difference in adoption of slightly over 14 percentage points (25.6% for sellers and 11.6% for non-sellers).

Finally, from the side of factors affecting transaction costs, non-seller households report having received training or extension services for rice production over the past production season (2013) 14.2% of the time, whereas sellers reported receiving that 25.6% of the time. Also, the difference in associativity is striking: while 18% of farming households that engage in rice trade are part of a producers’ association or cooperative, that metric is only 2.7% among non-selling farming households. Similarly, it is worth noting that the average distance to markets – captured in the Travel Effort Index – reveals that the effective absolute distance more than doubles when comparing sellers and non-sellers. The highlighted differences between sellers and non-sellers across demographic, financial, and technological dimensions further support the need for a systematic analysis to understand how these factors jointly drive market participation and final sales.

Econometric Approach

Empirically, we observe whether a rice farming household participates in the market and total paddy sales. However, the total sales are zero if a farmer does not enter the market; hence, the nature of the data makes a linear specification inadequate to model the expected value (Mather, Boughton, and Jayne, Reference Mather, Boughton and Jayne2013; Wooldridge, Reference Wooldridge2010). Although one might easily confuse this problem with one of sample selection (Heckman, Reference Heckman1979) within the data – that is, taking no sales as a “missing value” rather than zero – we are departing from a principle of maximization in which making no sales (v r = 0) reflects a rational decision (corner solution) from the farming household (Alene et al., Reference Alene, Manyong, Omanya, Mignouna, Bokanga and Odhiambo2008; Boughton et al., Reference Boughton, Mather, Barrett, Benfica, Abdula, Tschirley and Cunguara2007; Makhura, Kirsten, and Delgado, Reference Makhura, Kirsten and Delgado2001; Olwande et al., Reference Olwande, Smale, Mathenge, Place and Mithöfer2015). We use the two-part extension of the type I Tobit model formulated by Cragg (Reference Cragg1971), usually referred to as the truncated normal hurdle (or double-hurdle) model (Wooldridge, Reference Wooldridge2010). This allows the underlying coefficients of the probability of participation to differ from those of the extent of sales.

Let ω be a binary variable that takes the value of 1 if a household engages in trade and 0 otherwise. Also, let y be the total paddy rice sales that follow

(8) $$\matrix{ y { \ = \omega {y^{\rm{*}}}} \cr {{y^{\rm{*}}}} { = {\rm{x}}{{\theta}} + \varepsilon } \cr } $$

where y* is a nonnegative latent variable, x′ ∈ ℝ k contains observed attributes of the household, and D(ϵ|x) is truncated normal with a lower bound at − x θ and variance σ 2 (Wooldridge, Reference Wooldridge2010). Moreover, with m′ ∈ ℝ j also a set of household attributes, define the probability of market participation as:

(9) $$P\left(\omega =1|{\rm m}\right)=\Phi \left({\rm m}{\beta }\right)$$

in which Φ is the standard normal CDF, and let ω and y* be conditionally independent over a set of explanatory variables that are in both x and m. Then, when market participation occurs (y > 0), the conditional density of y is

(10) $$f\left( {y|{\rm{x}},{\rm{m}},y \gt 0} \right) = \left( {{1 \over \sigma }} \right){{\phi \left( {{{y - {\rm{x}}\theta } \over \sigma }} \right)} \over {1 - \Phi \left( {{{ - {\rm{x}}\theta } \over \sigma }} \right)}} = \left( {{1 \over \sigma }} \right){{\phi \left( {{{y - {\rm{x}}\theta } \over \sigma }} \right)} \over {\Phi \left( {{{{\rm{x}}\theta } \over \sigma }} \right)}}$$

while the conditional density for all possible values of y is

(11) $$f\left( {y|{\rm{x}},{\rm{m}}} \right) = {[1 - \Phi ({\rm{m}}{\beta} )]^{1[y = 0]}}{\left[ {\Phi ({\rm{m}}{\beta} )\left( {{1 \over \sigma }} \right){{\phi \left( {{{y - {\rm{x}}\theta } \over \sigma }} \right)} \over {\Phi \left( {{{{\rm{x}}\theta } \over \sigma }} \right)}}} \right]^{1[y \gt 0]}},$$

so, we can obtain consistent estimates $\widehat{{\theta }}$ and $\widehat{{\beta }}$ by quasi-maximum likelihood (QMLE).Footnote 4

Partial Effects

In this nonlinear scenario, we see how the coefficient estimates $\widehat{{\theta }}$ and $\widehat{{\beta }}$ would provide us with information about the direction of an effect, but of real importance are the partial effectsFootnote 5 of the covariates. The partial effects from the Probit model are straightforward and are directly connected with our theoretical model through ∂δ s /∂h. On the other hand, there are two kinds of conditional expected values of y that are of particular interest – and thus their related partial effects. Namely, we will have the expected value when y > 0 and for all possible values of y. These follow:

(12) $$E\left(y|{\rm x},{\rm m},y\gt 0\right)={\rm x}{{{\theta}} }+\sigma \lambda \left({{\rm x}{{{\theta}} } \over \sigma }\right)$$
(13) $$E\left(y|{\rm x},{\rm m}\right)=\Phi \left({\rm m}{\beta }\right)\left[{\rm x}{{{\theta}} }+\sigma \lambda \left({{\rm x}{{{\theta}} } \over \sigma }\right)\right],$$

where λ(⋅) is the inverse of the Mills ratio. Then, the related partial effects are as follows:

(14) $${\partial E\left(y|{\rm x},{\rm m},y\gt 0\right) \over \partial h}=\theta _{h}\left[1-\lambda \left({{\rm x}{{{\theta}} } \over \sigma }\right)\left[{{\rm x}{{{\theta}} } \over \sigma }+\sigma \lambda \left({{\rm x}{{{\theta}} } \over \sigma }\right)\right]\right]$$
(15) $${\partial E\left(y|{\rm x},{\rm m}\right) \over \partial h}=\phi \left({\rm m}{\beta }\right)\beta _{h}\left[{\rm x}{\theta }+\sigma \lambda \left({{\rm x}{{{\theta}} } \over \sigma }\right)\right]+\Phi \left({\rm m}{\beta }\right)\theta _{h}\left[1-\lambda \left({{\rm x}{{{\theta}} } \over \sigma }\right)\left[{{\rm x}{{{\theta }}} \over \sigma }+\sigma \lambda \left({{\rm x}{{{\theta}} } \over \sigma }\right)\right]\right],$$

which are directly liked with our theoretical correlations of interest, namely ∂v r /∂h and ∂v r /∂h|δ s = 1. Thus, while conditional (on y > 0) average partial effects (CAPE) consider only those who did nonzero sales, unconditional average partial effects (UAPE) consider the potential effect within the whole sample (Mzyece, Reference Mzyece2016).

Although a Tobit model can also be used under our setting, the double-hurdle approach provides greater flexibility: while the Tobit approach requires that x = m and θ = β , the double hurdle allows θ and β to vary freely and allows for x and m to be in different vector spaces. Therefore, the double hurdle brings fewer assumptions into the empirical strategy. If, for instance, attribute h appears only in the Probit model of market participation, then θ h = 0. Conversely, if h is only a covariate for total sales, then we have β h = 0. Either way, partial effects are largely simplified when a variable is part of only one side of the model.

Finally, due to the two-part nature of the analysis, we rely on cluster-bootstrapping for retrieving valid standard errorsFootnote 6 (Wooldridge, Reference Wooldridge2010). Other flexible estimation methods are based on the Tobit II and the log-normal double-hurdle models, but our specification tests suggested that QMLE based on the truncated normal double-hurdle should be the preferred estimator (see Supplementary Materials A.1.).

Results

We report the estimated partial effects of interest in Table 4. The average partial effect (APE) of the covariates on the probability of market participation are those in column (1), while columns (2) and (3) present their conditional and unconditional (on participation) average partial effects on total paddy rice sales (i.e., CAPE and UAPE), respectively. From the side of market participation, we find that, as the household head is older, the probability of participating in the market increases. Although weakly significant, an additional year of age is correlated with a 0.5 percentage point increase in the probability of participation. Such a finding is similar to that of Goetz (Reference Goetz1992), suggesting that older leaders in the household are better connected and more experienced in dealing with intrinsic aspects of local markets. However, other demographic and human capital variables show no significant effect on participation.

Table 4. Average partial effects on the probability of market participation and total paddy rice sales from the double-hurdle model for small-scale farmers in Eastern Bolivia, 2014

Probit regression: Wald test χ 2(24)= 96.64, p-value = 0.000.

Truncated regression: Wald test χ 2(18)= 69.96, p-value = 0.000.

Cluster bootstrap standard errors (1,000 reps.) in parentheses. *p <0.1; ** p <0.05; ***p <0.01.

a Reporting average partial effects (APE), average partial effects conditional on market participation (CAPE), and unconditional average partial effects (UAPE).

In terms of assets and financial capital, our results suggest that farm size is not correlated with market participation. On the other hand, farming households that acquired credit were 22.7 percentage points more likely to participate in the market than those who did not access credit. Conversely, when sales of crops other than rice take place, these are correlated to a 9.4 percentage point (weakly significant) increase in the probability of participation. When it is found that a household receives income from animal sales or off-farm employment, the probability of market participation decreases by roughly 9.5 and 11.9 percentage points, respectively. Our findings are in line with those of Alene et al. (Reference Alene, Manyong, Omanya, Mignouna, Bokanga and Odhiambo2008), Barrett (Reference Barrett2008), and Musah, Bonsu, and Seini (Reference Musah, Bonsu and Seini2014), which point to credit access as a mechanism to further invest in production, hence increasing the probability of market participation. However, differing from the findings of Boughton et al. (Reference Boughton, Mather, Barrett, Benfica, Abdula, Tschirley and Cunguara2007) that suggest that animal-derived income positively correlates with participation, we estimate a negative effect. Nonetheless, our finding is feasible within the theory – diversification on small scales can lead to autarkic production – and by empirical results of Woldeyohanes, Heckeley, and Surry (Reference Woldeyohanes, Heckeley and Surry2017) and Makhura, Kirsten, and Delgado (Reference Makhura, Kirsten and Delgado2001), with the latter pointing to the demand for in-household labor from other activities as a source of the negative effect. Also, as we derive our analysis from a cross section, we cannot consider, for instance, the seasonality of variables correlated with profits from animal sales.

Technology adoption is partially correlated with market participation. We find a weakly statistically significant average partial effect for the case of agrochemicals correlated to an increase in the probability of participation by 9.2 percentage points. Finally, among the factors associated with transaction costs, there are no significant partial effects from extension or training on participation, nor the distance to markets, as captured by the Travel Effort Index. Nevertheless, a significant partial effect arises from being part of an association or cooperative: on average, this is correlated to an increase in the probability of participation by roughly 27.1 percentage points. This further highlights the crucial role played by associativity in the Bolivian rice sector, which favors technological dissemination (Martinez et al., Reference Martinez, Labarta, Gonzalez and Lopera2021; Ortiz and Soliz, Reference Ortiz and Soliz2007) and market participation, according to our findings.

Now, we focus on total sales of paddy rice, for which we have both conditional and unconditional average partial effects – reporting the latter in parentheses in what follows. An additional year of education by the household head increases sales of paddy rice, on average, by roughly 0.276 tons (0.114 tons). The literature often points to a lack of education as a barrier to entering markets (Musah, Bonsu, and Seini, Reference Musah, Bonsu and Seini2014; Olwande et al., Reference Olwande, Smale, Mathenge, Place and Mithöfer2015; Sigei, Reference Sigei2014), and it is also true that higher education allows farmers to make better choices according to market conditions, thus likely making more efficient sales. On the other hand, for each additional dependent in the household, total sales are expected to be reduced by roughly 0.589 tons (0.225 tons), on average. Also, on average, sales are expected to be reduced for each additional working-age person in the household, although the effect is weakly significant (and insignificant in the unconditional case), likely reflecting additional food demand in the household. We do not detect any difference in sales based on food scarcity or the age of the household head. However, we find that the average effect of an additional year of experience producing rice is weakly connected to a total sales reduction of 0.199 tons (0.08 tons). Also, female-led households that participate in the market sell 1.78 tons less than other farmers, on average. In terms of assets and financial capital, we find that a 10% increase in farm size is related to an increase of 0.097 tons (0.041 tons) of paddy rice sales, so larger capacities are naturally connected to larger sales. Credit is only related to sales on the unconditional case (i.e., the estimated potential effect across all in-sample farmers), suggesting an increase of 1.09 additional tons of sales when credit is available. Our finding on farm size and credit availability is consistent with previous findings in developing countries (Abera, Reference Abera2009; Alene et al., Reference Alene, Manyong, Omanya, Mignouna, Bokanga and Odhiambo2008; Olwande et al., Reference Olwande, Smale, Mathenge, Place and Mithöfer2015; Woldeyohanes, Heckeley, and Surry, Reference Woldeyohanes, Heckeley and Surry2017).

Among the factors associated with transaction costs, we find a negative effect from extension or training (although in the unconditional effect is insignificant). Our analysis suggests that, on average, those who received extension or training sell, on average, about 1.7 tons less than those who did not receive such services. Although counterintuitive at first hand, the result should not be unexpected. It is worth asking who makes use of that kind of service from the start, which reveals that those who received (accessed) training and extension were likely in the lower bound of crop expertise beforehandFootnote 7 – even if they produced enough to enter the market. Finally, our findings point to the crucial relevance of membership in a farmers’ association to reduce transaction costs, thus increasing sales. On average, members of an association sell an additional 3.19 tons (2.74 tons) than non-associated farmers.

From the side of technological enhancements, we find that agrochemicals and mechanization use are correlated with total sales, although weakly. Respectively, these imply differences in the average total sales of 2.53 and 2.09 tons each compared to those who do not use those technologies. The unconditional effect is only significant in the case of agrochemicals. These findings are consistent with previous results of two-part model analyses found in Musah, Bonsu, and Seini (Reference Musah, Bonsu and Seini2014), Reyes et al. (Reference Reyes, Donovan, Bernsten and Maredia2012), and Barrett (Reference Barrett2008), revealing that technology implementations are related to productivity increases that are correlated with both increased probabilities of market participation and intensity of sales, especially across small-scale farmers (Alene et al., Reference Alene, Manyong, Omanya, Mignouna, Bokanga and Odhiambo2008; Olwande et al., Reference Olwande, Smale, Mathenge, Place and Mithöfer2015). Finally, farms located in the department of Santa Cruz vastly exceed the average sales of farms (additional 2.93 tons in the CAPE, although insignificant for the UAPE) that are either in the Beni or Cochabamba departments. Given that Santa Cruz is the department with the highest concentration of playas, the result is consistent with the local conditions and likely explains the apparent no-correlation of sales with distance to markets (i.e., most distance effect is pooled into the Santa Cruz binary control).

Discussion

As one of Bolivia’s most consumed and produced agricultural products, rice has become a strategic crop to achieve objectives of food security and improved livelihoods in rural areas. Policy efforts to bring change into a crop’s productive sector via technological transformation and increased market participation are common in the developing world (Olwande et al., Reference Olwande, Smale, Mathenge, Place and Mithöfer2015), including Bolivia (Larochelle and Alwang, Reference Larochelle and Alwang2015), but these may not be as successful as expected, especially among small farmers (Barrett, Reference Barrett2008). Although small-scale production represents the vast majority of rice-producing households in Bolivia, only a fraction of them engage in trade (Ortiz and Soliz, Reference Ortiz and Soliz2007), which, in addition to the existence of market failures, further limits the extent to which their welfare can be improved via production enhancement. Based on a nationally representative sample, nearly half of the rice farmers are producing only for self-consumption. Also, within a subsample of comparable rice acreage, we find that market participants are more productive and are less vulnerable to poverty. We provide results pointing to feasible factors and mechanisms that can increase the probability of participation and the extent of market participation, thus serving as potential recommendations for public policy targeting.

Our analysis suggests that participation is highly correlated with factors of financial capital, technology adoption, and determinants of transaction costs. Factors such as the acquisition of credit and alternative income sources play an important role in affecting the market participation of rice farmers. Specifically, income generated from the sales of animals (or their by-products) significantly decreases the probability of participation, whereas sales of other crops are correlated positively with participation. Credit acquisition remains an important channel to keep farmers enrolled in production, so efforts toward a more robust and accessible market for agricultural finance are likely to help increase the market participation of smallholder farmers. Farmers’ connectedness through producers’ associations or cooperatives is also a major driver of market participation, and we argue that its relevance comes through a channel of decreasing transaction costs. Such a finding builds on recent evidence around the Bolivian rice sector that highlights the strong incidence of associativity in technological enhancement. Strengthening the national and regional systems of association is, therefore, a strong mechanism for leveling the ground for producers when bargaining prices in regional playas in addition to their potential to disseminate technologies.

Finally, we find that determinants of total paddy rice sales are mostly found on the side of the relative productive scale, potential household food demands, and transaction costs – mainly through membership in farmers’ associations. Using agrochemicals (pest and disease controls) and mechanization significantly increase the expected total sales from small-scale farmers. Therefore, our results further highlight the need to foster technological adoption, which is reportedly limited in the Bolivian rice sector (Martinez et al., Reference Martinez, Labarta, Gonzalez and Lopera2021). Larger and steadier participation in the market serves not only to increase producers’ revenues but also to provide local systems with sufficient production, which can help in the stabilization of consumer prices. Altogether, the results also support previous findings on the Bolivian rice sector: even when focused on small-scale rice farmers, market participation and extent of participation are strongly influenced by the size of the productive land. Following the existence of market failures, participation is not fully determined by land availability or prices, so efforts to better target and engage producers with less land – even within the segment of small-scale farming – are needed for guaranteeing equitable growth.

Our findings provide additional and valuable insight into the landscape of rice farming in Bolivia, with a focus on small-scale farming. Our data suggest that, although the adoption of modern improved varieties is rather low, efforts from the Bolivian rice breeding program have been able to reach both commercial and self-consumption farmers. This means that although further efforts to promotion are needed to reach higher levels of adoption, these will likely reach all scales of production, thus opening a window for potential impacts not only on productivity but also in nutrition with the dissemination of biofortified materials (Viruez et al., Reference Viruez, Yonekura, Taboada, Borrero, Grenier, Viruez, Yonekura, Taboada, Borrero and Grenier2016). Also, we find that rice farmers’ associations play a crucial role in increasing participation and total sales, thus highlighting a channel that should be strengthened by public policies. As suggested by Markelova et al. (Reference Markelova, Meinzen-Dick, Hellin and Dohrn2009), these organizations increase the bargaining power of their associates, serving as a bridge to resolve coordination and market inefficiencies. Unfortunately, under the conditions that define the structure of the Bolivian paddy rice market – highly volatile prices, suboptimal pricing, and high transaction costs (Taboada and Viruez, personal communication, March Reference Taboada and Viruez2023) – additional incentives are driving small-scale farmers to venture out of selling paddy rice, with many reported cases (especially subsistence farmers) being forced to abandon their rural vocation. Our results, thus, cast light on potential channels that can be strengthened to revert such a trend, providing paths for increasing participation, production, and welfare of small-scale Bolivian rice farmers.

Although our findings provide relevant insights based on the only available nationally representative sample of rice farmers in the country, there are limitations that should be considered and addressed in future research. First, our analysis is based on partial correlations that cannot be asserted as causal. Therefore, although our estimates are qualitatively appealing, the exact magnitude of the effects remains to be explored. Studies exploiting exogenous variations on factors connected to proportional and fixed transaction costs would prove useful in quantifying the causal effects on market participation. Second, despite the suggestions from experts pointing to the available data as still representative of local conditions, more recent data are crucial for validating our analysis. Third, detailed and representative information on market-level data should be brought into the analysis. While our analysis exploits all available information at the farmer level, the dynamics of bargaining between farmers and sales intermediaries remain insufficiently explored and should be considered in future analyses.

Conclusion

Despite the relevance of rice farming as an income and food security crop in Bolivia, the market participation of small-scale rice farmers remains low. This limits the potential for welfare enhancement that can be achieved by national research programs aiming at the technological improvement of the crop. Our findings suggest that strengthening credit channels can increase market participation and sales. A central finding of our analysis is the strong relevance of membership in a farmer association in increasing the probability of market participation and final sales, likely by means of improving coordination and bargaining power. Overall, our finding suggests that efforts to promote the joint expansion of credit channels, technology adoption, and collective action are key to improving the livelihoods of small-scale Bolivian rice farmers.

Supplementary material

The supplementary material for this article can be found at https://doi.org/10.1017/aae.2023.25

Data availability statement

Implemented data and replication codes will be provided by the corresponding author upon request.

Acknowledgments

We want to thank Ricardo Labarta, Camila Alvayay, Thomas Keene, and Hyunjung Kim for their comments and suggestions made on previous versions of the manuscript and to Jeff Wooldridge for his valuable guidance on the empirical analysis. We also thank the managing editor, Dr. Carlos Carpio, and the three anonymous reviewers, whose comments and suggestions helped to greatly improve our research.

Author contribution

Conceptualization: DCL, CG, and JMM; data curation: DCL and JMM; formal analysis: DCL and CG; methodology: DCL, CG, and JMM; resources: CG; writing – original draft: DCL; writing – review and editing: DCL, CG, and JMM.

Financial support

This study is a result of the project Adoption study of rice varieties in Bolivia led by the Alliance of Bioversity International and CIAT, made possible with support from the CGIAR Global Research Program on Rice and HarvestPlus. HarvestPlus’ principal donors are the UK government, the Bill & Melinda Gates Foundation, the US government’s Feed the Future initiative, Government of Canada, the European Commission, and donors to the CGIAR Research Program on Agriculture for Nutrition and Health (A4NH). HarvestPlus is also supported by the John D. and Catherine T. MacArthur Foundation.

Competing interests

The authors declare none.

Footnotes

1 Nevertheless, this is not equivalent to a separability test. The theoretical framework, however, is flexible enough to make any significant effects (on participation or sales) be consistent with the scenario of non-separability.

2 We also performed the estimation using a subsample of farmers that follows the definition of Ortiz and Soliz (Reference Ortiz and Soliz2007) (i.e., 462 farmers, with 51% of market participation) which inflates the coefficient point estimates of most covariates. We report those estimations as additional results in the supplementary materials. Nevertheless, as producers beyond 5 ha are always market participants, we argue that keeping farmers with comparable rice areas provides a more suitable estimation of average partial effects. Therefore, we base our interpretations on the estimations derived from the further constrained sample.

3 The production season of the sample is 2013–2014, which is compared to a 2.7 tons/ha yield at the national level as reported in FAOSTAT (FAO, 2022).

4 Although the estimates from maximum likelihood (MLE) and QMLE are always identical, the efficiency of standard errors from MLE only occurs whenever both the conditional mean and distribution(s) are correctly specified. Conversely, QMLE only requires a correctly specified conditional mean and then uses a robust estimator of the asymptotical variance, which can be either a sandwich estimator or derived from bootstrapping (see Wooldridge (Reference Wooldridge2010), Ch. 12, 13).

5 Although these derivatives are defined as partial effects from a statistical point, they should not be considered as causal effects, since the changes in covariates cannot be assumed as random.

6 Since the double-hurdle model implements a first-stage Probit regression, then there is a potential problem of estimation error within the second-stage standard errors. Also, as the primary sampling unit is a community cluster, we implement a cluster bootstrap that does resampling at the community level. Hence, the standard errors are robust to cluster correlation and distributional misspecification.

7 Another reading could go along the way of “extension and training decrease total sales,” but we restrain ourselves from making such a claim as there is no exogenous variation to categorize it as that kind of causal effect.

References

Abera, G. “Commercialization of Smallholder Farming: Determinants and Welfare Outcomes. A Cross-sectional Study in Enderta District, Tigrai, Ethiopia.” Master thesis, The University of Agder, Norway, 2009.Google Scholar
Achandi, E.L., and Mujawamariya, G.. “Market Participation by Smallholder Rice Farmers in Tanzania: A Double Hurdle Analysis.” Studies in Agricultural Economics 118,2(2016):112–15.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Alene, A.D., Manyong, V.M., Omanya, G., Mignouna, H.D., Bokanga, M., and Odhiambo, G.. “Smallholder Market Participation under Transactions Costs: Maize Supply and Fertilizer Demand in Kenya.” Food Policy 33,4(2008):318–28.Google Scholar
Barrett, C.B.Smallholder Market Participation: Concepts and Evidence from Eastern and Southern Africa.” Food Policy 33,4(2008):299317.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Barrett, C.B., and Dorosh, P.A.. “Farmers’ WElfare and Changing Food PRices: Nonparametric Evidence from Rice in Madagascar.” American Journal of Agricultural Economics 78,3(1996):656–69.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bauguil, S. “Estudio de la cadena agroalimentaria del arroz en el departamento de Santa Cruz-Bolivia: producción, transformación, comercialización, consumo, comercio exterior y aspectos de apoyo al sector.” Unpublished manuscript, Jean Moulin Lyon 3 University, Lyon, France, 2003.Google Scholar
Bellemare, M., and Barrett, C.B.. “An Ordered Tobit Model of Market Participation: Evidence from Kenya and Ethiopia.” American Journal of Agricultural Economics 88,2(2006):324–37.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Boughton, D., Mather, D., Barrett, C.B., Benfica, R., Abdula, D., Tschirley, D., and Cunguara, B.. “Market Participation by Rural Households in a Low-Income Country: An Asset-Based Approach Applied to Mozambique.” Faith and Economics 50(2007):64101.Google Scholar
Calvo, S. Applying the Growth Diagnostics Approach: The Case of Bolivia. Washington, DC: International Monetary Fund, February 2006.Google Scholar
Cragg, J.Some Statistical Models for Limited Dependent Variables with Application to the Demand for Durable Goods.” Econometrica 39,5(1971):829–44.10.2307/1909582CrossRefGoogle Scholar
De Janvry, A., Fafchamps, M., and Sadoulet, E.. “Peasant Household Behaviour with Missing Markets: Some Paradoxes Explained.” The Economic Journal 101,409(1991):1400–17.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
De Janvry, A., and Sadoulet, E.. “Progress in the Modeling of Rural Households’ Behavior under Market Failures.” Poverty, Inequality and Development. De Janvry, A., and Sadoulet, E.., eds. New York: Springer, 2006.Google Scholar
Degiovanni, V., Martínez, C.P., and Motta, F.. Producción Eco-Eficiente del Arroz en América Latina. Cali, Colombia: International Center for Tropical Agriculture, 2010.Google Scholar
Fafchamps, M.Cash Crop Production, Food PRice Volatility, and Rural Market Integration in the Third World.” American Journal of Agricultural Economics 74,1(1992):90–9.10.2307/1242993CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Filmer, D., and Pritchett, L.H.. “Estimating Wealth Effects without Expenditure Data-or Tears: An Application to Educational Enrollments in States of India.” Demography 38,1(2002):115–32.Google Scholar
Food and Agriculture Organization of the United Nations (FAO). FAOSTAT Statistical Database. Rome, Italy: FAO, 2022. Internet site: http://www.fao.org/faostat/en/ Google Scholar
Gebremedhin, B., and Jaleta, M.. “Commercialization of Smallholders: Does Market Orientation Translate into Market Participation?” Working Paper, International Livestock Research Institute (ILRI), Addis Ababa, Ethiopia, 2010.Google Scholar
Goetz, S.A Selectivity Model of Household Food Marketing Behavior in Sub-Saharan Africa.” American Journal of Agricultural Economics 74,2(1992):444–52.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Heckman, J.J.Sample Selection Bias as a Specification Error.” Econometrica 47,1(1979):153–61.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Holloway, G.J., Barrett, C.B., and Ehui, S.K.. “The Double Hurdle Model in the Presence of Fixed Costs.” Working Paper, Applied Economics and Management, Cornell University, Ithaca, NY, September 2001.Google Scholar
Instituto Nacional de Estadistica (INE). Estadísticas económicas - Agricultura. La Paz, Bolivia: INE, 2023. Internet site: https://www.ine.gob.bo/index.php/estadisticas-economicas/agropecuaria/agricultura-introduccion/ Google Scholar
Jagwe, J., Machethe, C., and Ouma, E.. “Transaction Costs and Smallholder Farmers’ Participation in Banana Markets in the Great Lakes Region of Burundi, Rwanda and the Democratic Republic of Congo.” African Journal of Agricultural and Resource Economics 6,1(2010):302–17.Google Scholar
Key, N., Sadoulet, E., and De Janvry, A.. “Transaction Costs and Agricultural Household Supply Response.” American Journal of Agricultural Economics 82,2(2000):245–59.Google Scholar
Larochelle, C., and Alwang, J.. “Explaining Marketing Strategies among Bolivian Potato Farmers.” Quarterly Journal of International Agriculture 54,3(2015):285308.Google Scholar
Lowe, C.H.Determinants of Maize Marketing Decisions for Smallholder Households in Tanzania.” Ph.D. dissertation, Kansas State University, 2013.Google Scholar
Makhura, M., Kirsten, J.F., and Delgado, C.. “Transaction Costs and Smallholder Participation in the Maize Market in the Northern Province of South Africa.” Paper presented at the Seventh Eastern and Southern Africa Regional Maize Conference, Pretoria, South Africa, February 11–15, 2001.Google Scholar
Markelova, H., Meinzen-Dick, R., Hellin, J., and Dohrn, S.. “Collective Action for Smallholder Market Access.” Food Policy 34,1(2009):17.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Martey, E., Al-Hassan, R.M., and Kuwornu, J.K.. “Commercialization of Smallholder Agriculture in Ghana: A Tobit Regression Analysis.” African Journal of Agricultural Research 7,14(2012):2131–41.Google Scholar
Martinez, J.M., Labarta, R.A., Gonzalez, C., and Lopera, D.C.. “Joint Adoption of Rice Technologies among Bolivian Farmers.” Agricultural and Resource Economics Review 50(2021):252–72.Google Scholar
Mather, D., Boughton, D., and Jayne, T.S.. “Explaining Smallholder Maize Marketing in Southern and Eastern Africa: The Roles of Market Access, Technology and Household Resource Endowments.” Food Policy 43(2013):248–66.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ministerio de Desarrollo Rural y Tierras del Estado Plurinacional de Bolivia (MDRyT). Compendio Agropecuario: Observatorio Agroambiental y Productivo 2012. La Paz, Bolivia: Viceministerio de Desarrollo Rural y Agropecuario, 2012.Google Scholar
Muricho, G., Kasie, M., and Obare, G.. “Determinants of Market Participation Regimes among Smallholder Maize Producers in Kenya.” Paper presented at the International Association of Agricultural Economics Triennial Conference, Milan, Italy, August 9–14, 2015.Google Scholar
Musah, A.B., Bonsu, O.A.Y., and Seini, W.. “Market Participation of Smallholder Maize Farmers in the Upper West Region of Ghana.” African Journal of Agricultural Research 9,31(2014):2427–35.Google Scholar
Mzyece, A.Effect of Buyer Type on Market Participation of Smallholder Farmers in Northern Ghana.” Ph.D. dissertation, Kansas State University, 2016.Google Scholar
Nguyen, V.N., and Tran, D.V.. “Rice in Producing Countries.” FAO Rice Information, vol. 3. Nguyen, V.N., and Tran, D.V.., ed. Rome, Italy: FAO, 2002.Google Scholar
Ohen, S.B., Etuk, E.A., and Onoja, J.A.. “Analysis of Market Participation by Rice Farmers in Southern Nigeria.” Journal of Economics and Sustainable Development 4,7(2013):611.Google Scholar
Olwande, J., and Mathenge, M.. “Market Participation among Poor Rural Households in Kenya.” Paper presented at the International Association of Agricultural Economics Triennial Conference, Foz do Iguazu, Brazil, August 18–24, 2012.Google Scholar
Olwande, J., Smale, M., Mathenge, M.K., Place, F., and Mithöfer, D.. “Agricultural Marketing by Smallholders in Kenya: A Comparison of Maize, Kale and Dairy.” Food Policy 52(2015):2232.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Omamo, S.W.Transport Costs and Smallholder Cropping Choices: An Application to Siaya District, Kenya.” American Journal of Agricultural Economics 80,1(1998):116–23.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Omiti, J., Otieno, D., Nyanamba, T., and McCullough, E.. “Factors Influencing the Intensity of Market Participation by Smallholder Farmers: A Case Study of Rural and Peri-Urban Areas of Kenya.” African Journal of Agricultural and Resource Economics 3,1(2009):5782.Google Scholar
Ortiz, A.I., and Soliz, T.L.. El arroz en Bolivia. Santa Cruz, Bolivia: CIPCA, 2007.Google Scholar
Ouma, E., Jagwe, J., Obare, G.A., and Abele, S.. “Determinants of Smallholder Farmers’ Participation in Banana Markets in Central Africa: The Role of Transaction Costs.” Agricultural Economics 41,2(2010):111–22.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Reyes, B., Donovan, C., Bernsten, R., and Maredia, M.. “Market Participation and Sale of Potatoes by Smallholder Farmers in the Central Highlands of Angola: A Double Hurdle Approach.” Poster presented at the International Association of Agricultural Economics Triennial Conference, Foz do Iguazu, Brazil, August 18–24, 2012.Google Scholar
Sigei, G.Determinants of Market Participation among Small-Scale Pineapple Farmers in Kericho County, Kenya.” Master thesis, Egerton University, 2014.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Taboada, R., Guzmán, R., and Hurtado, J.. “Mejoramiento de arroz en Bolivia: Caracterización de poblaciones y uso del mejoramiento poblacional.” Avances en el mejoramiento poblacional en arroz. E.P. GuimarãesTaboada, R., Guzmán, R., and Hurtado, J.., ed. Santo Antônio de Goiás, Brazil: Embrapa Arroz e Feijão, 2000.Google Scholar
Taboada, R., and Viruez, J.. Personal Communication. Centro de Investigación Agrícola Tropical (CIAT-Bolivia), March 2023.Google Scholar
Timmer, C.P.The Agricultural Transformation.” International Agricultural Development, 3rd Edition. Timmer, C.P., eds. Baltimore, MD: The Johns Hopkins University Press, 1998.Google Scholar
Viruez, J., and Taboada, R.. Producción de arroz en Bolivia: conocimiento técnico para un manejo eficiente y rentable. Santa Cruz, Bolivia: Centro de Investigación Agrícola Tropical and Federación Nacional de Cooperativas Arroceras (FENCA), 2013.Google Scholar
Viruez, J., Yonekura, P., Taboada, R., Borrero, J., and Grenier, C.. “Arroz biofortificado para bolivia - Proyecto Harvestplus.” Reunión Anual del Programa de Cooperación Centroamericana para el Mejoramiento de Cultivos y Animales: Resúmenes. Viruez, J., Yonekura, P., Taboada, R., Borrero, J., and Grenier, C.., ed. San José, Costa Rica: Instituto Nacional de Innovación y Transferencia en Tecnología Agropecuaria, 2016.Google Scholar
White, D.S., Labarta, R.A., and Leguía, E.J.. “Technology Adoption by Resource-Poor Farmers: Considering the Implications of Peak-Season Labor Costs.” Agricultural Systems 85,2(2005):183201.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Woldeyohanes, T., Heckeley, T., and Surry, Y.. “Effect of Off-Farm Income on Smallholder Commercialization: Panel Evidence from Rural Households in Ethiopia.” Agricultural Economics 48,2(2017):207–18.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wooldridge, J.M. Econometric Analysis of Cross Section and Panel Data, 2nd Edition. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press, 2010.Google Scholar
Zanello, G.Mobile Phones and Radios: Effects on Transaction Costs and Market Participation for Households in Northern Ghana.” Journal of Agricultural Economics 63,3(2012):694714.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Figure 0

Table 1. Explanatory variables included in the double-hurdle model of market participation and rice sales of small-scale rice farmers in Eastern Bolivia, 2014

Figure 1

Table 2. Acreage, productivity, and poverty vulnerability of small-scale rice farmers in Eastern Bolivia, 2014

Figure 2

Table 3. Descriptive statistics of variables included in the double-hurdle model of market participation and rice sales of small-scale farmers in Eastern Bolivia, 2014

Figure 3

Table 4. Average partial effects on the probability of market participation and total paddy rice sales from the double-hurdle model for small-scale farmers in Eastern Bolivia, 2014