Hostname: page-component-586b7cd67f-vdxz6 Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-11-26T09:50:50.617Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Benevolent Policies: Bureaucratic Politics and the International Dimensions of Social Policy Expansion

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  05 October 2021

CARMEN JACQUELINE HO*
Affiliation:
University of Guelph, Canada
*
Carmen Jacqueline Ho, Assistant Professor, Department of Political Science, University of Guelph, Canada, [email protected].
Rights & Permissions [Opens in a new window]

Abstract

Research on the welfare state has devoted considerable attention to social policy expansion. However, little is known about why governments expand social policies serving groups with limited power on issues with low visibility. I call these “benevolent policies.” This class of social policies improves population well-being but produces minimal political gains for the governments enacting them. Why do governments expand benevolent policies if political incentives for reform are weak? I investigate this question by focusing on government responses to malnutrition. Drawing on nine months of fieldwork, including 71 interviews, I argue that the origins of policy expansion can be found in the government bureaucracy. Bureaucrats with technical expertise—technocrats—can play a defining role, deploying international pressure to court executive support and orchestrate policy change. Their actions help explain the Indonesian government’s unexpected expansion of nutrition policies, which serve low-income women and children and address micronutrient malnutrition.

Type
Research Article
Creative Commons
Creative Common License - CCCreative Common License - BY
This is an Open Access article, distributed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution licence (http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/), which permits unrestricted re-use, distribution, and reproduction in any medium, provided the original work is properly cited.
Copyright
© The Author(s), 2021. Published by Cambridge University Press on behalf of the American Political Science Association

Why do governments expand social policies? This question is central to our understanding of the welfare state. The existing literature offers two broad explanations for why governments act. First, governments are responding to groups with political power. Governments have incentives to introduce policies that appease groups which can threaten their political survival (Dion Reference Dion2010; Esping-Andersen Reference Esping-Andersen1990; Garay Reference Garay2016; Korpi Reference Korpi1978). Second, governments are addressing visible issues to garner political support or preempt political backlash (Diaz-Cayeros, Estevez, and Magaloni Reference Diaz-Cayeros, Estevez and Magaloni2016; Haggard and Kaufman Reference Haggard and Kaufman2008; Hicken and Simmons Reference Hicken and Simmons2008; Niedzwiecki Reference Niedzwiecki2018; Wong Reference Wong2006; Zucco Reference Zucco2013).

Left unknown is why governments expand social policies for groups with limited political power on issues with low visibility. I call these “benevolent policies,” identifying them as an overlooked class of social policies. Groups with limited power are less able to exert pressure on governments and elicit favorable reform. Issues with low visibility are less likely to be recognized by the public, reducing the likelihood that governments can use them for short-term political gains.

Conventional wisdom suggests that governments do not have strong incentives to expand benevolent policies and are unlikely to do so—yet empirical evidence, which I will discuss, shows there are conditions under which this occurs. I focus on explaining this puzzle.

Emblematic of benevolent policies are nutrition policies.Footnote 1 For women, malnutritionFootnote 2 prior to and during pregnancy is associated with restricted fetal development. In children, evidence links malnutrition to an estimated 3.1 million deaths every year, approximately 45% of global child deaths, primarily in low and middle-income countries (Black et al. Reference Black, Victora, Walker, Bhutta, Christian, de Onis, Ezzati, Grantham-McGregor, Katz and Martorell2013). Yet nutrition policies do not adequately respond to these challenges (WHO 2013). Government inaction, I contend, is a product of weak incentives. The recommended nutrition policies primarily serve a group with limited political power (low-income women and children) and address an issue with low visibility (micronutrient malnutrition), reducing political incentives for policy reform.Footnote 3 Certain governments, however, have defied expectations. This article focuses on Indonesia. After years of ignoring pervasive levels of malnutrition, the Indonesian government suddenly sprang into action and expanded its nutrition policies in 2012.

What explains the expansion of benevolent policies? Existing theories do not offer persuasive explanations. The social policies studied in the welfare state canon—serving groups with political power (e.g., the upper class, unions) or addressing issues with high visibility (e.g., cash transfers, health insurance)—lend themselves to overt, and often contested, forms of redistribution. From this vantage point, policy expansion is a product of conflict among domestic groups, organized to protect or advance their interests, or of a government’s pursuit of political gains. Government bureaucracies are viewed as mere arbiters of competing interests, bureaucrats within them as passive agents.

By contrast, I argue that the origins of benevolent policy reform can be traced to the government bureaucracy. In this article, I show that bureaucrats who have technical expertise in a subject—technocrats—can play a defining role. Technocrats harness the international pressure created by international organizations (IOs) to broaden their political connections within the bureaucracy. They use these connections to build vertical networks and elevate the desired policy onto the executive agenda, then leverage horizontal networks to coordinate policy change.

Contributions

This article makes three contributions. First, I conceptualize a new class of policies—benevolent policies—which the comparative welfare state scholarship has overlooked and undertheorized. While the empirical focus of this article is nutrition policies, the concept travels to any social welfare and public goods policy that serves a group with low power on an issue with low visibility. Examples include policies that serve migrants, refugees, low-income and racialized groups, or policies that address non-communicable diseases, sanitation, long-haul COVID, or water fluoridation, as I will discuss. This article opens up analytical space for studying evidence-based policies that dramatically improve welfare but provide governments with limited short-term political gains.

Second, I draw attention to technocrats as an important catalyst of change. For challenging issues like malnutrition, we tend to think of powerful social movements or vote-seeking politicians as the drivers of change. But technocrats, I argue, and their strategic deployment of international pressure within the bureaucracy, can also act as a source of policy change. While the comparative politics scholarship has “tended to ignore the bureaucracy itself” (Pepinsky, Pierskalla, and Sacks Reference Pepinsky, Pierskalla and Sacks2017, 250), recent research is advancing knowledge on bureaucratic politics (Bersch Reference Bersch2019; Bozcaga Reference Bozcaga2020; Centeno, Kohli, and Yashar Reference Centeno, Kohli and Yashar2017; Ding Reference Ding2020; Kim Reference Kim2020; Toral Reference Toral2021; Utama Reference Utama2014). I join this work by drawing on studies which bring the oft-divorced comparative politics and international relations literatures into conversation (Dion Reference Dion2008; Keck and Sikkink Reference Keck and Sikkink1998; Martínez Franzoni and Sánchez-Ancochea Reference Martínez Franzoni and Sánchez-Ancochea2014; Orenstein Reference Orenstein2013; White Reference White2011), continuing efforts to dissolve boundaries that have traditionally separated subfields.

Third, this work intervenes in a long-standing debate on democracy and welfare. Influential studies have produced contradictory results. Some find that democracy reduces infant mortality (McGuire Reference McGuire2010), whereas others do not (Ross Reference Ross2006). The concept of benevolent policies helps explain this disagreement. I show that democracy’s effects on social policies are not uniform. Although electoral competition contributes to the expansion of policies addressing issues with high visibility, it sidelines issues with low visibility. Studies have primarily documented democracy’s effect on policies for high-visibility issues like cash transfers or health insurance. But the sidelining of low-visibility issues such as micronutrient malnutrition, which contributes to 45% of global child deaths, can explain why democracy produces mixed results.

This article begins by discussing the concept of benevolent policies. These policies improve social welfare but produce minimal political gains for governments enacting them. While governments do not have strong incentives to expand these policies, some have done so. In 2012, the Indonesian government suddenly prioritized nutrition, marshaling resources toward the formulation and introduction of new nutrition policies. This was a break from past behavior. For decades, malnutrition rates remained “stubbornly high” (Rokx, Subandoro, and Gallagher Reference Rokx, Subandoro and Gallagher2018, 19). Despite the availability of simple, low-cost policy solutions, the government did not appear to pay serious attention—until 2012 when it unexpectedly introduced a raft of new policies.

To explain policy expansion, I develop an analytical framework that shines a bright light on the inner workings of the government bureaucracy. After describing my methods, rationale for case selection, and the data collected, I illustrate the analytical framework using the Indonesia case. I conclude by explaining the relevance of the benevolent policies concept for other social policies, then discuss the theoretical contributions of this article and an agenda for future research.

BENEVOLENT POLICIES

In this article, I introduce the concept of “benevolent policies” to explain why governments fail to tackle serious societal problems. I use the term, “benevolent,” to refer to acts that improve welfare but produce limited short-term political gains. The term is slippery, however, given the myriad of ways in which it can be used. In certain contexts, it conjures up images of a paternalistic state, guiding the supposedly misguided. In other settings, it is bound up with histories of racism and colonialism, reminiscent of the imperial impulse and so-called civilizing missions that occurred under the benevolent Western gaze.

I use the term, benevolent, as a reference to the benevolent dictator who acts for the benefit of her people rather than her own personal betterment. Benevolent policies advance citizen well-being, not just a government’s short-term political interests. Reflecting this, scholars have used the concept of a “benevolent state” to refer to governments that “act out of a primary concern for the welfare of all its citizens” and use “policies … to find solutions to recognized social problems” (Marcuse Reference Marcuse1978, 21).

Good Policies, Bad Politics

Benevolent policies have two core characteristics: they serve groups with limited power and address issues with low visibility. These policies improve welfare and well-being. But in comparison with policies that serve groups with high power or address issues with high visibility, benevolent policies produce limited short-term political gains for the government. These policies cannot easily be used to win votes, reward supporters, anchor coalitions, enhance government legitimacy, or ease popular discontent. The gains accrue to beneficiaries, a group with limited power, not the government enacting them. Moreover, welfare improvements take years to become apparent, limiting the government’s ability to claim credit for positive outcomes. These are good policies—but bad politics.

As there are an infinite number of groups to serve and issues to address but a finite amount of resources, governments must prioritize. Given their desire to continue governing, governments have strong incentives to serve groups with high power and address issues with high visibility, as I will explain.

The Group: Political Power and Policy Expansion

The “group” refers to two or more individuals who share a common characteristic. The group’s political power is shaped by its access to resources. These resources, whether they be funds, capital assets, or political connections, provide the group with greater influence over the government’s political survival.

Governments have strong incentives to respond to groups with significant resources (Ramesh Reference Ramesh2000), often governing on behalf of the powerful rather than the people. In the United States, the government has accommodated the demands of the upper class, resulting in a welfare state that “showers its benefits far more generously on the haves than on the have-nots” (Mettler Reference Mettler2011, 25). Similarly, in Uganda, the government has channeled favors to groups whose support they wish to secure (Mwenda and Tangri Reference Mwenda and Tangri2005).

A group’s political power can be augmented through collective action and social mobilization (Díez Reference Díez2013). When “marginalized groups are incorporated into the political arena and possess mobilizing power, there is greater pressure on the state to respond to their needs and expand social protection policy” (Pribble Reference Pribble2011, 194). In Sweden, the government responded to blue-collar workers who, organizing through labor unions, used strikes and protests to exert their political power (Korpi Reference Korpi1978). In Argentina, the government expanded social policies for unemployed and informal workers when they organized roadblocks and demonstrations (Garay Reference Garay2007). The government is more likely to attend to groups that have mobilized and can threaten its survival.

The most “pressing problems” are those that are “forced on the policymakers through pressure from injured or interested outside parties” (Hirschman Reference Hirschman1981, 146). These outside parties, however, vary in power, and social policies reflect the relative strength of different interest groups (Mesa-Lago Reference Mesa-Lago1978). It is domestic societal pressures emanating from groups with high power—that is, groups with access to substantial resources or the ability to coordinate large-scale collective action—that demand government attention and policy action. When a group has high political power, there is a need to appease it or, at the very least, avoid provoking its ire. For this reason, governments have strong incentives to prioritize groups with power.

The Issue: Visibility and Policy Expansion

The “issue” is the social problem that exists in society. The issue’s visibility is reflected by the public’s awareness of the issue or the public’s awareness of the government response.Footnote 4 The more immediate the consequences of the issue or the government response, the higher the public’s level of awareness. For example, crises such as earthquakes and nuclear power plant accidents, which have immediate consequences, often precipitate policy action (Birkland Reference Birkland1998). The public is very aware of the issue and the government’s role in remedying it.

Governments have strong incentives to address issues with high visibility. For social policies, an example is economic poverty. People know when they lack access to money and that the consequences can quickly result in deprivations such as hunger or homelessness. When governments expand social policies, such as conditional cash transfers (CCTs), the public sees the benefits of government action right away. For this reason, CCTs “with clear attribution of responsibility have provided electoral advantages to incumbent presidents” in Latin America (Niedzwiecki Reference Niedzwiecki2018, 12). Indeed, “the immediate electoral rewards to incumbents who implement and expand programs can entice rulers around the world to adopt CCTs” (Zucco Reference Zucco2013, 811).

In addition to cash transfers, governments have used other social policies to garner political support (Diaz-Cayeros, Estevez, and Magaloni Reference Diaz-Cayeros, Estevez and Magaloni2016). Following democratization, governments in Korea and Taiwan had strong incentives to extend health insurance to the broader citizenry, as everyday citizens had gained the ability to vote (Wong Reference Wong2006). Similarly, in Malawi, the government garnered political support by addressing food insecurity and expanding agricultural subsidies (Dionne and Horowitz Reference Dionne and Horowitz2016). In Tanzania, the government improved political approval because of its efforts to address malaria through bed net distribution (Croke Reference Croke2021).

Governments have also used social policies strategically, introducing reforms to preempt popular discontent. For instance, “social insurance in the early Latin American adopters” was “initiated by political elites who pre-empted the pressures for reform with policies aimed at diverting labor from radical demands” (Malloy Reference Malloy1989, 319).

Of its arsenal of social policies, governments have incentives to prioritize those that address high, rather than low, visibility issues. Like clientelistic exchanges, where politicians rely on the distribution of particularistic benefits rather than public goods to win office (Mares and Young Reference Mares and Young2018), social policies are politically useful when the recipient is aware of the issue addressed, or the government response. Therefore, governments are better positioned to garner political support or preempt discontent when they expand policies addressing high-visibility issues.

The Puzzle of Nutrition Policies

Unlike policies studied in the welfare state canon—which serve groups with high political power or address issues with high visibility—benevolent policies are a separate class of social policies. They serve groups with limited power on issues with low visibility. To be sure, a group’s level of power and an issue’s visibility are not set in stone. A group can augment its power if it gains access additional resources or effectively mobilizes. Similarly, an issue’s visibility can change. Advocates can launch information campaigns to increase awareness of an issue. An incumbent government can draw attention to its role in introducing policies the public may not previously have been aware of.

However, benevolent policies serve groups and address issues before political action is taken—when the group has low power and the issue has low visibility. Nutrition policiesFootnote 5 are a classic example. Chronic malnutrition affects 149.2 million children worldwide (UNICEF/WHO/World Bank 2021). To address the issue, nutrition expertsFootnote 6 have drawn upon scientific evidence and recommended that governments introduce nutrition policies which serve low-income women and children (a group with low political power) and address micronutrient malnutrition (an issue with low visibility.

For the poor, the hardship of economic adversity, including the sheer mental and physical exhaustion accompanying life at the margins, constrains their ability to demand government action (Thawnghmung Reference Thawnghmung2019). Concerned with daily survival, they rely on piecemeal responses rather than on organized approaches. Indeed, a history of inadequate access to social services can give way to “diminished expectations” reducing the likelihood that the poor organize (Holland Reference Holland2018).

At the same time, many low-income women and children work in the informal sector in Asia, Africa, Latin America, and the Middle East, taking jobs as domestic helpers or street vendors, for example. Informal workers are occupationally diverse and geographically dispersed, reducing their opportunities to organize and gain political power.

While there have been instances of women and informal workers mobilizing (Garay Reference Garay2007), this has occurred around visible issues. By contrast, low-visibility issues, such as micronutrient malnutrition, do not serve as effective rallying points. Micronutrients are essential vitamins and minerals such as iodine, Vitamin A, iron, and folate. Micronutrient malnutrition—the inadequate intake of essential vitamins and minerals—is commonly called “hidden hunger” or an “invisible” issue (Haddad Reference Haddad2013; Semba Reference Semba2012).

Often people do not know their diet is insufficient. They might eat starchy staples, such as rice or potatoes, which provide the calories to stave off hunger but not the essential vitamins and minerals they need. As micronutrient malnutrition only becomes apparent when the problem is severe, accumulating over long periods, deficiencies can cause impairments but remain undetected. As a result, low-income women and children are unlikely to mobilize and demand improved nutrition policies.

Nutrition experts have developed effective interventions (Zlotkin et al. Reference Zlotkin2005) and identified optimal delivery methods (Baxter et al. Reference Baxter, Roth, Mahmud, Ahmed, Islam and Zlotkin2014). However, governments will not necessarily adopt evidence-based recommendations. This is, in part, because the public is not typically aware of the government’s role in improving micronutrient intake. For example, governments can introduce an iodized salt policy, adding iodine to pregnant women’s diets, thus preventing irreversible physical and cognitive impairments in their children. However, the public does not often link government policies like salt iodization to their well-being. As it can take years to reap the benefits of nutrition interventions, governments are less able to claim credit for improving outcomes. In effect, the “costs of reforms are prompt and clear” but the “political rewards are delayed and uncertain” (Nelson Reference Nelson, Kaufman and Nelson2004, 31).

Benevolent policies, such as nutrition policies, might be categorized as “easy” redistribution because they are fiscally cheap and politically uncontested (Holland and Schneider Reference Holland and Schneider2017). But expanding these policies is, in practice, hard as governments lack strong incentives to pursue reform. The public does not mobilize to demand expanded policies, and governments cannot use these policies to garner short-term political gains. If public policy is “whatever governments choose to do or not do” (Dye Reference Dye1972, 18) then benevolent policies shed light on government inaction—the less studied aspect of public policy.

Yet certain governments have expanded benevolent policies, despite the absence of powerful groups agitating for reform or strong political incentives to pursue change. What explains this?

EXPLAINING POLICY EXPANSION

Policy expansion refers to intentional effort on behalf of the government to redress past omissions or address emerging problems. The government places the problem on the policy agenda, formulates new policy, and then issues the new or revised policy. For benevolent policies, where domestic societal pressures are weak, there is a need to “bring the state back in” to understand policy reform (Skocpol Reference Skocpol, Evans, Rueschemeyer and Skocpol1985). My work builds on classic scholarship on bureaucratic politics to carry out this analysis (Grindle and Thomas Reference Grindle and Thomas1991; Heclo Reference Heclo1974; Orloff and Skocpol Reference Orloff and Skocpol1984; Rothstein Reference Rothstein1998).

Government bureaucracies are increasingly staffed by technocrats—bureaucrats who have expertise in specific subjects. Technocrats have training in areas such as nutrition, computer science, economics, and education. Their professional training influences their ideologies. These ideas are powerful, shaping what they perceive as problems and appropriate solutions. Their ideologies become a guiding force behind their actions, motivating them to pursue specific policies. Their professional training also shapes their networks, connecting them with knowledge-based experts in IOs, as well as universities and nongovernmental organizations (Haas Reference Haas1992).

In Brazil, computer science professionals were supported by fellowships and grants for overseas graduate training in the 1970s. After returning home, they joined the government and “for the sake of their ideas and ideology, elected to act as political and ideological ‘guerrillas’ within public institutions” (Adler Reference Adler1986, 677). They sought to place their ideas on high-level agendas, ultimately leading Brazil to develop its domestic computer policy. In Chile, economics students were offered the opportunity to take courses at the University of Chicago in the 1950s and 60s. They returned to Chile, convinced that a competitive free market economy was the solution to developmental problems. The ideologically driven Chicago Boys, a group of neoliberal technocrats, designed economic policy during the Pinochet era (Silva Reference Silva1991).

Technocrats, such as the guerillas in Brazil or Chicago Boys in Chile, fight for their ideas. These ideas, however, “do not float freely” (Risse Reference Risse1994). Technocrats’ ability to influence government policy comes not from the merits of their proposed policies or the strength of their convictions but, rather, from their access to executive decision makers, such as the head of state. Policy making is inherently political and what becomes policy must be examined in the context of power.

From the lower echelons of government, to mid-level management, to cabinet level positions, technocrats can be found throughout the bureaucracy. It is the latter, with their access to executive decision makers, who are best positioned to influence policy. In Brazil, the guerillas succeeded in influencing policy when their commission was placed in the Ministry of Planning, which had direct links to the president (Adler Reference Adler1986). In Chile, the Chicago Boys were able to shape policy because they were senior members of government who enjoyed the support of the president (Silva Reference Silva1991).

Technocrats may believe policy expansion is needed, but in the absence of political connections, it is unlikely that they can turn their ideas into policy. Executive support is essential for policy reform (Martínez Franzoni and Sánchez-Ancochea Reference Martínez Franzoni and Sánchez-Ancochea2014; Rosenberg Reference Rosenberg1979). This is especially true for benevolent policies. And like social policies more broadly, benevolent policies address “wicked problems,” which “require substantially greater coordination efforts than do relatively tame problems that fall neatly into the domain of a single government organization” (Peters Reference Peters2018, 2). Education policies, for example, work best if students can access transportation to school and job opportunities after graduation. Similarly, the Ministry of Health must harmonize nutrition policies with agricultural and education efforts. Therefore, to pursue policy expansion, technocrats must convince actors in the executive office, as well as relevant ministries, to mobilize for reform.

I argue that once in their positions, technocrats continue to fight for their ideas, even in the face of opposition. Indeed technocratic expertise in the bureaucracy has long policy legacies (Pierson Reference Pierson2000). Technocrats will continue to advocate and train new generations to push for policy change. In the absence of direct access to executive decision makers, they will devise alternative methods to gain the ear of executive decision makers.

One strategy, which I highlight in this article, is the use of international pressure to construct a broader coalition that incorporates well-connected government officials into policy efforts. The coalition, with both expert knowledge and political connections, builds vertical networks to court leadership support. Executive support augments the coalition’s power within the bureaucracy. The coalition uses this power, along with its horizontal networks, to pressure other ministries into cooperation. I show how this process of internal constituency buildingFootnote 7 facilitates policy expansion by introducing an analytical framework that looks outside the state, then inside the bureaucracy.

Looking Outside the State: International Organizations

Constructivist research shows how IOs use social processes to shape domestic policies (Avant, Finnemore, and Sell Reference Avant, Finnemore and Sell2010; Dobbin, Simmons, and Garrett Reference Dobbin, Simmons and Garrett2007; Risse, Ropp, and Sikkink Reference Risse, Ropp and Sikkink1999). For instance, IOs organize international meetings such as conferences, workshops, and forums. At these meetings, IOs put forward a core set of ideas that emphasize the need for governments to prioritize specific issues and policy solutions (Dion Reference Dion2008; Weyland Reference Weyland2004). IOs assess governments on their fidelity to the recommended policies. Governments that adopt the policies receive praise, while those that do not are shamed, stoking reputational concerns (Kelley and Simmons Reference Kelley and Simmons2015).

These processes of socialization can lead to policy change. For example, the United Nations Educational, Scientific, and Cultural Organization’s efforts led to a wave of governments adopting new science policies, despite the absence of domestic demand for reform. The IO “took up science policy as a cause and… ‘taught’ states the value and utility of science policy organizations” (Finnemore Reference Finnemore1993, 566). Similarly, I draw attention to the role of socialization.

However, I am not making the case for IOs as teachers of norms. Rather, I argue that IOs, through their efforts at socialization, serve as “coalition magnets” (Béland and Cox Reference Béland and Cox2016) when there is “congruence” between IOs’ efforts and technocrats’ agendas (Acharya Reference Acharya2004).

The term, “coalition,” typically refers to coordination between different groups to achieve a common goal (Kwon Reference Kwon2007; Nam Reference Nam2015). For example, transnational advocacy networks have built new links between actors in civil society and IOs (Keck and Sikkink Reference Keck and Sikkink1998). Similarly, human rights norms have facilitated the mobilization of both domestic and international groups (Black Reference Black, Thomas, Ropp and Sikkink1999). However, I modify the definition of coalition to refer to coordination between individuals of the same group. The coalition I describe in this article is primarily composed of actors within the government bureaucracy.

IOs draw attention to a range of policies. Their efforts are especially important for benevolent policies, where domestic pressures for policy expansion are weak. But IOs do not drive the domestic agenda. Instead, IOs’ efforts at socialization serve as the focal point around which technocrats coalesce and mobilize like-minded individuals within the government bureaucracy. These individuals believe that policy expansion is needed, but their experiences have taught them that technical knowledge alone cannot facilitate reform.Footnote 8 They view international pressure as an opportunity to advance their agenda and use it to integrate knowledge-based experts from their formal and informal networks into their efforts.

Meanwhile, IOs are inviting high-ranking government officials to international meetings, with the purpose of socializing these individuals. Technocrats follow up with government officials and bring them into their network. I call this group “the coalition.”

Looking Inside the Bureaucracy: The Coalition

In this scenario, technocrats are no longer acting alone. IOs have articulated similar ideas, granting legitimacy to their calls for policy expansion. Technocrats strategically deploy international pressure to facilitate the construction of a coalition, broadening the network of actors within the government bureaucracy involved in their cause. I emphasize the centrality of these networks, which encompass both formal and informal linkages, to explain policy expansion (Lee and Goodman Reference Lee, Goodman, Lee, Buse and Fustukian2001). These include vertical networks, which connect technocrats to executive decision makers, and horizontal networks, which cut across ministries.

The coalition leverages international pressure, in conjunction with its expanded networks, to gain the support of executive decision makers. Studies have documented the use of this strategy by activists outside the government. For example, the Council of Europe (CoE) sought to push governments to change their views of citizenship and minority rights. German activists, who shared the CoE’s ambitions, used CoE efforts as a “tool for generating pressure on political elites in Bonn” (Checkel Reference Checkel1999, 105).

Similarly, the coalition uses IO efforts to place pressure on executive decision makers within their own government. As social policy issues “in health and education can rarely capitalize on a sense of urgency” (Kaufman and Nelson Reference Kaufman and Nelson2004, 13), international pressure becomes a tool for insisting on immediate action. The coalition draws upon its political connections to set up meetings with executive decision makers. Citing international scrutiny and reputational concerns, the goal is to get the head of state’s support in policy expansion.

Executive support signals that policy expansion is a priority (Grindle Reference Grindle2004). The coalition then uses executive decision makers’ commitment to policy expansion, in conjunction with international pressure, to create a sense of urgency for reform and demand interministerial cooperation.

This is a dynamic process, shaped by interactions over time. IOs play a role in structuring the international environment, but their efforts alone do not decisively create new domestic policies. Their attempts at socialization may draw attention to the importance of certain policies, but the extent to which this leads to policy change is constrained by the domestic context. It is technocrats, who work inside the bureaucracy and understand the complexities of the policy-making process, who play a crucial role in facilitating coordination within the bureaucracy (Figure 1).

Figure 1. Analytical Framework

Here, I lay out the scope conditions for the analytical framework, specifying the conditions under which it has more, or less, explanatory power. For benevolent policies, policy expansion is likely to have its origins in the bureaucracy, given that domestic societal pressures are weak. Technocrats who believe there is a need for reform play a critical role. They are better positioned to facilitate policy expansion when they have access to executive decision makers. In the absence of direct access to leadership, technocrats can devise alternative methods for obtaining leadership support, such as constructing a coalition with politically connected members. This is true for all welfare states, truncated or not.

However, technocrats are more likely to emerge and wield influence in certain contexts. When a bureaucracy is staffed by highly trained technocrats with long-term careers, they are more likely to emerge to champion reform. Their higher level of training provides them with the skills needed to identify and address societal problems while also socializing them into a certain way of thinking. There is an increased chance that they belong to the same knowledge-based communities as their IO counterparts. This overlap increases the likelihood that technocrats share similar ideologies and view IO efforts as “congruent” with their own agendas. With extended time horizons, these technocrats see the value of benevolent policies, which pay off in the long run. These technocrats are better able to use IO pressure to garner executive attention if governments are, or recently have been, foreign aid recipients. Governments that have accepted aid are enmeshed in complex relationships with IOs and thus more susceptible to external influence.

METHODS, CASE SELECTION, AND DATA

This article uses the case study method to explain policy expansion. While large-n studies have the advantage of generalizability, case studies are “particularly useful in explaining cases that do not fit an existing theory, in order to explain why the case violates theoretical predictions and to refine or replace an existing hypothesis” (Levy Reference Levy2008, 5). As benevolent policies have been overlooked in the literature, hiding in plain sight, I use the intensive study of a single case to carry out theory building.

The Indonesian government, and its sudden introduction of new nutrition policies, is the ideal case to study. Conventional explanations—including theories of industrialism, democracy, and the power resource theory—do not offer persuasive accounts for the policy expansion that took place in 2012.

Studies that fall under the broad umbrella of industrialism suggest that economic growth occurs in tandem with the expansion of social policies (Rimlinger Reference Rimlinger1971; Wilensky Reference Wilensky1974). But while the Indonesian government experienced rapid economic growth from 2000 onward, nutrition policies remained inadequate. For more than a decade, the government had the resources to address malnutrition but did not take significant policy action. This suggests that economic growth was not responsible for reform.

Another prominent strand of literature links democracy to the expansion of the welfare state (Haggard and Kaufman Reference Haggard and Kaufman2008; McGuire Reference McGuire2010; Wong Reference Wong2006). Electoral competition creates incentives for policy makers to respond to low-income citizens’ needs, facilitating the expansion of redistributive policies. However, democracy does not change a government’s incentive to address issues with low visibility. In the 2000s, Indonesia’s democratization was accompanied by the expansion of pro-poor policies—but also an intensified focus on visible issues. The government prioritized policies with electoral returns such as cash transfers. Although these could indirectly improve nutrition, the focus on visible issues sidelined micronutrient malnutrition. Therefore, theories of democracy cannot explain policy expansion.

Another body of research, organized around the power resource theory, links partisan ideology to policy expansion (Esping-Andersen Reference Esping-Andersen1990; Korpi Reference Korpi1978). In the 2000s, the “left turn” in Latin America was accompanied by the expansion of social policies, suggesting that left-leaning parties had a decisive influence on the introduction of redistributive policies (Huber and Stephens Reference Huber and Stephens2012). However, the left–right divide is largely imperceptible among Indonesian political parties (Fossati et al. Reference Fossati, Aspinall, Muhtadi and Warburton2020). Another element of the theory links union mobilization to reform. In Indonesia, however, poor women and children often work in the informal sector and are unlikely to unionize, reducing the power resource theory’s analytical purchase.

To investigate alternative drivers of policy change, I carry out inductive process tracing, using empirical observations to derive propositions and formulate sequences (Hall Reference Hall2013). This approach is “often used for the purpose of theory development through the identification of key events and through the specification of hypotheses about how these events connect together” (Falleti and Mahoney Reference Falleti, Mahoney, James and Thelen2015, 229).

This article’s primary data draw upon nine months of fieldwork conducted during 2014–16 as part of a broader research project on the politics of welfare state expansion.Footnote 9 I carried out 71 in-depth, semistructured interviews in Jakarta, Indonesia (2015) as well as Bangkok, Thailand (2014), Manila, Philippines (2015), Phnom Penh, Cambodia (2016), and Vientiane, Laos (2016). This process involved speaking with policy makers in governments, nutrition specialists affiliated with IOs, and representatives from civil society on the nutrition policy-making process. I interviewed individuals from groups with varying mandates to verify claims. In addition, I carried out informal observations in the nutrition section of an IO over three months (2014) and at three closed-door regional nutrition meetings in Southeast Asia (2014-15), observing interactions between representatives from governments, IOs, and civil society. In the next section, I draw upon these data to show how technocrats facilitate policy expansion.

NUTRITION POLICIES IN INDONESIA

In the late 1800s, a mysterious illness was ravaging the Asia Pacific region. Beriberi, which affects the cardiovascular and nervous system, was initially thought to be an infectious disease. Fearing threats to its colony, the Dutch government sent scientists to Indonesia to investigate. They discovered that beriberi was the result of a vitamin deficiency, not a pathogen.Footnote 10 This finding propelled Indonesia’s program of research in nutrition forward. The Special Institute for Nutrition Research was established in Indonesia, providing advice to the government. The Institute carried out the nutrition program for the Ministry of Health in the 1950s and later became a division of the national government. Around this time, Indonesian universities began adding nutrition sciences to their curriculum, increasing the country’s technical capacity.

More broadly, opportunities for advanced training would continue to grow in Indonesia. The Ford Foundation, for example, began sending students overseas and many studied economics at the University of California at Berkeley. By the early 1960s, these students returned to Indonesia. They took up academic positions and later, positions in the government where they would become known as the Berkeley Mafia.

In 1967, after a bloody power struggle, General Suharto became president of Indonesia, ushering in a period of authoritarian rule. To modernize the bureaucracy and respond to development challenges, technocrats came to the fore of his New Order regime. To be sure, this did not turn the bureaucracy into an apolitical institution. Nor did it result in a policy-making process free from corruption. But as part of “a wish to ‘catch up’ with the West,” the government sought to develop technical expertise and was supported by donors such as the World Bank and International Monetary Fund (Wicaksono Reference Wicaksono2018, 631).

In the authoritarian New Order government, the Berkeley Mafia held key ministerial positions, heavily influencing policy. Widjojo Nitisastro, the most prominent member of the Berkeley Mafia and one of Suharto’s most trusted advisors, was appointed head of Bappenas (the National Planning Agency).Footnote 11 Bappenas was a powerful agency, holding unassailable authority over development planning and budgeting. There, Nitisastro established an intergenerational network of technocrats. Indonesian students, including those specializing in nutrition, continued to study abroad, and upon their return they joined universities and the government.

Policy Expansion in the 1970s

The expansion of nutrition policies in the 1970s illustrates how Nitisastro, who supported nutrition policies and had access to the president, shaped policy reform. While Nitisastro was a market-oriented economist, he nevertheless advocated for government intervention to achieve development goals (Chalmers Reference Chalmers, Vedi and Chalmers1997). In his keynote speech at the National Institute of Sciences in 1970, he declared “we must not operate under the illusion that economic development will in itself cause development in other sectors” and indicated there was a need for the government to expand social policies (Soekirman Reference Arsjad Anwar, Ananta and Kuncoro2008).

At Nitisastro’s instruction, nutrition was included in national development planning in 1978 (Soekirman Reference Arsjad Anwar, Ananta and Kuncoro2008). In 1979, the government expanded its nutrition policies, introducing the Family Nutrition Improvement Program (Usaha Perbaikan Gizi Keluarga or UPGK). Many of the program’s interventions, such as vitamin A supplementation, iron-folate tablets, and nutrition education and counseling, produced limited short-term political gains.

Policy expansion, then, can be traced to the executive support.Footnote 12 Technocrats in Bappenas advocated for the introduction of nutrition programs (Heaver Reference Heaver2005). And these technocrats, especially “top decision makers from Bappenas,” were crucial for establishing “an interministerial national program in nutrition” (Rohde and Hendrata Reference Rohde, Hendrata, Scrimshaw and Wallerstein1982, 227). Reflecting on this, a technocrat working in the bureaucracy in the 1970s noted the importance of Nitisastro’s connections to the president for elevating nutrition on the government agenda (Table 1).Footnote 13 The Family Nutrition Improvement Program continued until the 1990s.

Table 1. Periods of Nutrition Policy Expansion and Retrenchment in Indonesia

Policy Retrenchment in the 1990s and 2000s

In 1993, Suharto announced the sixth development cabinet. The leadership of BappenasFootnote 14 as well as several ministerial posts, previously held by Nitisastro’s protégés, were taken over by individuals who sympathized with Bacharuddin Jusuf Habibie’s ideas on development. Habibie had held a number of key bureaucratic positions in the Indonesian government and had a close personal relationship with the president (Amir Reference Amir2008).

In contrast to Nitisastro, Habibie was an aeronautic engineer by training and placed industrial sectors at the core of development. But “concentrating on high-technology development inevitably entails marginalizing the development of other sectors more beneficial for the populace as a whole” and this “failed to address social issues such as poverty and unemployment” (Amir Reference Amir2008, 320).

In 1997, Indonesia was hit by a massive currency depreciation. As the economy plummeted, the government had no choice but to accept IO loans and the accompanying policies, including social safety nets. The government introduced the JPS program (Jaring Pengaman Sosial), a social safety net program, with the World Bank, Asian Development Bank, and bilateral donors providing budget and program support (Sumarto, Suryahadi, and Widyanti Reference Sumarto, Suryahadi and Widyanti2002). The JPS program was intended to mitigate the adverse effects of the crisis including poverty, unemployment, and malnutrition. However, nutrition efforts largely ignored micronutrient intake. Indeed, the “inclusion of too many other health issues may have diluted the nutrition interventions” (WHO 2012).

Amidst mass protests, Suharto resigned as Indonesia’s president in 1998, handing over office to Habibie. This marked the country’s transition to a democratic system of governance. By this time, the executive decision makers who had supported nutrition policies had been replaced or were losing power. Nitisastro’s last formal position with the government’s Economics Assistance Team ended in 2001 (Table 1).

At the same time, democracy, long hailed for its potential to facilitate the expansion of the welfare state, was not pushing nutrition policies to the forefront of Indonesia’s policy agenda but was instead sidelining it. While the extension of the voting franchise increased the power of low-income groups, it sidelined low-visibility issues. Politicians had a better chance at securing office if they addressed high-visibility issues, and they relied on policies like JPS and cash transfers. JPS was “a key plank” in Habibie’s attempt “to survive politically … at a time when the first post-Suharto elections were looming” (Aspinall Reference Aspinall2014, 812). The following two administrationsFootnote 15 continued to reach out to poor voters in the same way, as low-income groups favored parties that demonstrated concern for social welfare (Mujani and Liddle Reference Mujani and Liddle2010).

In the 2009 elections, Susilo Bambang Yudhoyono, the then president, campaigned for reelection on a pro-poor platform. It was “the introduction of massive cash programs for the poor that triggered Yudhoyono’s meteoric rise from electoral underdog to almost unassailable frontrunner” in 2009 (Mietzner Reference Mietzner2009, 4). Even as the economy rebounded and began to skyrocket, social policies focused on high-visibility issues.

The Indonesian economy rumbled along on high for years. Yet amidst significant economic growth and poverty reduction, malnutrition persisted. According to the World Bank (2021), 42.4% of children in the newly democratized country were affected by chronic malnutrition in 2000, as measured by rates of stunting (low height-for-age; Figure 2). A decade later, the numbers had hardly improved and 39.2% of children were malnourished in 2010.

Figure 2. Prevalence of Stunting among Children under the Age of Five in Indonesia

Note: Source: World Bank 2021.Footnote 17

As nutrition policies had not reemerged as a political priority, observers remained concerned. “Progress on reducing stunting rates has not been as good as on other social development indicators in Indonesia,” they lamented (Rokx, Subandoro, and Gallagher Reference Rokx, Subandoro and Gallagher2018, 19). In the scramble to introduce policies that would secure political office, nutrition policies had been left behind.

The UNICEF office in Indonesia observed that malnutrition remained a stubborn issue, in part because “stunting and maternal nutrition are not easily visible. People are generally not aware that malnutrition is a problem” (UNICEF Indonesia 2012, 2). This made it difficult to get the issue onto the national agenda. In interviews conducted in 2015, interviewees agreed, attributing the difficulty of getting nutrition policies prioritized to low visibility. As a technocrat explained,

Nutrition problems is unseen. If someone suffers from anemia, we cannot see it right? This is why [the] nutrition problem is so difficult… . We are struggling to convince everyone that nutrition is very important.Footnote 16

As emphasis shifted to visible health policies, nutrition policies fell to the wayside. This, I contend, contributed to the dismantling of Indonesia’s Family Nutrition Improvement Program. The program was provided by the posyandu (Pos Pelayanan Terpadu), the Integrated Health Service Post in Indonesia. The posyandu provides services for basic maternal and child health, including nutrition services. While the number of health posts grew by 15% in the years following democratization, between 2000 and 2006 (Chaparro, Oot, and Sethuraman Reference Chaparro, Oot and Sethuraman2014), Indonesia’s Family Nutrition Improvement Plan was gradually removed (WHO 2012). As another technocrat explained,

You previously had the posyandu focused on nutrition… . Then the role of nutrition interventions in posyandu became … limited to just growth monitoring… . The [nutrition] promotion aspect, the counseling, got dropped off in the busyness of trying to immunize these kids, get them weighed. The actual [nutrition] counseling part, which is the most important part, got dropped.Footnote 18

Nutrition programming, with its low visibility, was slowly dismantled and replaced by more visible health services. And because technocrats advocating for nutrition no longer had the ear of the president, malnutrition continued to persist on a large scale. Government attention never reached the same levels as in the 1970s. Commenting on this, an employee of a bilateral donor in Indonesia observed that since democratization, “everything has stalled.”Footnote 19

Policy Expansion in 2012

Against this backdrop, technocrats trained in nutrition continued to advocate for policy expansion.Footnote 20 But nutrition did not become a priority on the government agenda, even as the Indonesian economy recovered from the economic crisis and began to grow rapidly. It was not until IOs began concerted efforts to draw attention to malnutrition that the Indonesian government again expanded its nutrition policies.

In 2010, the World Bank introduced the Scaling Up Nutrition Framework for Action at its spring meetings in Washington, DC. This laid the foundation for the “Scaling Up Nutrition” movement (SUN). IOs, including the World Bank, UNICEF, WHO, and Food and Agriculture Organization (FAO), renewed their efforts to pressure governments to expand nutrition policies.

Operating under the auspices of the UN, SUN began recruiting governments to join the movement and commit to “developing or revising national policies, strategies and plans to scale up nutrition” (SUN 2018, para. 3). Indonesian technocrats saw this as an opportunity to advance their agenda. They had been pushing for the prioritization of nutrition for years, yet it continued to be sidelined.

SUN does not have legal status, nor does it provide financial resources to governments that commit to policy reform. Instead, SUN places pressure on governments by drawing attention to the need for expanded policies that serve poor women and children and address micronutrient malnutrition. In 2011, SUN organized a meeting at the United Nations General Assembly in the United States, emphasizing the prevalence of malnutrition and the need for government action (SUN 2011). Over the next few years, their efforts would build to a crescendo.

Indonesian technocrats coalesced around SUN and began reaching out to individuals sympathetic to their cause within the bureaucracy. They formed a coalition, calling themselves “the Sunners.”Footnote 21 Over time, the coalition began to gain attention. Within the bureaucracy, Indonesian technocrats working on social policies, but not specifically on nutrition, acknowledged the emergence of the coalition.Footnote 22 Outside the bureaucracy, representatives working for an IO in Thailand,Footnote 23 in addition to nutrition consultants based in the US, observed how the coalition had formed in response to SUN.Footnote 24 A Sunner, whose early calls for nutrition reform had gone unheeded said, “nutrition in a country is influenced by the world and its perceptions of the issue,” and “now, we have started moving, because of the international.”Footnote 25

Central to the Sunners’ plan for policy reform was convincing the president to join SUN. However, the Sunners did not have direct access to him. To reach the president, a Sunner drew on her connection to the Minister of Health, Endang Rahayu Sedyaningsih, who had attended the 2011 SUN meeting. As the Sunner explained,

A couple of months after that [the 2011 SUN meeting], I met her [the Minister of Health] and I asked her whether we will participate in the SUN movement or not. She said, “yes, we will.” But at that time she was not sure how we could send the interest to the SUN Global Secretariat… . So we waited for a while and then we met again. And again, I asked her whether she is willing to write a letter to the UN.Footnote 26

The Sunner kept pressing the Minister of Health. Eventually, the Minister of Health agreed and obtained approval from the President, who sent “the letter to Sec-Gen Ban Ki Moon, saying that Indonesia was willing to be part of the movement.”Footnote 27 After the letter was sent to the Secretary-General, a Sunner said, “I initiated a meeting of the senior nutritionists in Indonesia and I said to them we need to establish a policy framework. We cannot only involve in the movement without having a policy framework in place.” She used Indonesia’s commitment to SUN to divert resources to the formulation of new nutrition policies. As the Sunners gained momentum, the coalition grew to include Indonesians based at universities and nongovernmental organizations.

The Sunners were keen to demonstrate progress to IOs. This was especially true for policy reform, as SUN evaluates governments on their national policies and then compares them with other governments. Government officials attended meetings every six weeks by telephone to report progress updates. A Sunner said, “We were monitored by the [SUN] Secretariat through the teleconference, and the teleconference was done every six weeks. So it was very intensive.”Footnote 28 As such, they diverted resources to formulating policies.

The Sunners used this pressure to keep policy efforts on track. This facilitated the rapid drafting and introduction of nutrition policies. In 2012, new policies were launched under the name the First Thousand Days of Life Movement (1000 Hari Pertama Kehidupan). Notably, SUN’s emphasis on the first thousand days of life meant that policies would be directed toward women and children. Ministers from the Coordinating Ministry for People’s Welfare, Bappenas, the Ministry of Health, and the Ministry of Women’s Empowerment and Child Protection carried out the launch (Kementerian PPN/Bappenas 2012).

The first document was a policy framework called the National Movement on Accelerating Nutrition Improvement within the Framework of the First Thousand Days of Life (Kerangka Kebijakan Gerakan Nasional Percepatan Perbaikan Gizi Dalam Rangka Seribu Hari Pertama Kehidupan). The policy framework articulated the role of key ministries and stakeholders in supporting nationwide efforts to address malnutrition, including micronutrient malnutrition. This was accompanied by a second document called the Guidelines for Program Planning: National Movement on Accelerating Nutrition Improvement within the Framework of the First Thousand Days of Life (Pedoman Perencanaan Program Gerakan Sadar Gizi Dalam Rangka Seribu Hari Pertama Kehidupan). This provided guidance on implementing the policy framework.

By this point, the Sunners had generated momentum by obtaining commitment from the president and developed policies that adapted international recommendations to the Indonesian context. While these policies created basic guidelines, the Sunners needed buy-in from different ministries to set up policy implementation (Sardjunani and Achadi Reference Sardjunani and Achadi2016). Describing past attempts to introduce policy change, an Indonesian national working for an IO in Jakarta said, “there is a Coordinating Minister but anything that needed coordination in the past did not work.”Footnote 29 The Sunners knew this. But this time, they could use the international pressures to insist on the necessary coordination. Because the president had committed to SUN and international attention remained focused on nutrition policies, they could push recalcitrant ministries to cooperate. At the same time, they were drawing on their informal networks and reaching out to government officials with whom they had existing relationships.

The Sunners invoked the Indonesian government’s commitment to SUN to convene high-level meetings and presented internationally recommended policies as “best practices” to avoid internal conflict.Footnote 30 They brought drafts of the newly formulated policies to show that the core work had been completed, and they emphasized the need to introduce new policy, given the external attention on Indonesia’s high levels of malnutrition.

In 2013, the president launched Presidential Decree 42, the National Movement to Accelerate Improvements in Nutrition (Peraturan Presiden Republik Indonesia Nomor 42 Tahun 2013 Tentang Gerakan Nasional Percepatan Perbaikan Gizi). The presidential decree created a taskforce within the government spanning several ministries, which would coordinate efforts to improve nutrition. The interministerial taskforce, while slow to get started, reported to the president and convened 13 government ministries and UN agencies on malnutrition.

Later, Indonesia’s 2015–19 National Medium-Term Development Plan (Rencana Pembangunan Jangka Menengah Nasional or RPJMN) recognized nutrition as requiring the cooperation of different ministries and incorporated the nutrition policy framework. New indicators, introduced through these policy changes, were harmonized with the 2011–15 National Food and Nutrition Action Plan (2011–15 Rencana Aksi Nasional Pangan Dan Gizi or RAN-PG).

The expansion of nutrition policies demonstrates how technocrats used IO pressure to augment their political power within the bureaucracy then obtained executive support and mobilized relevant government officials for policy expansion (Table 1). By 2015, there was a buzz of excitement—that this might be the beginning of improved nutrition in Indonesia.Footnote 31

CONCLUSION

At the heart of all policy making is a tension between technical expertise, on one hand, and politics, on the other. Evidence-based policy solutions may exist and have the potential to dramatically improve lives but fail to become policy if politics do not work in their favor.

This is exemplified by benevolent policies. The concept makes legible a host of policies affected by government inaction. For instance, refugees and migrants often lack state recognition, making it difficult to accumulate resources or organize. Recently the WHO drew attention to the “invisible” epidemic of noncommunicable diseases (NCDs) in Europe. Refugees and migrants often have higher rates of certain NCDs, yet governments have been slow to introduce relevant policies. Similarly, sanitation policies in Indonesia have been plagued by inaction. “Citizen demand is insufficient to catalyze government action” and governments “are not poised to take credit” (Winters, Karim, and Martawardaya Reference Winters, Karim and Martawardaya2014, 33). The benevolent policies framework explains why this has resulted in inadequate sanitation policies.

The benevolent polices framework can also help us anticipate government inaction. COVID-19, for example, has predominantly affected low-income and racialized individuals in the US. Many have recovered, but an estimated 15 million people will be affected by long-haul COVID, experiencing a range of debilitating symptoms months after being infected (Phillips and Williams Reference Phillips and Williams2021). Like other postinfection syndromes, such as myalgic encephalomyelitis/chronic fatigue syndrome, the medical community has been ambivalent about recognizing the illness, lowering public awareness. The benevolent policies framework suggests that the government will be slow to introduce relevant policies.

Under certain conditions, however, governments do act. For example, in Canada, low-income citizens are almost twice as likely to suffer from poor oral health compared with high-income citizens. While these individuals rarely organize to demand action on oral health, the government introduced water fluoridation policies that have reduced tooth decay in children.

How do these “good policies” overcome “bad politics?” In this article, I focus on nutrition policies in Indonesia. I foreground the bureaucracy, an explanatory variable that often slips into the background. Technocrats, I argue, can be an important catalyst for policy change. Even after policies are hollowed out, technocrats remain within the bureaucracy and can serve as the spark behind policy reform. I show that technical expertise has long policy legacies. Technocrats continue to fight for their ideas, even in the face of policy retrenchment, and leverage alternative strategies to orchestrate policy reform.

I draw on both the comparative politics and international relations scholarship, weaving together research from the two subfields, to make my argument. Technocrats deploy IO pressure to build a coalition and broaden their political connections within the bureaucracy. Technocrats, by harnessing international pressure, shape the channels for information flow, building vertical networks to elevate the policy onto the executive agenda and horizontal networks to coordinate different ministries for policy change.

Therefore, I show how policies get initiated, formulated, and introduced—even when domestic pressure for reform is weak. In doing so, I am adding analytical precision to the welfare state literature, which has paid limited attention to the government bureaucracy.

When I spoke with interview participants, there was a sense of optimism about the new policies that were introduced in 2012. However, these high hopes must be tempered by a broader view of the Indonesian state. As a Sunner told me, “policy implementation is our next big challenge.”Footnote 32 Indonesia faces governance challenges, including the capture of state institutions by various elites. Despite efforts around democratization, corruption remains the norm rather than the exception and administrative malfeasance is a perennial issue. Nevertheless, the country appears to be headed in a better direction. After expanding nutrition policies in 2012, chronic malnutrition declined, with stunting rates dropping to 36.4% in 2013, then declining to 30.8% in 2018 (Figure 2).

Research indicates that in Indonesia elite capture is not inevitable (Alatas et al. Reference Alatas, Banerjee, Hanna, Olken and Julia2012). However, the decentralized nature of the Indonesian state suggests there is likely to be variation in policy implementation (Shair-Rosenfield, Marks, and Hooghe Reference Shair-Rosenfield, Marks and Hooghe2014). Further work is needed to explore the influence of nonstate actors, such as religious groups (Cammett and MacLean Reference Cammett and MacLean2014; Cammett and Şaşmaz Reference Cammett and Şaşmaz2021), shared identity (Singh Reference Singh2015), and social network structures (Cruz, Labonne, and Querubín Reference Cruz, Labonne and Querubín2020) on nutrition policy implementation and subnational variation.

Future research on benevolent policies can illuminate the conditions under which governments act, when clear, short-term political gains are limited. As I show in this article, work in this area will complement the rich and dynamic scholarship on the factors that frustrate—or facilitate—welfare state expansion.

Supplementary Materials

To view supplementary material for this article, please visit http://doi.org/10.1017/S0003055421000927.

DATA AVAILABILITY STATEMENT

Research documentation and data that support the findings of this study are available at the American Political Science Review Dataverse: https://doi.org/10.7910/DVN/MEWHPE.

Acknowledgments

Interview participants in Indonesia generously shared their time and knowledge. I extend my deepest gratitude to them. I also thank Joseph Wong, Linda White, Stanley Zlotkin, Antoinette Handley, and Heather Millar for their incisive feedback on several drafts of the manuscript; Isabela Mares, Stephan Haggard, Allen Hicken, and Moira Faul for their insights at critical times; and Jessica Soedirgo, Diana Sue Kim, Daniel Béland, Matthew M. Kavanagh, Edward Koning, Sebastian Dettman, and the APSR editors and four reviewers for their valuable comments. I thank Peter Edward Harron for his endless support. Finally, I am grateful to have had the opportunity to join the Takemi Program at the Harvard T.H. Chan School of Public Health and the Research Cluster on Comparative Inequality at the Weatherhead Center for International Affairs while developing this article, and for feedback at APSA, ISA, CPSA, SEAREG, McMaster University, SickKids Centre for Global Child Health, SMU, and MUN seminars.

Funding Statement

This research was funded by the Fulbright Foundation, International Development Research Centre, Social Sciences and Humanities Research Council of Canada, and the University of Toronto.

Conflict of Interest

The author declares no ethical issues or conflicts of interest in this research.

Ethical Standards

The author declares the human subjects research in this article was reviewed and approved by the University of Toronto and the certificate number is provided in the appendix. The author affirms that this article adheres to the APSA’s Principles and Guidance on Human Subject Research.

Footnotes

1 The issue of malnutrition has largely been ignored by political scientists, leaving an important societal concern unexplored.

2 The term “malnutrition” technically refers to both undernutrition and overnutrition. This article focuses on “undernutrition,” a deficiency of calories or essential nutrients, but uses the term malnutrition as it is more familiar to political scientists.

3 Evaluating the recommended policies is not the central concern of this article. I leave this task to the nutrition experts. Instead, I take the recommended policies as given and focus on illuminating the political conditions which explain policy expansion.

4 My conceptualization of low visibility shares parallels with work by Jacob Hacker and Suzanne Mettler. Hacker examines social policies affected by “subterranean politics, only occasionally involving a broad circle of participants and resisting the scrutiny that public programs typically invite” (Reference Hacker2002, 83). My definition, by contrast, does not specify the participants. For Mettler, submerged policies have low visibility as the government’s role is obscured (Mettler Reference Mettler2011). By contrast, I define low visibility as low public awareness of the issue or government response.

5 The recommended nutrition policies include interventions such as salt iodization, vitamin A supplementation, iron fortification, folic acid supplementation, calcium supplementation, and multiple micronutrient powders. These target low-income women and children and increase their intake of essential micronutrients.

6 In this article, nutrition experts include nutritionists, epidemiologists, medical doctors, and public health professionals.

7 I thank Reviewer 2 for this term.

8 Individuals who have expert knowledge and political savvy have been called technopolitical actors. In Costa Rica, “technopoliticians comfortably interacted with politics, the technical aspects of the architecture involved, and international policy prescriptions. They became intermediaries and translators of international ideas, drawing on them to shape policy debates and policy design” (Martínez Franzoni and Sánchez-Ancochea Reference Martínez Franzoni and Sánchez-Ancochea2014, 111).

9 Please see the Appendix, where I provide further information on research ethics and methods.

10 Christiaan Eijkman, the Dutch director of the lab, discovered that beriberi was caused by a deficiency in Vitamin B1 (thiamine). He won the Nobel Prize for his discovery.

11 Badan Perencanaan Pembangunan, commonly shortened to Bappenas.

12 A similar dynamic can be seen in the expansion of family planning policies, which had the support of a technocrat with access to the president. Widjojo Nitisastro completed his PhD at Berkeley between 1957 and 1961. In his dissertation, he calls “for ‘a massive development effort’ and an enhanced family planning programme to provide employment and reduce population pressures” (Chalmers Reference Chalmers, Vedi and Chalmers1997, 55). In 1967, Nitisastro was appointed head of Bappenas. In 1968, the government rapidly expanded family planning policies. Technocrats attributed policy expansion to the cultivation of presidential commitment and their ability to coordinate supporting ministries’ efforts (Shiffman Reference Shiffman2004).

13 Personal Interview, October 8, 2015, Jakarta, Indonesia.

14 Ginandjar Kartasasmita took over leadership of Bappenas.

15 Led by Abdurrahman Wahid (1999–2001) then Megawati Sukarnoputri (2001–04).

16 Personal Interview, November 3, 2015, Jakarta, Indonesia.

17 The data were smoothed by removing an outlier in 2004.

18 Personal Interview, October 20, 2015, Jakarta, Indonesia.

19 Personal Interview, October 28, 2015, Jakarta, Indonesia.

20 Personal Interview, October 8, 2015, Jakarta, Indonesia.

21 Personal Interview, October 28, 2015, Jakarta, Indonesia; Personal Interview, November 3, 2015, Jakarta, Indonesia.

22 Personal Interview, October 20, 2015, Jakarta, Indonesia.

23 Personal Interview, September 29, 2015, Bangkok, Thailand.

24 Personal Interview, October 20, 2015, Jakarta, Indonesia.

25 Personal Interview, October 9, 2015, Jakarta, Indonesia.

26 Personal Interview, November 3, 2015, Jakarta, Indonesia.

27 Personal Interview, November 3, 2015, Jakarta, Indonesia.

28 Personal Interview, November 3, 2015, Jakarta, Indonesia.

29 Personal Interview, October 21, 2015, Jakarta, Indonesia.

30 Personal Interview, October 28, 2015, Jakarta, Indonesia.

31 Personal Interview, October 8, 2015, Jakarta, Indonesia; Personal Interview, October 24, 2015, Jakarta, Indonesia; Personal Interview, October 28, 2015, Jakarta, Indonesia.

32 Personal Interview, October 26, 2015, Jakarta, Indonesia.

References

REFERENCES

Acharya, Amitav. 2004. “How Ideas Spread: Whose Norms Matter? Norm Localization and Institutional Change in Asian Regionalism.” International Organization 58 (2): 239–75.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Adler, Emanuel. 1986. “Ideological ‘Guerrillas’ and the Quest for Technological Autonomy: Brazil’s Domestic Computer Industry.” International Organization 40 (3): 673705.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Alatas, Vivi, Banerjee, Abhijit, Hanna, Rema, Olken, Benjamin A., and Julia, Tobias. 2012. “Targeting the Poor: Evidence from a Field Experiment in Indonesia.” American Economic Review 102 (4): 1206–40.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Amir, Sulfikar. 2008. “The Engineers versus the Economists: The Disunity of Technocracy in Indonesian Development.” Bulletin of Science, Technology & Society 28 (4): 316–23.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Aspinall, Edward. 2014. “Health Care and Democratization in Indonesia.” Democratization 21 (5): 803–23.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Avant, Deborah D., Finnemore, Martha, and Sell, Susan K., eds. 2010. Who Governs the Globe? New York: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Baxter, Jo-Anna B., Roth, Daniel E., Mahmud, Abdullah Al, Ahmed, Tahmeed, Islam, Munirul, and Zlotkin, Stanley H.. 2014. “Tablets Are Preferred and More Acceptable Than Powdered Prenatal Calcium Supplements among Pregnant Women in Dhaka, Bangladesh.” The Journal of Nutrition 144 (7): 1106–12.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Béland, Daniel, and Cox, Robert Henry. 2016. “Ideas as Coalition Magnets: Coalition Building, Policy Entrepreneurs, and Power Relations.” Journal of European Public Policy 23 (3): 428–45.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bersch, Katherine. 2019. When Democracies Deliver: Governance Reform in Latin America. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Birkland, Thomas A. 1998. “Focusing Events, Mobilization, and Agenda Setting.” Journal of Public Policy 18 (1): 5374.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Black, David. 1999. “The Long and Winding Road: International Norms and Domestic Political Change in South Africa.” In The Power of Human Rights: International Norms and Domestic Change, eds. Thomas, Risse, Ropp, Stephen C., and Sikkink, Kathryn, 78108. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Black, Robert, Victora, Cesar G, Walker, Susan P, Bhutta, Zulfiqar A, Christian, Parul, de Onis, Mercedes, Ezzati, Majid, Grantham-McGregor, Sally, Katz, Joanne, Martorell, Reynaldo, et al. 2013. “Maternal and Child Undernutrition and Overweight in Low-Income and Middle-Income Countries.” The Lancet 382 (9890): 427–51.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Bozcaga, Tugba. 2020. “The Social Bureaucrat: How Social Proximity among Bureaucrats Affects Local Governance.” Paper presented at the Annual Meeting of the American Political Science Association, Online.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cammett, Melani, and MacLean, Lauren. 2014. The Politics of Non-State Social Welfare. Ithaca, NY: Cornell University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cammett, Melani, and Şaşmaz, Aytuğ. 2021. “Navigating Welfare Regimes in Divided Societies: Diversity and the Quality of Service Delivery in Lebanon.” Governance. https://doi.org/10.1111/gove.12576.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Centeno, Miguel A., Kohli, Atul, and Yashar, Deborah J., eds. 2017. States in the Developing World. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Chalmers, Ian. 1997. “The Pragmatic Technocrats.” In The Politics of Economic Development in Indonesia: Contending Perspectives, eds. Vedi, Hadiz and Chalmers, Ian, 3943. London: Routledge.Google Scholar
Chaparro, Camila, Oot, Lesley, and Sethuraman, Kavita. 2014. “Indonesia Nutrition Profile.” FHI 360/FANTA. https://www.fantaproject.org/sites/default/files/download/Indonesia-Nutrition-Profile-Apr2014.pdf.Google Scholar
Checkel, Jeffrey T. 1999. “Norms, Institutions, and National Identity in Contemporary Europe.” International Studies Quarterly 43 (1): 84114.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Croke, Kevin. 2021. “The Impact of Health Programs on Political Opinion: Evidence from Malaria Control in Tanzania.” The Journal of Politics 83 (1): 340–53.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cruz, Cesi, Labonne, Julien, and Querubín, Pablo. 2020. “Social Network Structures and the Politics of Public Goods Provision: Evidence from the Philippines.” American Political Science Review 114 (2): 486501.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Diaz-Cayeros, Alberto, Estevez, Federico, and Magaloni, Beatriz. 2016. The Political Logic of Poverty Relief: Electoral Strategies and Social Policy in Mexico. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Díez, Jordi. 2013. “Explaining Policy Outcomes: The Adoption of Same-Sex Unions in Buenos Aires and Mexico City.” Comparative Political Studies 46 (2): 212–35.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ding, Iza. 2020. “Performative Governance.” World Politics 72 (4): 525–56.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dion, Michelle. 2008. “International Organizations and Social Insurance in Mexico.” Global Social Policy: An Interdisciplinary Journal of Public Policy and Social Development 8 (1): 2544.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dion, Michelle. 2010. Workers and Welfare Comparative Institutional Change in Twentieth Century Mexico. Pittsburgh, PA: University of Pittsburgh Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dionne, Kim Yi, and Horowitz, Jeremy. 2016. “The Political Effects of Agricultural Subsidies in Africa: Evidence from Malawi.” World Development 87: 215–26.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Dobbin, Frank, Simmons, Beth, and Garrett, Geoffrey. 2007. “The Global Diffusion of Public Policies: Social Construction, Coercion, Competition, or Learning?Annual Review of Sociology 33: 449–72.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dye, Thomas. 1972. Understanding Public Policy. Englewood Cliffs, NJ: Prentice-Hall.Google Scholar
Esping-Andersen, Gøsta. 1990. The Three Worlds of Welfare Capitalism. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Falleti, Tulia G., and Mahoney, James. 2015. “The Comparative Sequential Method.” In Advances in Comparative-Historical Analysis, eds. James, Mahoney and Thelen, Kathleen, 211–39. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Finnemore, Martha. 1993. “International Organizations as Teachers of Norms: The United Nations Educational, Scientific, and Cultural Organization and Science Policy.” International Organization 47 (4): 565–97.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fossati, Diego, Aspinall, Edward, Muhtadi, Burhanuddin, and Warburton, Eve. 2020. “Ideological Representation in Clientelistic Democracies: The Indonesian Case.” Electoral Studies 63: 102111.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Garay, Candelaria. 2007. “Social Policy and Collective Action: Unemployed Workers, Community Associations, and Protest in Argentina.” Politics & Society 35 (2): 301–28.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Garay, Candelaria. 2016. Social Policy Expansion in Latin America. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Grindle, Merilee. 2004. Despite the Odds: The Contentious Politics of Education Reform. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Grindle, Merilee, and Thomas, John. 1991. Public Choices and Policy Change. Baltimore, MD: The Johns Hopkins University Press.Google Scholar
Haas, Peter. 1992. “Introduction: Epistemic Communities and International Policy Coordination.” International Organization 46 (1): 135.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hacker, Jacob. 2002. The Divided Welfare State: The Battle over Public and Private Social Benefits in the United States. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Haddad, Lawrence. 2013. “How Can We Build an Enabling Political Environment to Fight Undernutriton?The European Journal of Development Research 25 (1): 1320.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Haggard, Stephan, and Kaufman, Robert R.. 2008. Development, Democracy, and Welfare States: Latin America, East Asia, and Eastern Europe. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Hall, Peter A. 2013. “Tracing the Progress of Process Tracing.” European Political Science 12 (1): 2030.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Heaver, Richard. 2005. Strengthening Country Commitment to Human Development: Lessons from Nutrition. Washington, DC: The World Bank.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Heclo, Hugh. 1974. Modern Social Politics in Britain and Sweden: From Relief to Income Maintenance. New Haven, CT: Yale University Press.Google Scholar
Hicken, Allen, and Simmons, Joel W.. 2008. “The Personal Vote and the Efficacy of Education Spending.” American Journal of Political Science 52 (1): 109–24.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hirschman, Albert O. 1981. Essays in Trespassing: Economics to Politics and Beyond. New York: Cambridge University Pres.Google Scholar
Ho, Carmen Jacqueline. 2021. “Replication Data for: Benevolent Policies: Bureaucratic Politics and Social Policy Expansion.” Harvard Dataverse. Dataset. https://doi.org/10.7910/DVN/MEWHPE.Google Scholar
Holland, Alisha C. 2018. “Diminished Expectations: Redistributive Preferences in Truncated Welfare States.” World Politics 70 (4): 555–94.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Holland, Alisha C., and Schneider, Ben Ross. 2017. “Easy and Hard Redistribution: The Political Economy of Welfare States in Latin America.” Perspectives on Politics 15 (4): 9881006.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Huber, Evelyne, and Stephens, John D.. 2012. Democracy and the Left : Social Policy and Inequality in Latin America. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kaufman, Robert, and Nelson, Joan, eds. 2004. Crucial Needs, Weak Incentives. Baltimore, MD: Johns Hopkins University Press.Google Scholar
Keck, Margaret E., and Sikkink, Kathryn. 1998. Activists beyond Borders: Advocacy Networks in International Politics. Ithaca, NY: Cornell University Press.Google Scholar
Kelley, Judith G., and Simmons, Beth A.. 2015. “Politics by Number: Indicators as Social Pressure in International Relations.” American Journal of Political Science 59 (1): 5570.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kementerian PPN/Bappenas. 2012. “Peluncuran Gerakan Nasional 1000 HPK.” Berita Utama (Headlines). https://www.bappenas.go.id/id/berita-dan-siaran-pers/kegiatan-utama/peluncuran-gerakan-nasional-1000-hpk/.Google Scholar
Kim, Diana S. 2020. Empires of Vice: The Rise of Opium Prohibition across Southeast Asia. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Korpi, Walter. 1978. The Working Class in Welfare Capitalism : Work, Unions, and Politics in Sweden. Boston: Routledge.Google Scholar
Kwon, Huck-ju. 2007. “Advocacy Coalitions and Health Politics in Korea.” Social Policy & Administration 41 (2): 148–61.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lee, Kelley, and Goodman, Hilary. 2001. “Global Policy Networks: The Propagation of Health Care Financing Reform since the 1980s.” In Health Policy in a Globalising World, eds. Lee, Kelley, Buse, Kent, and Fustukian, Suzanne, 97119. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Levy, Jack S. 2008. “Case Studies: Types, Designs, and Logics of Inference.” Conflict Management and Peace Science 25 (1): 118.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Malloy, James M. 1989. “Policy Analysts, Public Policy and Regime Structure in Latin America.” Governance 2 (3): 315–38.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Marcuse, Peter. 1978. “Housing Policy and the Myth of the Benevolent State.” Social Policy 8 (4): 2126.Google Scholar
Mares, Isabela, and Young, Lauren E.. 2018. “The Core Voter’s Curse: Clientelistic Threats and Promises in Hungarian Elections.” Comparative Political Studies 51 (11): 1441–71.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Martínez Franzoni, Juliana, and Sánchez-Ancochea, Diego. 2014. “Filling in the Missing Link between Universalism and Democracy: The Case of Costa Rica.” Latin American Politics and Society 56 (4): 98118.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
McGuire, James. 2010. Wealth, Health, and Democracy in East Asia and Latin America. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mesa-Lago, Carmelo. 1978. Security in Latin America: Pressure Groups, Stratification, and Inequality. Pittsburgh, PA: University of Pittsburgh.Google Scholar
Mettler, Suzanne. 2011. The Submerged State: How Invisible Government Policies Undermine American Democracy. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mietzner, Marcus. 2009. Indonesia’s 2009 Elections: Populism, Dynasties and the Consolidation of the Party System. Sydney: Lowy Institute for Public Policy.Google Scholar
Mujani, Saiful, and Liddle, R. William. 2010. “Personalities, Parties, and Voters.” Journal of Democracy 21 (2): 3549.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mwenda, Andrew, and Tangri, Roger. 2005. “Patronage Politics, Donor Reforms, and Regime Consolidation in Uganda.” African Affairs 104 (416): 449–67.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Nam, Illan. 2015. Democratizing Health Care Welfare State Building in Korea and Thailand. New York: Palgrave Macmillan.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Nelson, Joan. 2004. “The Politics of Health Sector Reform: Cross National Comparisons.” In Crucial Needs, Weak Incentives, eds. Kaufman, Robert and Nelson, Joan, 2364. Baltimore, MD: Johns Hopkins University Press.Google Scholar
Niedzwiecki, Sara. 2018. Uneven Social Policies: The Politics of Subnational Variation in Latin America. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Orenstein, Mitchell A. 2013. “Pension Privatization: Evolution of a Paradigm.” Governance 26 (2): 259–81.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Orloff, Ann Shola, and Skocpol, Theda. 1984. “Why Not Equal Protection? Explaining the Politics of Public Social Spending in Britain, 1900-1911, and the United States, 1880s-1920.” American Sociological Review 49 (6): 726–50.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Pepinsky, Thomas B., Pierskalla, Jan H., and Sacks, Audrey. 2017. “Bureaucracy and Service Delivery.” Annual Review of Political Science 20: 249–68.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Peters, B. Guy. 2018. “The Challenge of Policy Coordination.” Policy Design and Practice 1 (1): 111.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Phillips, Steven, and Williams, Michelle A.. 2021. “Confronting Our Next National Health Disaster: Long-Haul COVID.” New England Journal of Medicine 385: 577–9. DOI: 10.1056/NEJMp2109285.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Pierson, Paul. 2000. “Increasing Returns, Path Dependence, and the Study of Politics.” American Political Science Review 94 (2): 251–67.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Pribble, Jennifer. 2011. “Worlds Apart: Social Policy Regimes in Latin America.” Studies in Comparative International Development 46 (2): 191216.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ramesh, M. 2000. “The State and Social Security in Indonesia and Thailand.” Journal of Contemporary Asia 30 (4): 534–46.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rimlinger, Gaston V. 1971. Welfare Policy and Industrialization in Europe, America, and Russia. New York: Wiley.Google Scholar
Risse, Thomas. 1994. “Ideas Do Not Float Freely: Transnational Coalitions, Domestic Structures, and the End of the Cold War.” International Organization 48 (2): 185214.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Risse, Thomas, Ropp, Steve C., and Sikkink, Kathryn, eds. 1999. The Power of Human Rights : International Norms and Domestic Change. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rohde, Jon, and Hendrata, Lukas. 1982. “Development from Below.” In Nutrition Policy Implementation: Issues and Experience, eds. Scrimshaw, Nevin and Wallerstein, Mitchell, 209–30. New York: Plenum Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rokx, Claudia, Subandoro, Ali Winoto, and Gallagher, Paul. 2018. Aiming High: Indonesia’s Ambition to Reduce Stunting. Washington, DC: World Bank Group.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rosenberg, Mark B. 1979. “Social Security Policymaking in Costa Rica: A Research Report.” Latin American Research Review 14 (1): 116–33.Google Scholar
Ross, Michael. 2006. “Is Democracy Good for the Poor?American Journal of Political Science 50 (4): 860–74.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rothstein, Bo. 1998. The Social Democratic State: The Swedish Model and the Bureaucratic Problem of Social Reforms. Pittsburgh, PA: University of Pittsburgh Press.Google Scholar
Sardjunani, Nina, and Achadi, Endang. 2016. “SUN Movement Experiences in Indonesia.” ENN Exchange. https://www.ennonline.net/fex/51/sunexperiencesindonesia.Google Scholar
Semba, Richard D. 2012. “The Historical Evolution of Thought Regarding Multiple Micronutrient Nutrition.” The Journal of Nutrition 142 (1): 143S–56S.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Shair-Rosenfield, Sarah, Marks, Gary, and Hooghe, Liesbet. 2014. “A Comparative Measure of Decentralization for Southeast Asia.” Journal of East Asian Studies 14 (1): 85108.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Shiffman, Jeremy. 2004. “Political Management in the Indonesian Family Planning Program.” International Family Planning Perspectives 30 (1): 2733.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Silva, Patricio. 1991. “Technocrats and Politics in Chile: From the Chicago Boys to the CIEPLAN Monks.” Journal of Latin American Studies 23 (2): 385410.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Singh, Prerna. 2015. “Subnationalism and Social Development: A Comparative Analysis of Indian States.” World Politics 67 (3): 506–62.Google Scholar
Skocpol, Theda. 1985. “Bringing the State Back In: Strategies of Analysis in Current Research.” In Bringing the State Back In, eds. Evans, Peter, Rueschemeyer, Dietrich, and Skocpol, Theda, 343. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Soekirman. 2008. “Convinced from the Start That National Development Is Not Synonymous with Economic Development.” In Testimonials of Friends about Widjojo Nitisastro, eds. Arsjad Anwar, M., Ananta, Aris, Kuncoro, Ari, 183–88. Jakarta, Indonesia: Kompas Book Publishing.Google Scholar
Sumarto, Sudarno, Suryahadi, Asep, and Widyanti, Wenefrida. 2002. “Designs and Implementation of Indonesian Social Safety Net Programs.” The Developing Economies 40 (1): 331.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
SUN. 2011. “Summary Note: SUN Meeting and Workshop Held at United Nations General Assembly 20th and 21st September 2011. Scaling Up Nutrition (SUN) Movement: The First Year and the Future.” Scalingupnutrition.org. https://scalingupnutrition.org/wp-content/uploads/2012/09/archived/summmary-note.pdf.Google Scholar
Thawnghmung, Ardeth Maung. 2019. Everyday Economic Survival in Myanmar. Madison: University of Wisconsin Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Toral, Guillermo. 2021. “The Benefits of Patronage: How Political Appointments Can Enhance Bureaucratic Accountability and Effectiveness.” Paper presented at the Annual Meeting of the American Political Science Association, Boston.Google Scholar
UNICEF Indonesia. 2012. “Issue Briefs: Maternal and Child Nutrition.” UNICEF.Google Scholar
UNICEF/WHO/World Bank. 2021. Levels and Trends in Child Malnutrition: Key Findings of the 2021 Edition of the Joint Child Malnutrition Estimates. New York: UNICEF.Google Scholar
Utama, Rahardhika Arista. 2014. “How Bureaucracy Affects Inequality: The Case of Post-Authoritarian Indonesia.” In Arryman Fellows Symposium, Jakarta, Indonesia.Google Scholar
Weyland, Kurt Gerhard, ed. 2004. External Models, International Influence, and the Politics of Social Sector Reforms. Washington, DC: Woodrow Wilson Center Press.Google Scholar
White, Linda. 2011. “The Internationalization of Early Childhood Education and Care Issues: Framing Gender Justice and Child Well-Being.” Governance 24 (2): 285309.Google Scholar
WHO. 2012. “Family Nutrition Improvement Programme (UPGK).” Global Database on the Implementation of Nutrition Action (GINA). https://extranet.who.int/nutrition/gina/en/node/23365 Google Scholar
WHO. 2013. Global Nutrition Policy Review: What Does It Take to Scale up Nutrition Action? Geneva, Switzerland: World Health Organization.Google Scholar
Wicaksono, Ario. 2018. “The Role of Policy Transfer in Indonesian Governance: The Case of Academic Administrative Entrepreneurs.” Policy Studies 39 (6): 622–37.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wilensky, Harold L. 1974. The Welfare State and Equality : Structural and Ideological Roots of Public Expenditures. Oakland: University of California Press.Google Scholar
Winters, Matthew S., Karim, Abdul Gaffar, and Martawardaya, Berly. 2014. “Public Service Provision under Conditions of Insufficient Citizen Demand: Insights from the Urban Sanitation Sector in Indonesia.” World Development 60: 3142.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wong, Joseph. 2006. Healthy Democracies: Welfare Politics in Taiwan and South Korea. Ithaca, NY: Cornell University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
World Bank. 2021. “Prevalence of Stunting, Height for Age (% of Children under 5), Indonesia.” World Bank Data. https://data.worldbank.org/indicator/SH.STA.STNT.ZS?locations=ID.Google Scholar
Zlotkin, Stanley H., Claudia Schauer, Anna Christofi des, Waseem Sharieff, Mélody C. Tondeur, and S. M. Ziauddin Hyder. 2005. “Micronutrient Sprinkles to Control Childhood Anaemia.” PLoS Medicine 2 (1): e1. 2428.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Zucco, Cesar. 2013. “When Payouts Pay Off: Conditional Cash Transfers and Voting Behavior in Brazil.” American Journal of Political Science 57 (4): 810–22.Google Scholar
Figure 0

Figure 1. Analytical Framework

Figure 1

Table 1. Periods of Nutrition Policy Expansion and Retrenchment in Indonesia

Figure 2

Figure 2. Prevalence of Stunting among Children under the Age of Five in IndonesiaNote: Source: World Bank 2021.17

Link
Supplementary material: File

Ho supplementary material

Appendix

Download Ho supplementary material(File)
File 45.5 KB
Submit a response

Comments

No Comments have been published for this article.