Hostname: page-component-78c5997874-xbtfd Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-11-08T16:29:39.322Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

The Political Economy of the Prussian Three-Class Franchise

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  28 September 2020

Sascha O. Becker
Affiliation:
Xiaokai Yang Chair of Business and Economics, Monash University, part-time Professor, University of Warwick, and Research Fellow at CAGE, CEPR, CESifo, CReAM, Ifo, IZA, ROA, and SoDaLabs. Address: 900 Dandenong Rd, Building H, room 4.54, Caulfield East VIC 3145, Australia. E-mail: [email protected].
Erik Hornung
Affiliation:
Professor of Economic History, University of Cologne, and Research Fellow at CAGE, CEPR, and CESifo. Address: Albertus-Magnus-Platz, 50923 Cologne, Germany. E-mail: [email protected].
Rights & Permissions [Opens in a new window]

Abstract

How did the Prussian three-class franchise, which politically over-represented the economic elite, affect policies? Contrary to the predominant and simplistic view that the system allowed the landed elites to capture most political rents, we find that members of parliament from constituencies with a higher vote inequality support more liberal policies, gauging their political orientation from the universe of roll call votes cast in parliament during Prussia’s rapid industrialization (1867–1903). Consistent with the characteristics of German liberalism that aligned with economic interests of business, the link between vote inequality and liberal voting is stronger in regions with large-scale industry.

Type
Article
Creative Commons
Creative Common License - CCCreative Common License - BY
This is an Open Access article, distributed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution license (http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/), which permits unrestricted reuse, distribution, and reproduction in any medium, provided the original work is properly cited.
Copyright
© The Economic History Association 2020

It has been widely acknowledged that the pre-industrial distribution of landownership exerted a continuing influence on the political and economic institutions of industrializing societies across the world. Suffrage institutions historically excluded large parts of society from political influence and arguably affected long-run development through biased tax systems and public goods provision (Engerman and Sokoloff 2005). Concentration of political power in the hands of a small landed elite alongside a vast majority of the population without effective rights has been associated with the adoption of policies that mainly benefit this elite (Acemoglu, Johnson, and Robinson Reference Acemoglu, Johnson and Robinson2001, Reference Acemoglu, Johnson and Robinson2002).

The conventional wisdom regarding Prussia’s development during the second half of the nineteenth century is that the landowning elite, the Junkers, retained sufficient control over the political process to obtain political rents. According to Gerschenkron (Reference Gerschenkron1966, p. 25), due to the unequal and indirect Prussian franchise, Junkers dominated both chambers of the Prussian parliament and could thus veto legislation in the Federal Council of the German Empire. Despite several attempts to introduce an equal voting system, which were blocked by members of parliament (MPs) representing voting districts where the landed elite was concentrated, Prussia maintained a voting system that was unequal, non-secret, and indirect until the eve of WWI (Ziblatt Reference Ziblatt2008). Since 1850, members of the lower house of the Prussian parliament were elected under the so-called three-class franchise system, which translated tax payments into voting weights. Voters were grouped into three classes (Abteilungen) by total direct taxes paid. Each of the three classes represented one-third of the total direct tax revenue and received the same number of votes. Classes were filled with voters ranked according to their tax payments, starting from the highest, adding taxpayers until one-third of the total tax base was reached, thereby allocating less than 5 percent of voters into the first class, on average.

By tying voting power to economic power, the system arguably produced policies tailored to fit the landed nobility.Footnote 1 German economic historians widely agree that the franchise system was designed to “generate Conservative votes,”Footnote 2 and thereby produced (socio-) economic policies favored by agrarian elites (see, e.g., Nipperdey Reference Nipperdey1992, p. 86; Clark Reference Clark2006, pp. 560–61). Kühne (Reference Kühne1994a, p. 25) stresses that the system was “the bulwark of reactionary Prussianism par excellence.”Footnote 3 Indeed, the Prussian parliament was firmly regressive in so far as Social Democrats were not able to win any mandates until 1908. Despite this univocal assessment, the question of whether the unequal distribution of voting rights in Prussia produced conservative policies is ultimately an empirical one and has not been answered thus far.

This paper fills this gap and investigates how the three-class franchise contributed to the adoption of liberal or conservative (socio-)economic policies by the Prussian parliament. We find that MPs from constituencies with higher vote inequality, that is, where a small number of affluent voters holds a large share of the political power, vote significantly more for liberal policies. Crucially, our result of a link between vote inequality and more liberal voting holds controlling for landownership inequality, which in itself generates more conservative voting, in line with earlier claims that landed elites protected their own interests (Gerschenkron Reference Gerschenkron1966).

Post-1848 German liberalism catered to a relatively small group of bourgeois voters that advocated low taxes and free-market capitalism (Gall Reference Gall1975; Kurlander Reference Kurlander and Jefferies2015). In fact, Gross (Reference Gross2004, p. 22) summarizes the vision of German liberals as seeking progressive development toward modern rationalism, bourgeois individualism, high industrialization, free-market capitalism, and the unified nation-state. With national unity (excluding Austria) and the German constitution in 1871, central goals of liberalism had been achieved, including progressive legislation such as the penal code, the commercial code, the reform of the monetary system, and the Prussian county ordinance. The subsequent relative decline of the popularity of liberalism coincided with a period of economic stagnation (Langewiesche Reference Langewiesche and Martel1992). In the 1880s and 1890s, liberals aimed to address the looming social challenges of rapid industrialization and the demise of the working class by adopting social liberalism, a form of liberalism that opposed governmental social policy and supported “self-help” instead of “state-help” (Kurlander Reference Kurlander and Jefferies2015). Advancing public education and improving the urban infrastructure became central instruments in their strive for a liberal society (Langewiesche 1990; Palmowski Reference Palmowski1999).

In the Prussian parliament, liberal and conservative views differed on many issues. We illustrate some of the divides of the time by inspecting five salient debates in which liberals opposed tuition fees in public primary schools, supported decentralization of administrative power, opposed nationalization of railroads, supported tax exemptions for income from capital investments, and supported the construction of a canal that arguably increased competition in East Elbian grain markets.

We capture the (socio-)economic orientation of policies by measuring the political orientation of MPs using the universe of 329 roll call votes (RCVs) from the Prussian House of Representatives in the period of 1867–1903. We apply Poole’s (Reference Poole2000) optimal classification (OC) method, described in detail later, to measure two salient dimensions of MPs’ political orientation: their liberal or conservative economic orientation and their secular or religious orientation. The start year is chosen because in January 1867 Prussia reached its maximum extension after incorporating Schleswig-Holstein. The choice of the end year is due to the fact that, from the election period 20 (1904–1908), there was a change in the procedure to elect MPs, and in 1906 a range of constituencies were split. Our period of analysis is characterized by the rapid industrialization of the economy and by the secularization of society in Prussia and the German Empire more broadly.Footnote 4

The results are robust to the inclusion of a sizable set of constituency-level control variables capturing regional development and thereby the political preferences of the median citizen. Complementing the analysis with biographical information of MPs, we also inspect whether voting was biased toward MPs’ personal agendas. The inclusion of both sets of variables does not change our main qualitative findings.

Furthermore, we control for party affiliation. Of course, since parties are collectives of like-minded people, party affiliation captures a lot of the variation in political orientation of MPs. But since parties did not exercise complete control over MP voting behavior, there is sufficient within-party variation in political orientation that our main results hold conditional on party affiliation.

Despite the fact that our broad set of control variables explains a substantial amount of variation in the political orientation of MPs, we discuss remaining endogeneity concerns related to omitted variable bias. As we explain in more detail later, the allocation of voters to classes reflects local thresholds between terciles of the tax base that are arbitrary from a national perspective. In locations with a large number of high-income earners, voters with high incomes are more likely to be allocated to lower classes than elsewhere. Using this insight, in a robustness check, we further aim to mitigate endogeneity concerns by using the share of voters in the first class as an instrumental variable (IV) for vote inequality. Resulting IV estimates confirm the link between vote inequality and liberal orientation.

In placebo tests, we inspect whether the “secular-religious” dimension of political orientation responds to vote inequality. Conflicts between Protestants and Catholics that culminated in the secularist policies of the Kulturkampf (“culture struggle”) era in the 1870s transcended class structures and should not be reflected in the distribution of voting power. Indeed, we find that vote inequality does not predict for which type of cultural policies MPs vote.

What explains our results? The three-class franchise was designed when industrialization was in its infancy. The rise of large-scale industry in late nineteenth-century Prussia increased earnings and tax contributions of industrialists. This development resulted in a stronger income dispersion and therefore in higher vote inequality in industrial regions (Kuznets Reference Kuznets1955; Bartels Reference Bartels2019) than in agricultural regions where the income of landowners remained largely unchanged. As a consequence, the highly unequal distribution of individuals across voting classes in industrial regions created a small and homogeneous first class, which was able to coordinate on electoral delegates during primary elections (Urwahlen) and to influence the selection of their favorite MP, who would support liberal policies, as our results show. Our result of an effect of vote inequality on liberal orientation of MPs holds for Prussia in general. In line with our expectations, we find that this effect is particularly pronounced in regions with a high share of large firms whose owners would benefit the most from liberal economic policies.

Our findings are in line with a recent literature debating the role of elites in the process of modernization and democratization. This literature presents results that are broadly consistent with the idea that elites prefer “liberal” policies if those are in their own interest.Footnote 5 For example, Ashraf et al. (Reference Ashraf, Francesco, Oded, Boris and Hornung2017) argue that capital-owning elites in industrializing Prussia granted more freedom to the masses to incentivize their labor effort. In Tsarist Russia, liberal nobles cooperated with the peasantry to expand public goods provision (Nafziger Reference Nafziger2011). In nineteenth-century Sweden, a suffrage reform shifted voting power from landed elites to industrialists, resulting in higher investments in railways and structural change (Hinnerich, Lindgren, and Pettersson-Lidbom Reference Hinnerich, Lindgren and Pettersson-Lidbom2017). In Revolutionary France, the enlightened elite supported more “liberal” education policies (Squicciarini and Voigtländer 2016).

We also contribute to a large literature that uses RCVs to study the orientation of historical parliaments (see, e.g., Schonhardt-Bailey Reference Schonhardt-Bailey1998; Rosenthal and Voeten Reference Rosenthal and Voeten2004; Heckelman and Dougherty 2013). We are not aware of work that systematically analyzes RCVs from the Prussian House of Representatives. However, inspecting a period that strongly overlaps with ours, Häge (Reference Häge2019) provides a descriptive analysis of the policy space across different Reichstag legislatures during the Bismarck era in the German Empire.Footnote 6 While their orientation shows similarities, the two parliaments differ in their franchise system. Thus, discrepancies in dimensionality and party affiliation could be the outcome of a fundamentally different political process. In addition, our paper focuses on explaining rather than describing the orientation of parliament.

Earlier work that tried to explain voting behavior in the Prussian House of Representatives has so far focused on selected RCVs debating important issues. Ziblatt (Reference Ziblatt2008) analyzed one RCV seeking to abolish the three-class franchise in 1912 and finds higher landownership inequality but not income inequality to be associated with voting in favor of preserving the three-class system.Footnote 7 Mares and Queralt (Reference Mares and Queralt2014) analyze one RCV on the introduction of a Prussian income tax system in 1891, showing that higher landownership inequality is associated with voting for the adoption of an income tax that disproportionately burdened the industrialists.Footnote 8

Thus, on the data front, we go beyond previous work by using the universe of RCVs in the Prussian House of Representatives during 1867–1903. We consider this data work a major contribution for several reasons: First, future research will be able to analyze any or all of the RCVs not analyzed in earlier single-RCV studies. Second, future research will be able to use previously unavailable measures of political orientation for Prussia derived with the OC method based on the universe of RCVs.

HISTORICAL CONTEXT

In 1848/1849, Prussia introduced a bicameral parliament, with an appointed House of Lords (Herrenhaus) and an elected House of Representatives (Abgeordnetenhaus). The constitution, imposed by the King, stipulated that the lower chamber was elected by male citizens aged 24 or older who had paid taxes in the preceding year. Additionally, the exclusion of women and of those not paying taxes is a form of unequal voting, which was very common until the early twentieth century. However, in Prussia, voters were allocated to three classes reflecting terciles of the total direct tax base. Votes were effectively weighted in proportion to payments of direct taxes (class-tax, classified income tax, real estate and property tax, and business tax): the upper tercile of tax payments had as many votes as the middle tercile and the lower tercile. On average, first-class voters had about 17.5 times the number of votes of third-class voters, even stronger inequality at the local ward (Urwahlbezirk) level. In the extreme, a single taxpayer who paid one-third or more of direct taxes in a ward would have as many votes as all of the taxpayers in the lower tercile combined.Footnote 9

The thresholds for allocating voters into the three classes according to their tax payments were determined at the municipality level.Footnote 10 Municipalities with more than 1,750 inhabitants were subdivided into wards but maintained the municipality-level tax thresholds.

The mayor was responsible for the division into wards, frequently leading to gerrymandering (Kühne Reference Kühne1994a; Richter Reference Richter2017). In cases where social stratification led to sorting into city quarters, the first and second class remained unpopulated in poorer wards, whereas the first class was populated by many voters in richer wards, reducing individual voting power in wealthy city quarters.Footnote 11

Elections proceeded in two stages: in stage one, the primary elections (Urwahlen), voters elected electoral delegates (Wahlmänner). In stage two, the electoral delegates elected the members of the House of Representatives. Stage one was voting by a show of hands, in other words, non-secret, and took place at the level of wards.Footnote 12 Each class in a ward elected the same number of delegates, ranging between 3 and 6 per ward, one per 250 inhabitants (according to the last census). At the second stage, electoral delegates from all wards in an electoral constituency met to elect between one and three MPs, depending on its population size. The three-class franchise was frequently disputed but persisted in parallel with the equal voting system of the Imperial Diet, the Reichstag, until 1913.

The Political Landscape

The Prussian party landscape stabilized during the early periods of our analysis. Political fractions and parties formed during the 1860s, and gained relevance after German Unification in 1871, when the German Reichstag was established.Footnote 13

Drawing on biographical information from Kühne (Reference Kühne1994b), we report the party affiliation of MPs in Table 1.Footnote 14 The table depicts an aggregate number of 3,658 MP-by-period observations of party affiliation between 1867 and 1903. A range of smaller factions were represented in parliament. Following the detailed discussion in Treue (Reference Treue1975), we classify members of smaller factions into larger party groups as indicated in Columns (2) and (3). This leaves us with six main parties that were active during our period of analysis (and the residual category “Other” (1.35 percent of observations)).

Table 1 PARTY AFFILIATION FREQUENCY

Notes: This table reports the party affiliation of all 3,658 MP-by-period observations whose votes were scalable. Column Party depicts the original party assignment according to Kühne (Reference Kühne1994b). Cases in which party affiliation was uncertain were coded according to the most likely party affiliation. Column Classification consolidates smaller parties with similar platforms. Column Indicator lists a party code used in graphical presentation of the policy space. Columns Freq. and In Percent show the frequency and share of party affiliation.

Source: See Kühne (Reference Kühne1994b) and Online Appendix A.

Parties offered a wide spectrum of political views, which we discuss in more detail in Online Appendix A.1.Footnote 15 However, due to the inequalities embedded in the franchise system, parties addressing social issues and redistribution such as the Socialist Workers’ Party (later Sozialdemokratische Partei Deutschlands (SPD)) did not manage to obtain any seats in parliament until 1908.Footnote 16

For the purpose of our analysis that focuses on positions of MPs, it is important to note that party discipline was far from perfect. In fact, as we will show, MPs often deviated from the party line, a key feature permitting analysis of MPs’ political orientation.

Roll Call Voting

The Prussian constitution of 1850 stipulates in article 64 that the King and each of the chambers have the right to introduce bills. In the House of Representatives, legislative proposals can be introduced by the president of the chamber or by groups of at least ten MPs. To vote, the majority of members of the chamber must be present. Proposals are voted on by absolute majority. To adopt a law, all three sides (King and both chambers) must agree, so they are fully equal in the legislative process.

Voting in the House of Representatives took several forms. When the majority on an issue was clear-cut, a count based on standing or sitting MPs established the result. RCVs were triggered in one of two ways: (1) on request of at least 50 MPs (Plate 1903, p. 187; §61 GO) and (2) with a majority of less than 15 votes, a roll call could be requested without further support/signatures (Plate 1903, p. 187; §58 GO). From 13 February 1875, some roll call votes were replaced by a division of the assembly (Hammelsprung).Footnote 17 This reform likely explains why the number of roll call votes declined after 1875 (see Table A.1 in the Online Appendix). The absolute majority decided all votes. Abstentions were typically not included in the calculation of the majority.Footnote 18

Since RCVs were only called on close and/or contentious issues, they are likely to be quite selective (Carrubba et al. 2006). This has advantages and disadvantages: RCVs are associated with highly important issues, which is a clear upside for our analysis. On the other hand, party discipline tends to be enforced more strongly in RCVs, at least in modern parliaments (Yordanova and Mühlböck Reference Yordanova and Mühlböck2015). If that was true also in historic parliaments, and if we could observe all votes in the Prussian Parliament, the actual variation in political orientation across MPs would likely be larger than what we observe using only RCVs. However, our analysis shows that there is substantial variation in political orientation within parties, in other words, de facto party discipline is far from perfect. This has important implications for our analysis because we capture meaningful variation in political orientation above and beyond what is predicted by party membership.

CONCEPTUAL FRAMEWORK

The three-class franchise was created at a time when industrialization was still in its infancy and income inequality was relatively low. Large landowners paid a sufficient amount of taxes to populate the first two classes, despite the fact that they enjoyed a range of tax exemptions and paid little taxes on land—their main source of income. Due to the rapid rise of large-scale industry in the second half of the century, industrialists started to obtain high returns to capital investment and incurred an increasing share of the total tax base (Bartels Reference Bartels2019). In industrializing regions, this development lifted the new industrial elites into the first two classes, where they crowded out parts of the traditional elites. Thus, the rise of industry created an unforeseen regional concentration of high incomes and thereby a higher level of vote inequality in industrializing regions while vote inequality in agricultural regions was less affected. This description is in line with the developments first observed by Kuznets (Reference Kuznets1955) who also relied on Prussian income data (also, see Grant Reference Grant2002; Bartels Reference Bartels2019).

Figures 1(a) and 1(b) depict the spatial variation of vote inequality and landownership inequality across Prussia. Regions with high levels of vote inequality, as measured by a Gini coefficient across franchise classes, can be found throughout Prussia, especially in more urban and industrial locations.Footnote 19 The spatial distribution of landownership inequality, as measured by a Gini coefficient across farm size classes, shows that landownership inequality concentrates in the more rural eastern provinces. A comparison of the two maps visually confirms our previously noted interpretation that the mechanics of the franchise system may have provided political rents to an industrial elite and were not exclusively captured by the agrarian elite.

Figure 1 SPATIAL VARIATION IN INEQUALITIES IN PRUSSIA

Notes: The figure shows the spatial distribution of vote inequality and landownership inequality. Vote inequality is a Gini coefficient calculated using the county-level number of voters in each class in the three-class franchise system of 1893 assuming that the tax burden of each class amounts to exactly one-third. Landownership inequality is a Gini coefficient calculated using the county-level number of farms with arable land by size-class (up to 1 hectare, 1 to 2 ha, 2 to 10 ha, 10 to 50 ha, 50 to 100 ha, and more than 100 ha) in 1882.

Source: See Online Appendix C for data sources.

DIVERGING INTERESTS

We assume that the new concentration of industrialists at the top of the income distribution led to the creation of a small first (and likely second) class of voters whose interests were best served by policies that allowed them to explore economic opportunities arising from decentralization, improved transport infrastructure, or tax exemptions for capital gains.Footnote 20 Such policies were firmly supported by MPs in parties self-identifying as “liberal” in their name, which propagated liberal economic policies, stressed the need for (domestic) competition, and supported the separation of church and state.

On the other hand, we assume that large landowners predominantly favor policies that protect their (socio-)economic status. In rural regions with little competition over entry into the upper classes, political preferences in the first and second class therefore should remain conservative. Higher levels of landownership concentration may reflect higher demand for social control due to a higher risk of expropriation for the elite (Weber Reference Weber1917; de Tocqueville Reference de Tocqueville1856). Since landowners rely on an immobile factor of production, they prefer conservative policies that sustain inequality (Acemoglu and Robinson Reference Acemoglu and Robinson2000; Boix Reference Boix2003).

So far, we have highlighted the polar cases of industrialists and landowners, as if their interests were ideal points in a spectrum.Footnote 21 However, industrialization in agricultural regions may have similarly increased heterogeneity in political preferences. Any heterogeneity of interests within the first class of voters should lead to the election of less conservative MPs, even in initially purely agricultural areas.

FROM GROUP INTERESTS TO MP ORIENTATION

In the two-stage election system, where each class voted for electoral delegates who in turn elected MPs, the electoral college commands particular power. Kühne (Reference Kühne1994a, pp. 51–52) suggests that electoral delegates served as intermediaries between the electorate and MPs. Because the socio-economic background of delegates and first-class voters overlapped, the elite often succeed in electing their desired MP. Furthermore, a more concentrated economic elite will find it easier to coordinate on and influence electoral delegates, and in extension local MPs because smaller groups of homogeneous voters will find it easier to coordinate on outcomes.Footnote 22 Coordination costs are likely to be the lowest in the industrial urban areas because of higher population density, better transport infrastructure, and low information costs (Kühne Reference Kühne1994a, pp. 51–52). We therefore expect a stronger link between vote inequality and liberal voting in areas with industrial elites.

But there is another reason why the interests of industrial elites may have translated into a majority for liberal MPs in their constituencies: a strategic complementary between the interests of first- and third-class voters. It is often argued that during the second phase of industrialization, roughly corresponding to our period of analysis, industrial elites may have formed a strategic coalition with the third class to support policies that are mutually beneficial for capitalists and workers (also, see Galor and Moav Reference Galor and Moav2006; Doepke and Zilibotti Reference Doepke and Zilibotti2008; Llavador and Oxoby Reference Llavador and Oxoby2005), for example, free public schooling and freedom of occupational choice that benefited both industrialists and workers.

In summary, we expect higher vote inequality to be associated with the election of MPs with more liberal viewpoints, especially in districts with large-scale industry.

Results from Selected RCVs

Before we analyze the relationship between aggregate measures of political orientation and vote inequality, we present examples of specific roll calls in which vote inequality explains the voting behavior of MPs.Footnote 23 For this regression analysis, we select five RCVs that meet the following criteria: substantial relevance for the Prussian economy, substantial divide between liberal and conservative positions, sufficiently narrow margin so that the result may be altered by reasonable changes in inequality, and broad coverage of topics and election periods.

Table 2 presents results from regressions of an indicator variable (yea/nay) on a Gini index of vote inequality for each of the five RCVs.Footnote 24 Results reflect a linear probability model where vote inequality affects the probability to vote “yea.” In each RCV, we determine whether a “yea” vote reflects liberal or conservative position by the fact that the majority of MPs from conservative or liberal parties voted for the position (see top of Table 2 for positions). Throughout, we control for a Gini index of landownership inequality, the most important aspect of the political economy according to the literature.Footnote 25 A more detailed summary of the parliamentary debates surrounding each RCV can be found in Online Appendix B.

Table 2 RESULTS FOR SELECTED ROLL CALL VOTES

* = Significant at the 10% level.

** = Significant at the 5% level.

*** = Significant at the 1% level.

Notes: This table reports results from linear probability models estimated for five individual RCVs. The roll calls are nr. 44 in election period 10 (Column (1)), nr. 65 in election period 10 (Column (2)), nr. 1 in election period 14 (Column (3)), nr. 10 in election period 17 (Column (4)), and nr. 6 in election period 19 (Column (5)). The binary dependent variable assumes the value one for yea and the value zero for nay votes. Vote inequality (sd) and landownership inequality (sd) are standardized with zero mean and a standard deviation of one. We denote the conservative (C) and liberal (L) position at the top of the table. A position is coded as conservative if the majority of MPs from the conservative parties voted for it, and vice versa. Standard errors, clustered at the constituency level, in parentheses.

Source: See Online Appendix C for data sources.

Across the five roll calls, we find that MPs from districts with a higher vote inequality have a higher probability of voting for the liberal position. Column (1) shows results from a RCV on the King’s bill to re-introduce school tuition fees. Since 1850, the Prussian constitution stipulated that public primary schooling was tuition free so that municipalities were required to finance schooling from taxation or other local sources. In 1869, the King proposed to revoke free tuition and was defeated by a liberal majority.

Column (2) shows results from a RCV within the debate about the major administrative reform of 1872 (Kreisordnung) that effectively ended police authority of the landed nobility. The amendment to the bill, introduced by a liberal MP, proposed that the newly introduced role of a public official (Amtshauptmann) should be filled following a selection by the local administration instead of an appointment by the King. This amendment about the decentralization of power passed with a liberal majority.

Column (3) shows results from a RCV on section 1 of the Trade Ministry’s bill that allowed the state to buy private railroad companies. The bill passed with a conservative majority and led to the nationalization of railroads in 1880. In Table B.1 in the Online Appendix, we show that vote inequality is significantly associated with voting against the bill once a larger set of control variables is included.

Column (4) shows the results from a RCV in the context of the debate about the famous income tax reform of 1891 (Hill Reference Hill1892). MPs voted on an amendment to section 16 of the bill regarding the taxation of income from investment in joint stock companies (e.g., dividends). This conservative amendment requesting a 3.5 percent deduction passed whereas a competing liberal amendment requesting a 4 percent deduction was defeated by a conservative majority.

Column (5) shows results from a RCV on a proposal to construct the Dortmund-Rhine segment of a canal connecting the rivers Rhine and Elbe, introduced by the Kaiser in 1899. Conservatives opposed the canal construction and defeated the bill because it would be detrimental to agrarian interest and would foster the import of cheap grain from the United States.

The findings allow us to discuss a thought experiment, in which we can understand how policies would have changed if vote inequality had been different (ceteris paribus). The results imply that when increasing vote inequality by one standard deviation (0.039 Gini points), the probability of voting for the liberal position increases by up to 20 percent. In two out of five RCVs such a change in inequality would have tipped the balance towards adopting the more liberal policy, in two cases the liberal majority would have been even larger, and in one case the result would remain unchanged.

MODEL AND DATA

To estimate the relationship between the political orientation of MPs and the vote inequality in their electoral constituency, we generate a dataset in which the unit of observation is an MP, or more precisely, MP-by-constituency. The reason for the subtle distinction is that a small number of MPs (104 cases) represent different constituencies over their career.Footnote 26 Our results are robust to using MPs who represent the same district throughout their career. We employ the following standard OLS framework:

(1) $${PolI{d_{ic}} = \alpha + \beta VoteIne{q_c} + \gamma X_c^{'} + \zeta Z_i^{'} + {\varepsilon _{ic}},}$$

where Pol Id ic constitutes a measure of political orientation of an MP i in constituency c. We use the OC algorithm (described in the next section) to construct continuously valued scores describing the voting behavior of MPs across all RCVs in which they participate. In fact, the OC algorithm will give us two OC scores, one capturing a liberal-conservative dimension, and one capturing a secular-religious dimension.Footnote 27 Vote Ineq c is our measure of vote inequality, calculated from the distribution of voters across the three classes. ${X_c^{'}}$ is a vector of constituency-level characteristics and ${Z_i^{'}}$ is a vector of individual-level MP characteristics.

Vote Inequality

Vote inequality is a Gini coefficient calculated from the distribution of voters across the three classes. Using the fact that each class contributed exactly one-third to the tax base, we calculate the Gini coefficient based on the number of voters in each class. Notice that vote inequality assigns the same power to each voter in the same class so that we do not require information about the complete, individual-level tax contributions in a constituency.Footnote 28

An individual qualified for the first class by crossing a threshold that was determined by last year’s tax payments of all voters in a municipality. The threshold is therefore determined by local conditions and not by a national classification. This consideration helps to alleviate concerns regarding endogeneity in vote inequality. The classification of voters is strongly affected by the individual with the highest income in a municipality, leading to extreme heterogeneity in the threshold determining inclusion in the first class.

Two examples may clarify the arbitrary nature of classification as discussed by contemporaries (Königlich Preußisches Statistisches Bureau 1861–1904, vol. 2, p. 109). In the election of 1861, in a ward in the county Schleiden (province Rheinland) each of the three voters with the highest tax contributions paid 270 thalers.Footnote 29 Two of them were allocated to the first class whereas the third was allocated to the second class,Footnote 30 where he had to share his vote with ten other taxpayers who jointly paid only 260 thalers in taxes. In a ward in the county Belgard (province Pomerania), the first class was populated by two voters paying 364 and 237 thalers in taxes, respectively, the second class was populated by another two voters paying 213 and 189 thalers in taxes, while the third class was populated by 160 voters with one paying 102 thalers and the remaining 159 voters combined paying 396 thalers in total. These examples show that the local economic elite did not, by definition, end up being eligible for voting in the first class. Put differently, small differences in income at the top could move individuals across classes, with substantial consequences for individual voting weights and power.

Across Prussia, on average, the threshold to become a first-class voter was a payment of 56 thalers in taxes. However, regional variation was extreme: the minimum threshold was 7 and the maximum threshold was 12,496 thalers. If an individual taxpayer contributed more than half of the total local tax base, the second class even remained unpopulated. Given that the local distribution of incomes was decisive, variation in residential location of high-income earners led to huge heterogeneity, especially in urban areas. Before a reform in 1891, municipalities first determined tax payment thresholds based on the city-wide population of voters, before subsequently breaking the electorate into wards. In wards with many high-income voters, the first class was crowded, leading to a relative devaluation of a vote. In poor wards, the first and sometimes even the second class remained empty if none of the voters crossed the city-wide threshold.

The previous examples imply that there is strong heterogeneity in the distribution of voters across classes and that the allocation of voters to classes is beyond the power of the individual. In our standard regression framework, we aim to exclude remaining systematic heterogeneity by conditioning on a substantial set of control variables. In a robustness check, we use an IV approach that exploits heterogeneity in the size of the first class, exploiting the fact—described previously—that the richest individual’s income was decisive for its size.

The earliest available measure of vote inequality for all constituencies of post-1866 Prussia is from 1893 and reported in Königlich Preußisches Statistisches Bureau (1864–1905, vol. 17).Footnote 31 Our analysis will test robustness of the results using the distribution of voters across classes from the election of 1861. These data are less prone to potential reverse causality but are unavailable for the new provinces annexed by Prussia after 1866, that means we lose more than 350 MPs.

Constituency Characteristics

Constituency-level control variables are aggregated from county-level data provided by Galloway (Reference Galloway2007) and iPEHD (Becker et al. Reference Becker, Francesco, Erik and Woessmann2014). Electoral constituencies comprised at least one, but typically several (administrative) counties (Kreise). Put differently, the approximately 500 Prussian counties are nested in 256 electoral constituencies, allowing us to map aggregated county-level census data to MPs representing these constituencies.Footnote 32 Table C.1 in Online Appendix C presents summary statistics.

Following the literature (Lehmann Reference Lehmann2010b; Mares and Queralt Reference Mares and Queralt2014; Ziblatt Reference Ziblatt2008), we include a set of standard explanatory variables for MP voting behavior in the Prussian House of Representatives in our vector of constituency characteristics.

The most important control variable is landownership inequality capturing Gerschenkron’s idea of a link between the interests of large landowners and conservative voting.Footnote 33

Other control variables include the industrial employment share, the urbanization rate, the share of Protestants, the linguistic fractionalization, the share of the population that lives in their municipality of birth, as well as the literacy rate to capture heterogeneity in the available stock of human capital.Footnote 34 These indicators measure differences in development, cultural heterogeneity, and structural differences across regions.

The period under analysis is a critical juncture in the transition from agriculture to industry. At the beginning of the period, slightly less than half of the population was based in agriculture. At the end, agricultural employment made up merely one-third of the labor force. However, these structural changes may be an outcome of the political process and therefore prone to concerns of reverse causality. Thus, in our regressions we include variables that are measured closest to the starting point of our analysis in 1867.Footnote 35 If an MP represents the average individual in his constituency, we expect local conditions to explain a large part of the variation of MPs’ voting behavior. However, if MPs represent the local elite but also act in their own interest, individual characteristics may explain a lot of the variation. We can probe this by also controlling for MP characteristics.

MP Characteristics

MP characteristics drawn from Kühne (Reference Kühne1994b) vary at the individual level and can be broadly divided into biographic and political characteristics. Table C.2 in Online Appendix C presents summary statistics.

BIOGRAPHIC CHARACTERISTICS OF MPS

Biographic characteristics include the occupation of an MP as reported in the parliamentary minutes. We coded occupations to match the following six categories: public administration, clergy, industry, agriculture, education, and services.Footnote 36 Roughly one-third (789) of the MPs in the data set report agriculture, in other words, landownership, as their main occupation. Landowners have a higher probability of being affiliated with conservative parties.Footnote 37 On the other hand, industrialists predominantly select into liberal parties.Footnote 38

The religious denomination of MPs roughly reflects the distribution within the population. In 1880, the population of the average Prussian constituency was composed of 67.2 percent Protestants, 31.4 percent Catholics, and 1.1 percent Jews. Protestants are slightly over-represented in parliament, while Catholics and Jews are slightly under-represented.Footnote 39 Two-thirds of the Catholic MPs are affiliated with the Centre party and the Polish minority party. We expect them to lean towards policies that support a strong position of the church. Additional attributes that are available from MP biographies include nobility status, academic titles, residence in the electoral constituency, and retirement status.Footnote 40

POLITICAL CHARACTERISTICS OF MPS

Further variables capture the parliamentary engagement of an MP and the context in which he was elected. RCV participation measures the share of the total RCVs in a period in which the MP participated.Footnote 41 The electoral margin captures the strength of the mandate and whether the MP seat was strongly contested.Footnote 42 The electoral turnout captures the level of representation (see, e.g., Jackman Reference Jackman1987).Footnote 43 The count of the number of MPs to be elected in the constituency captures electoral competition.Footnote 44

In a robustness test, we include measures of party affiliation as control variables. These are not a regressors like any others: by virtue of parties’ ability to draw like-minded representatives to stand for them, we expect party affiliation to absorb a substantial part of the variation in OC scores.

MEASURING POLITICAL ORIENTATION USING OPTIMAL CLASSIFICATION

To understand whether the franchise biased parliamentary voting patterns, we inspect MPs’ overall voting behavior instead of voting in single roll calls or changes in voting behavior over time.Footnote 45 This requires us to classify all votes into categories that reflect a political orientation. Manually classifying votes from 329 roll calls into liberal and conservative (or into secular and religious) leanings is a task that would be prone to many arbitrary decisions.

Simply reading minutes of parliamentary debates preceding RCVs, we could gain a nuanced impression of speakers’ positions but still incorrectly classify MP positions because debates do not reveal underlying rationales of voting choices. Furthermore, classification requires the strong assumption that all MPs perceive the political dimension underlying a vote in the same way. Even a selected subset of RCVs may lead to erroneous classification. Suppose we selected a set of RCVs that evolve around secular-religious motives during the Kulturkampf, including a vote on a bill that exempts priests from punishment for reading mass and administering the sacraments. It will be hard for us to classify whether an MP’s vote is motivated by his allegiance to the Pope, his support of Bismarck, or his liberal orientation that rejects state intervention. Votes may indeed reflect multiple motives and dimensions that are obscured. Manually determining how to code “yea” or “nay” votes in any RCV requires us to make assumptions about the position of all MPs in this matter.

To avoid the pitfalls of “manual” classification, political science has developed scaling methods that are widely used in the analysis of parliamentary voting. In our main approach, we follow this literature and analyze RCVs using the non-parametric OC method introduced by Poole (Reference Poole2000).Footnote 46 Similar to a principal component analysis, the OC method extracts one or more latent variables from the votes that are fed into the algorithm. This approach is superior to a researcher’s classification because decisions will not be biased by prior knowledge (and interpretation) of the content of the RCVs or the party affiliation of MPs. The algorithm does not rely on an ex ante classification but allows an ex post interpretation of the latent dimensions it uncovers.

OC is a non-parametric scaling procedure that classifies a matrix of yea and nay votes.Footnote 47 After generating an “agreement matrix” between MPs, the algorithm extracts coordinates that locate MPs within a policy space using a pre-specified number of dimension. For simplicity, suppose that voting in parliament is exclusively driven by one dimension—liberal or conservative motives. The OC method interprets votes of MPs as revealed preferences from a choice between a proposed policy and the status quo. The underlying assumptions are that legislators have Euclidean preferences defined over the policy space and that they vote sincerely for the alternative closest to their “ideal point.”Footnote 48 Since neither the exact position of the proposed policy nor the status quo is known, we only observe two positions reflecting “yea” or “nay” votes. These two positions can be intersected by a cutting line separating groups of legislators with different positions. To illustrate this procedure, in Online Appendix Section D, we show the policy space and the cutting lines for the five selected RCVs discussed earlier. Using a larger number of RCVs allows us to estimate MP positions more precisely due to varying distances between ideal points, proposal, and the status quo. The OC algorithm will produce a rank ordering of MPs and vectors of relative distances that constitute the latent dimensions.

OC Results for the Prussian Parliament

Our main analysis pools all 329 RCVs across ten election periods providing us with substantial variation in political orientation within parties. Each MP representing the same constituency during one or several election periods constitutes one observation, similar to the “fixed career model” described in Asmussen and Jo (Reference Asmussen and Jo2016). The various issues voted on over this long period are such that party discipline cannot be always imposed, giving us substantial within-party variation in political orientation. Pooling across periods also reduces the impact of outliers, and the resulting ideal points are more likely to represent an unbiased measure of constituency-level policy preferences.

However, some MPs switched their party affiliation over time.Footnote 49 While we assign party affiliation based on the party for which an MP casts the highest number of votes, this ignores the possibility that party switches might reflect genuine movement in some MPs’ political orientation. However, in Becker and Hornung (Reference Becker and Hornung2019), we show that findings are qualitatively similar when inspecting election periods separately, thus allowing for party switching and relaxing restrictions on legislators’ ability to move within the policy space.

We identified roll calls by working through the universe of parliamentary minutes. For all RCVs, minutes list the name of MPs and record “yea” and “nay” votes as well as abstentions and absence.Footnote 50 We coded these votes and matched MPs by name and period of activity to the Kühne (Reference Kühne1994b) dataset that provides us with biographical information and constituency identifiers. The quality of the match was manually checked using all available historical sources.

Table 3 presents descriptive information generated when scaling the RCV data with the OC method. The analysis is limited to legislators who voted in at least 15 RCVs and excludes extremely lopsided votes where the losing side consisted of less than 2.5 percent of MPs.Footnote 51 These criteria apply to 328 of the 329 RCVs and to 1,903 of 2,291 MPs, amounting to a total of 107,282 individual votes (58,540 yea and 48,742 nay). Abstentions and absence during an RCV are coded as missing values. Similar to Häge (Reference Häge2019) who analyzes the Reichstag during the Bismarck era, we find abstentions to be rare (487 votes) but absenteeism to be substantial.

Table 3 PREDICTION OF VOTING BEHAVIOR ACROSS PARLIAMENTS FROM 1867–1903

Notes: This table reports descriptive statistics of MP’s voting behavior. Column (1) lists the number of scaled RCVs. Column (2) lists the number of MPs that actively cast at least one vote during the whole period. Column (3) lists the number of scaled MPs with a minimum requirement of 15 votes. Columns (4) and (5) list the percentage of correctly classified yea and nay votes and the Average Proportion Reductions in Error (APRE) predicted by the OC process for the one-dimensional case. Columns (6) and (7) list the same for the two-dimensional case. Columns (8)–(10) list the eigenvalues for the first three dimensions.

Source: See Online Appendix C for data sources.

Table 3 also provides information on the correct classification of votes (Columns (5) and (7)), the Average Proportional Reduction in Error (APRE) (Columns (6) and (8)),Footnote 52 and eigenvalues (Columns (9) to (11)) comparing a one-dimensional and a two-dimensional case. We correctly classify 89.4 percent of votes when assuming one dimension and can increase the accuracy of classification to 96 percent when adding a second dimension. Comparing APREs, we find that two-dimensional scaling substantially improves the error reduction by approximately 17 percentage points. Comparing eigenvalues, we find that the third is considerably smaller suggesting that parliamentary debates may be sufficiently described by two dimensions.Footnote 53, Footnote 54 We label the two dimensions of Pol Id ic the liberal-conservative and secular-religious dimensions.

The Policy Space for the Prussian Parliament

The output of the OC algorithm, the two dimensions of an MP’s political orientation, Pol Id ic, are presented in Figure 2(a). Assuming a two-dimensional policy space, the OC procedure generates two coordinates that reveal the position of each MP within a unit circle, in other words, coordinates assume values between –1 and +1. Colors and letters indicate party membership as presented in Table 1. We find that MPs belonging to the same party are spatially clustered, reflecting the fact that parties are groups of like-minded representatives. Using information about the political landscape in Prussia outlined earlier, we interpret the two dimensions as a liberal-conservative and a secular-religious dimension, reflecting the main cleavages between parties in parliament. Even though parliament did not capture the full spectrum of political views (remember the absence of Social Democrats), it included parties advocating ideas of liberalism as outlined in the introduction and parties advocating conservative views with preferences for a strong monarchy and adherence to the feudal class structure. At the same time, parliament included parties advocating conflicting views about secularization and preservation of the church’s power.

Figure 2 THE PRUSSIAN POLICY SPACE DURING ELECTION PERIODS 10–19

Notes: Positions of MPs in the Prussian House of Representatives. Each shape represents the political orientation of an MP based on his voting behavior during all roll calls in the period 1867–1903. Figure (b) is rotated to fix the centroid of the Conservative Party (K) to the horizontal axis. Figure (c) is rotated to fix the centroid of the Centre Party (Z) to the vertical axis.

Source: See Online Appendix C for data sources.

Since the OC algorithm is agnostic about the spatial orientation of its output, we anchor the policy space using leaders of the Conservative and Centre parties.Footnote 55 To guarantee that the two dimensions and the corresponding MP-level positions exactly reflect liberal-conservative and secular-religious cleavages, we rotate the policy space to align the centroid of the Conservative Party with the horizontal axis and the centroid of the Centre Party with the vertical axis (see Figures 2(b) and 2(c)).Footnote 56 Both rotations look very much alike.

On the conservative-liberal axis (see Figure 2(b)), Left Liberals (yellow F) and National Liberals (green N) are almost exclusively located in the western regions of this axis. Free Conservatives (grey R) and Conservatives (blue K) are positioned in the eastern part of the policy space. Members of the Centre Party (red Z) and of minority groups (brown M) are divided between liberal and conservative positions but many lean toward moderate conservative positions. On the secular-religious axis, while Centre Party MPs exclusively locate on the religious side of the secular-religious axis, MPs from the National Liberals and Free Conservatives can be found in the secular southern region. However, since the Conservative Party was divided over secularization and “orthodox” Protestant MPs sympathized with the position of the Centre Party, we find considerable variation across liberal and conservative parties.Footnote 57

We confirm the graphical observations of a clear ranking of parties along the liberal-conservative spectrum in OLS regressions presented in Column (1) of Table 4. Here, we regress MP’s positions in the liberal-conservative dimension on their party affiliation, using the Conservative Party as omitted category. The results thus depict the relative position of all other parties. As expected, the coefficient on Left Liberals reveals the largest distance to MPs from the Conservative Party, followed by the National Liberals. Similarly, in Column (2), coefficients on Free Conservatives and National Liberals reveal the largest distance to the (omitted) Centre Party along the secular-religious dimension. As expected, the mostly Catholic and pro-religious members of minority parties hold positions that are closely aligned with the Centre Party in this dimension. Note that the R2 in these regressions is 0.62 and 0.47, respectively, in other words, while party affiliation matters for MPs’ position, there is still substantial within-party variation left.

Table 4 PARTY AFFILIATION AND POLITICAL ORIENTATION

* = Significant at the 10% level.

** = Significant at the 5% level.

*** = Significant at the 1% level.

Notes: This table reports results of OLS regressions of political orientation on vote inequality in a sample of MPs with at least 15 votes in the period 1867–1903. Column (1) - Positive values of the dependent variable are interpreted to reflect higher levels of conservative orientation; negative values reflect liberal orientation. Column (2) - Positive values of the dependent variable are interpreted to reflect higher levels of adherence to the church; negative values reflect secular orientation. Standard errors, clustered at the constituency level, in parentheses.

Source: See Online Appendix C for data sources.

RESULTS AND INTERPRETATION

In this section, we will use Pol Id ic, the two dimensions of an MP’s political orientation derived from the OC method (displayed in Figure 2), as dependent variables in the regression framework described by Equation (1). In all specifications we cluster standard errors at the level of constituencies.

Main Results in the Liberal-Conservative Dimension

Table 5 presents results from OLS regressions using the liberal-conservative dimension as dependent variable. Column (1) shows the most parsimonious model explaining liberal-conservative political orientation with two measures of inequality—vote inequality and landownership inequality. Vote inequality is negatively associated with political orientation. MPs from constituencies with a more unequal distribution of voters across classes vote significantly more for liberal policies. This central finding qualifies the predominant assumption in the literature that the franchise system produced conservative policies. While it is true that the three-class franchise kept Social Democrats at bay until 1908, higher vote inequality is associated with more liberal policies. In line with the widely held belief, however, we find MPs from constituencies with a more unequal distribution of landownership to have a more conservative orientation.

Table 5 VOTE INEQUALITY AND LIBERAL-CONSERVATIVE ORIENTATION

* = Significant at the 10% level.

** = Significant at the 5% level.

*** = Significant at the 1% level.

Notes: This table reports results of OLS regressions of liberal-conservative orientation on vote inequality in a sample of MPs with at least 15 votes in the period 1867–1903. Positive values of the dependent variable are interpreted to reflect higher levels of conservative orientation; negative values reflect liberal orientation. Standard errors, clustered at the constituency level, in parentheses.

Source: See Online Appendix C for data sources.

Subsequent columns add control variables that potentially affect the political orientation of MPs. By including them, we try to rule out that the effect of vote inequality is driven by economic development. Furthermore, we include several measures of cultural heterogeneity that are expected to correspond to secular-religious voting much more than liberal-conservative voting.Footnote 58

Columns (2) and (3) add the industrial employment share and the urbanization share to capture structural differences in the economic development of regions. More industrialized and urbanized constituencies are expected to be more progressive and thus prefer more liberal politics. Indeed, both variables are negatively associated with political orientation. At the same time, more industrialized/urbanized areas are more unequal. It is therefore not surprising that controlling for these variables, the magnitude of the inequality coefficient is reduced (but remains highly significant).

Columns (4)–(6) sequentially add the share of Protestants, the linguistic fractionalization, and the share of non-migrants to the model. Religious denomination and language heterogeneity pick up differences between the political orientation of Catholic regions in the West, the central Protestant regions, and the Slavic regions in the East. Since Protestant regions are more developed than Catholic regions, conditional on industrialization and urbanization, this variable may predict a more liberal orientation. Linguistic fractionalization is highest in the Slavic regions of Prussia that may oppose the national-conservative policies of Bismarck. A higher share of the population living in their municipality of birth is expected to reflect lower levels of openness and a more conservative orientation. However, these factors do not seem to play an important role in affecting liberal-conservative voting once a variable accounting for the literacy rate is included in Column (7). The literacy rate is a significant predictor of conservative voting. This finding may be explained by the fact that conservative parties appealed to a more literate Protestant electorate. The literacy seems to capture conservative Protestants better than the overall share of Protestants, which becomes significantly negative upon joint inclusion.Footnote 59

Across all specifications, we find vote inequality to be systematically associated with more liberal voting. In terms of magnitude, the coefficient on vote inequality in Column (7) means that a one standard deviation increase in the Gini index is associated with a 0.177 standard deviation decrease in conservative orientation.Footnote 60 In other words, moving an MP from a constituency at the 10th percentile (~0.47) of the vote inequality distribution to the 90th percentile (~0.58), he will shift his orientation by 19.7 percent toward the liberal maximum.

Placebo Test in the Secular-Religious Dimension

Table 6 presents results from a placebo test in which we use the secular-religious dimension as a dependent variable. We expect this dimension to be uncorrelated with vote inequality because the process of secularization in Germany transcended class structures and should not be reflected in the distribution of voting power. Indeed, we find that the correlation between vote inequality and secular-religious orientation is entirely spurious. While vote inequality seems to predict more secular voting behavior in Columns (1)–(3), the coefficient is close to zero, once the share of Protestants in the constituency is considered. Not surprisingly, the share of Protestants is in itself a strong predictor of secular voting behavior.

Table 6 VOTE INEQUALITY AND SECULAR-RELIGIOUS ORIENTATION

* = Significant at the 10% level.

** = Significant at the 5% level.

*** = Significant at the 1% level.

Notes: This table reports results of OLS regressions of secular-religious orientation on vote inequality in a sample of MPs with at least 15 votes in the period 1867–1903. Positive values of the dependent variable are interpreted to reflect higher levels of adherence to the church; negative values reflect secular orientation. Standard errors, clustered at the constituency level, in parentheses.

Source: See Online Appendix C for data sources.

This finding reflects the strong cleavage between Centre party MPs elected in the Catholic regions and MPs from Protestant regions that strongly favored a separation of church and state.

Furthermore, higher linguistic fractionalization is associated with more secular voting. In this dimension, linguistically more heterogenous regions encompass a larger share of minorities that may indeed favor policies that restrict a church that caters only to one religious denomination. In sum, this placebo test finds that the secular-religious orientation, which arguably transcended economic heterogeneity, is unrelated to vote inequality.

Robustness Tests

This subsection tests the robustness of our findings to potential alternative explanations and confounding factors. Robustness tests are presented in Table 7, where Panel A displays results for the liberal-conservative orientation and Panel B displays results for the secular-religious (placebo) orientation. For the sake of clarity in presentation, this table does not show coefficients of the control variables. We mention some of them and will particularly focus on Panel A.

Table 7 ROBUSTNESS CHECKS

* = Significant at the 10% level.

** = Significant at the 5% level.

*** = Significant at the 1% level.

Notes: This table reports results of OLS regressions in a sample of MPs with at least 15 votes in the period 1867–1903. Panel A - Positive values of the dependent variable are interpreted to reflect higher levels of conservative orientation; negative values reflect liberal orientation. Panel B - Positive values of the dependent variable are interpreted to reflect higher levels of adherence to the church; negative values reflect secular orientation. Column (1) Baseline Spec. repeats results from Column (7) in Tables 5 and 6. Column (2) Income Tax adds a control for the average per-capita tax payments in a constituency in 1878. The lower number of observations is due to missing values for city counties. Column (3) Social Uprisings adds a control for the number of violent protests in a constituency during the 1816–1867 time period. Column (4) MP Controls adds the full set of MP controls as shown in Table C.2 in the Online Appendix. The lower number of observations is due to missing values for electoral margin and turnout. Column (5) District Dummies adds a full set of 35 administrative district (Regierungsbezirk) fixed effects. Column (6) Party Controls add a set of party affiliation controls, defined as the share of active election periods an MP was affiliated with each of the parties. Column (7) 1861 Sample is estimated in a sample of regions that were part of Prussia prior to 1866. Column (8) 1861 Vote Inequality test robustness to substituting the vote inequality measured in 1893 with a 1861 measure that is only available in the smaller sample. Standard errors, clustered at the constituency level, in parentheses.

Source: See Online Appendix C for data sources.

Column (1) repeats the baseline specification (Column (7) from Table 5) before adding a control for per capita payments of direct taxes to the model in Column (2). By doing so, we address the concern that vote inequality is a mere proxy for the average income in an electoral constituency.Footnote 61 Results on vote inequality remain qualitatively unchanged but coefficients are slightly larger.

Column (3) adds a control for social uprisings that took place in a constituency between 1815 and 1867. This measure captures a threat of socially motivated unrest that loomed strongly during this period. The threat of social democracy may have pushed MPs from electoral constituencies with higher vote inequality toward more liberal voting. While we indeed find that MPs from constituencies with more protests vote slightly more liberally, our main result remains unchanged.Footnote 62

Results may be driven by observable characteristics of the individual MPs. If the peculiarities of the franchise system selected a certain type of MP into office, this would constitute a mechanism through which vote inequality might affect political orientation. However, if MP characteristics reflect characteristics (and preferences) of the local elite, these may determine both inequality and political orientation and present a threat to identification. In Column (4), the coefficients on vote inequality and landownership inequality are substantially reduced but the results remain qualitatively unchanged. As expected, conservative orientation is predicted by MPs holding occupations in public administration and agriculture, by noble status, and by Catholic denomination. These variables also explain a large share of the variation as measured by the R-squared.

Results displayed in Column (5) show that adding 35 administrative-district (Regierungsbezirk) fixed effects leaves the relationship of interest barely affected while the coefficient on landownership inequality is substantially reduced. Thus, broad regional disparities between the agricultural east and the industrial west do not explain the relationship between vote inequality and political orientation.

In Table 4, we have shown that party affiliation is a strong predictor of voting behavior. Our subsequent empirical framework has exploited variation across parties ignoring affiliation. Indeed, we think that party affiliation reflects much of the differences in political orientation that we are actually interested in. Controlling for party affiliation thus only allows us to exploit within-party variation in political orientation, which by definition, is much more limited. Nevertheless, Column (6) shows that, even conditional on party affiliation, MPs vote significantly more for liberal policies when elected in a constituency with a higher vote inequality.

As indicated before, our main measure of vote inequality refers to 1893, the first time it is available for post-1866 Prussia. We test robustness of the results using a Gini index of vote inequality from 1861 for the subset of constituencies reflecting the contemporary Prussian borders. Column (7) re-estimates the model with individual-level controls in the smaller sample of 1861 constituencies. Column (8) shows that results are barely different from the findings in Column (7) when using the 1861 measure of vote inequality.

Columns (1)–(8) in Panel B repeat the previously noted regressions for the secular-religious placebo dimension. Adding more control variables, administrative-district fixed effects, party affiliation, or replacing vote inequality with its 1861 measure does not change the relationship between vote inequality and secular-religious orientation.

Additional robustness tests are presented in Becker and Hornung (Reference Becker and Hornung2019), where we confirm that findings are qualitatively similar when inspecting the ten election periods separately. The relationship between conservative orientation and vote inequality remains negative over time. This rules out the possibility that the results are driven by the relative dominance of liberal policies prior to Bismarck’s conservative turn in 1878.

Mitigating Potential Endogeneity Concerns

Despite the extensive number of control variables, our estimates may be biased if unobserved variables correlate with both the distribution of voters across classes and the political orientation of the MP. We address this concern in an IV approach that exploits variation in the share of voters in the first class. As discussed in the section on vote inequality, the local threshold that allocates voters to the three classes is somewhat arbitrary. Assignment to the first class is not within an individual’s power but is largely determined by the share of tax payments coming from the individual with the highest income. The exact number of voters in the first class is therefore plausibly exogenous to systematic heterogeneity in local conditions. Note, however, that we do not want to suggest that this is similar to randomly assigning votes to individuals but rather similar to arbitrarily changing voting power within the economic elite.

The exclusion restriction requires that the share of voters in the first class affects the political orientation of MPs only indirectly, through vote inequality. We argue that this assumption holds because it seems plausible that the share of individuals endowed with higher voting power because of local income thresholds can only affect MP voting patterns via the inherent features of the three-class franchise.Footnote 63 Consider a hypothetical example of two constituencies with an identical number of taxpayers. In both constituencies A and B, the top two taxpayers pay 200 and 100 thalers of tax, respectively. Due to the distribution of tax payments of all other taxpayers outside the top 2, in constituency A, the top taxpayer (paying 200 thalers) is the only member of the first class, whereas in constituency B, the top two taxpayers are both members of the first class. In other words, the share of taxpayers in the first class is twice as high in constituency B than in constituency A. The exclusion restriction amounts to saying that the one and only first-class voter in constituency A affects political outcomes in his constituency only by virtue of the fact that the resulting vote inequality inherent in the three-class franchise gives him more power, but not because his position in the income distribution per se has an effect on RCV outcomes. Since the distribution of top incomes is identical in constituencies A and B, this strikes us as a reasonable assumption.

Table 8 presents results comparing OLS results to a 2SLS approach using the share of voters in the first class as an instrument for vote inequality in 1861.Footnote 64 We find the coefficient on vote inequality to be marginally smaller when comparing our baseline findings on the liberal-conservative orientation in Column (1) to the findings in Column (3). The qualitative findings, however, remain unchanged, even when controlling for individual MP characteristics and party affiliation. The results for the secular-religious orientation are close to zero in the 2SLS regression, confirming the earlier findings of a lack of a relationship with vote inequality.

Table 8 MITIGATING ENDOGENEITY CONCERNS

* = Significant at the 10% level.

** = Significant at the 5% level.

*** = Significant at the 1% level.

Notes: This table reports results of OLS and 2SLS regressions. Columns (1) and (3)–(5): Positive values of the dependent variable are interpreted to reflect higher levels of conservative orientation; negative values reflect liberal orientation. Column (6) and (8)–(10): Positive values of the dependent variable are interpreted to reflect higher levels of adherence to the church; negative values reflect secular orientation. Columns (1) and (6) repeat baseline results in the 1861 sample. Columns (2)–(3) and (7)–(8) report the first and second stages of a 2SLS approach using the share of voters in the first class as an instrument for vote inequality. Columns (4) and (9) add the full set of MP controls. Columns (5) and (10) add a set of party affiliation controls, defined as the share of active election periods an MP was affiliated with each of the parties. Standard errors, clustered at the constituency level, in parentheses.

Source: See Online Appendix C for data sources.

Discussing the Mechanism

In this section, we explore our hypothesis that industrialization created a level of income inequality that allowed large-scale industrialists to elect MPs who provided liberal policies that were conducive to industrialists (see the conceptual framework section). In line with this reasoning, we expect the effect of vote inequality on liberal voting to be amplified in areas with a higher share of large firms. For this exercise, we digitized data on the number of large and small firms in a Prussian county, from the 1875 Census of Industrial Firms. In the census, large firms are defined as firms with at least five employees.

To probe the hypothesis, we define a dummy 𝟙 (% Large firms ≥q 75) for the upper quartile of the distribution of the share of large firms.Footnote 65 Table 9 shows the result from this exercise. In Column (1), we add the main effect of being in the upper quartile in terms of share of large firms as a regressor. The variable by itself does not affect voting behavior. In Column (2), we estimate an interaction term between vote inequality and the large firms dummy. We find that large firms are only associated with liberal voting if vote inequality is high. Note that our set of controls includes the industrial employment share, thus holding the general level of industrialization fixed.

Table 9 VOTE INEQUALITY AND INDUSTRIAL ELITES

* = Significant at the 10% level.

** = Significant at the 5% level.

*** = Significant at the 1% level.

Notes: This table reports results of OLS regressions in a sample of MPs with at least 15 votes in the period 1867–1903. Columns (1) and (2): Positive values of the dependent variable are interpreted to reflect higher levels of conservative orientation; negative values reflect liberal orientation. Column (3) and (4): Positive values of the dependent variable are interpreted to reflect higher levels of adherence to the church; negative values reflect secular orientation. 𝟙 (% Large firms ≥q 75) is equal to one if the constituency-level share of firms with more than five employees is in the highest quartile. Standard errors, clustered at the constituency level, in parentheses.

Source: See Online Appendix C for data sources.

We interpret these findings as evidence that industrialists were better able to coordinate on liberal policies when the electoral elite was small and benefited from a liberal economy. While we do not observe the characteristics of the electoral elite in our data, we think it is conceivable that in some regions industrialization created a level of income inequality that allowed large-scale industrialists to use the political power provided by the franchise system to commission a self-serving liberal agenda.

Columns (3) and (4) show that the concentration of large-scale industry does not matter for voting along the secular-religious placebo dimension.

CONCLUSION

The Prussian Parliament, with its three-class franchise has been widely described as conservative. In fact, Social Democrats did not enter until 1908, whereas they were represented in the Reichstag from the year it was founded, in 1871. However, the historical narrative often seems to conclude that the three-class franchise made for conservative policies because of the power it gave to landed elites. Our paper challenges this view. We exploit the voting behavior of MPs in 329 RCVs to predict political orientation using the OC method (Poole, Reference Poole2000). We find that—within the Prussian Parliament—higher local vote inequality is associated with a more liberal orientation of MPs.

Vote inequality as a result of the three-class franchise gave more votes to those paying more taxes. Our hypothesis is that, in late nineteenth century Prussia, this property of the franchise system gave a lot of voting power to new industrial elites. Using census data on the number of small and large firms, we show that the magnitude of our results is stronger in constituencies with a high concentration of large industrial firms. This corroborates our interpretation that large-scale industrialists were able to take advantage of the franchise system and elected delegates who voted for liberal policies. This finding also lends support to the view that historically, economic elites were not a monolithic conservative group, but that some may have favored liberalization and modernization for self-serving reasons.

Furthermore, this paper is the first to present a comprehensive picture of the Prussian policy space over ten election periods (1867–1903), covering a crucial period in the structural transformation of the German Empire from an agricultural to an industrial economy. We hope that our new constituency-level measures of liberal-conservative and secular-religious orientation of MPs will be useful for other researchers interested in understanding this fascinating period of the history of one of Europe’s leading economies.

Footnotes

We thank the Centre for Advanced Studies and the Centre for Economic Studies at the University of Munich for their kind hospitality. We thank Chris Anderson, Carles Boix, Marta Curto-Grau, Marc Debus, and Frank Häge as well as seminar audiences at the MPI for Tax Law and Public Finance, at the first German Congress for Economic and Social History in Münster, TU Darmstadt, ZEW Mannheim, the IPERG-UB Barcelona, and the Workshop Regional Economics and Local Political Economy in Siegen for comments. The editor and two anonymous referees gave excellent comments and guidance. We thank Niklas Gebhard, Philipp Höfer, Robin Mamrak, Maximilian Neumann, and Stephanie Spahn for research assistance. Support by the ESRC Centre for Competitive Advantage in the Global Economy (ESRC grant ES/L011719/1) is gratefully acknowledged.

1 For example, Hallerberg (Reference Hallerberg2002) argues that the electoral system was set up in a way that allowed parliament to amend the tax code to reduce the burden for large landowners.

2 See Geheimes Staatsarchiv, Preussischer Kulturbesitz, I HA Rep90 Staatsministerium St. M 9317, Berlin, 7 May, 1849, as cited in Ziblatt (Reference Ziblatt2008, p. 621).

3das Bollwerk des reaktionären Preußentums schlechthin.”

4 The period coincides with the transition from agriculture to industry (see, e.g., Reference Becker and HornungBecker, Hornung, and Woessmann 2011), the move from free trade to protectionism at the national level (see, e.g., Lehmann Reference Lehmann2010b), the secularization of society (see, e.g., Becker and Woessmann 2013; Becker, Nagler, and Woessmann 2017), the introduction of a welfare state (see, e.g., Bauernschuster, Driva, and Hornung Reference Bauernschuster, Driva and Hornung2020; Lehmann-Hasemeyer and Streb Reference Lehmann-Hasemeyer and Streb2017), and the demographic transition (see, e.g., Becker, Cinnirella, and Woessmann Reference Becker, Cinnirella and Woessmann2010).

5 The competing hypothesis holds that elites adopt policies in favor of the lower classes because of a prevailing threat of revolution by the masses (Acemoglu and Robinson Reference Acemoglu and Robinson2000; Aidt and Franck 2015). On the other hand, Aidt and Jensen (2017) argue that the introduction of the secret ballot in the United States and Europe came as a by-product of the process of modernization due to the decline of social control and vote buying.

6 The dimensionalities of the Reichstag during the later Weimar period and the earlier Frankfurt National Assembly are depicted by Hansen and Debus (Reference Hansen and Debus2012) and Herrmann and Sieberer (Reference Herrmann and Sieberer2019), respectively.

7 Lehmann-Hasemeyer, Hauber, and Opitz (Reference Lehmann-Hasemeyer, Hauber and Opitz2014) show that the Berlin Stock Exchange reacted negatively to the extension of the franchise in Saxony in 1896 and 1909.

8 Debus and Hansen (2014) use several Weimar Republic roll calls to study the voting behavior of women in parliament. Lehmann (Reference Lehmann2010a) analyzes several RCVs from the Reichstag during the Weimar Republic to analyze how coalitions formed between MPs of different parties.

9 The most prominent example was the industrialist Alfred Krupp who was the only voter in the first class in his ward. However, the pattern can also be found in rural wards where the income distribution was dominated by a local noble estate owner.

10 In cases when several smaller municipalities were combined into one ward, thresholds were determined at the ward level.

11 The tax reform of 1891 and the subsequent voting reform for the 1893 election introduced classification of voters according to ward-level thresholds. This led to the arbitrary upgrading of low-income voters into the first and second class in poor quarters and downgrading of high-income voters into the second and third class in wealthy quarters. According to the most prominent example, the Chancellor of the German Empire, Bernhard von Bülow, was required to vote in the third class in 1903, because he lived in the Reich Chancellery, which was located within the ward with the highest tax base in Berlin.

12 Because voting in primary elections was not secret, voters in the upper tercile, who often were employers of those in the lower terciles, held coercive power. Thus, even if we had information on voting behavior by the third class in primary elections, they would not necessarily reveal true preferences. Intimidating behavior by industrial employers, rural landlords, and public officials has been documented for elections of other contemporary German parliaments including the Reichstag and the Prussian House of Representatives (Kühne Reference Kühne1994a; Mares Reference Mares2015; Ziblatt Reference Ziblatt2009).

13 Twenty four percent of Prussian MPs were members of the two parliaments at the same time for at least one year (those who were, on average 6.7 years; MPs overall, on average 1.6 years). Concerns that MPs who belonged to both parliaments were systematically different can be addressed with a dummy variable for dual membership. In unreported regressions, we find that adding such a control variable does not change our results.

14 In some cases when party affiliation was uncertain, we used the most likely party affiliation given in Kühne (Reference Kühne1994b). Party changes within legislature are extremely rare and affect well below 1 percent of MPs. In cases when MPs changed party affiliations, we assigned the party for which they cast most of their (roll call) votes.

15 For a summary of key debates that provides further context to the political landscape of the period, see Online Appendix A.2 and especially Table A.2.

16 In that sense, the Prussian Parliament as a whole was a conservative one. But as argued before, our interest is in the link between vote inequality and political orientation within the three-class franchise.

17 In the German context, MPs would (re-)enter the House via different doors to facilitate counting.

18 In our analysis period, there were four exceptional cases where abstentions were, however, included in the count (Plate Reference Plate1903, p. 180).

19 For details on variable construction please refer to the data section.

20 The assumption that industrial elites prefer liberal policies is supported by the fact that, among the three types of liberties—individual, economic, and political—liberal parties in late nineteenth-century Prussia are most strongly associated with economic liberalism (Mork Reference Mork1971).

21 Note that the famous “Marriage of Iron and Rye” (Schonhardt-Bailey Reference Schonhardt-Bailey1998; Lehmann Reference Lehmann2010b) describes a coalition in the German Reichstag with its equal voting system, and not in the Prussian Parliament. This coalition of industrial elites and large landowners in the German Empire agreed on the introduction of protectionist tariffs in 1879 in the German Reichstag. External affairs such as tariff setting were exclusively dealt with in the national parliament, the Reichstag.

22 Kühne (Reference Kühne1994a, p. 52) describes long-serving electoral delegates as de facto “patricians,” underlining their influence.

23 For an overview of the frequency of all RCVs by content and election period, see Table A.2 in the Online Appendix.

24 The replication files are provided in Reference Becker and HornungBecker and Hornung (2020).

25 In Table B.1 in the Online Appendix, we show that results are robust to the inclusion of a larger set of control variables.

26 MPs switching constituencies throughout their career may be a highly selected group that strategically ran in various electoral constituencies. In (unreported) regressions we find that constituency switching is unrelated to vote inequality and other constituency characteristics.

27 The two separate OC scores as outcome variables give rise to a two-equation system. We will generally assume that the standard errors are uncorrelated across equations. In fact, since the correlation between the two dimensions is only about 2 percent, this seems reasonable. However, using the potentially more efficient seemingly unrelated regression (SUR) method that allows standard errors to be correlated, we find very similar results.

28 Different from a measure of income inequality, vote inequality ignores within-class variation in income. Most likely vote inequality is correlated with income inequality because variation between income groups is a substantial part of the overall variation in incomes. Since this paper is interested in the franchise system, we use the vote inequality Gini that exactly captures the different degree of representation enjoyed by the three classes.

29 Based on the classified income tax of 3 percent at the time, their income must have been 9,000 thalers.

30 The source does not clarify how one of the three voters with identical tax contribution of 270 thalers was selected to go into the second class, as ties were not regulated in the electoral law.

31 The data was collected just after the 1891 tax reform changed the distribution of voters across classes in the three-class franchise.

32 Unfortunately, since MPs do not represent a county, we cannot match MPs to specific counties, even though our data is available at this level.

33 The correlation between vote inequality and landownership inequality is approximately 69 percent.

34 For further information see Online Appendix C.

35 Using initial differences excludes some (but not all) of the most pressing endogeneity concerns, which is why in Table E.1 in the Online Appendix, we show that results also hold in the smaller sample of Prussia in its pre-1867 borders, where we can use control variables from the censuses in 1849 and 1861.

36 Note that MPs might have multiple occupations and can be captured in several categories.

37 Within the Conservative party ca. 55 percent of the MPs are landowners; 38 percent of the Free Conservatives are landowners, but only 21 percent of National Liberals and 24 percent of Left Liberals report such an occupation.

38 Left Liberals: 19 percent; National Liberals: 18 percent; Other Liberals: 15 percent; Conservatives 3 percent; Free Conservatives: 8 percent; Centre Party: 9 percent.

39 This pattern remains largely stable over time, once MPs from the early election periods, where denomination is often unknown, drop out of parliament.

40 The variable “noble title” is unity if the affix of an MP includes the term Freiherr, Graf, Baron, Edler Herr, Prinz, von, vom, am, aus dem, de, du, van, or zur. The variable “academic title” is unity if the title of an MP includes the term Dr. or Dipl. Ing.

41 This variable may be related to both representation and political orientation.

42 The literature (see, e.g., Fowler Reference Fowler2005; Fowler and Smirnov Reference Fowler and Smirnov2005) argues that MPs are more likely to enforce extreme versions of their political agenda if the margin of victory is large.

43 Importantly, our turnout measure reflects participation of electoral delegates (Wahlmänner) in the second stage of the electoral process and not the turnout of voters in the primary elections (Urwahl). The turnout in this second stage is about 90 percent on average and remains stable across periods. For the smaller sample of constituencies in the pre-1867 borders, we also have information on the turnout in the primary elections by class. As expected, turnout increases in the level of representation (first class: 57 percent; second class: 44 percent; third class: 24 percent). However, neither of these measures is significantly related to political orientation.

44 Prussian constituencies had between one and three MPs. Multi-member constituencies have been argued to foster electoral competition and broader coalition building, leading to more redistributive policies (Persson and Tabellini Reference Persson and Tabellini2004).

45 Since the franchise system was not subject to change during our period under investigation, we do not expect major changes in voting behavior over time. Neither procedural rules on roll call voting nor on plenary agenda setting experienced fundamental changes during the period.

46 This methodology is related to the W-NOMINATE method that is frequently used in economics and has been adopted by the media when discussing the U.S. Congress. According to Rosenthal and Voeten (Reference Rosenthal and Voeten2004), the OC method is superior to parametric methods such as W-NOMINATE, when analyzing a multi-party setting such as ours.

47 For a more technical discussion, see Poole (Reference Poole2000).

48 In fact, following Hix and Noury (Reference Hix and Noury2016) we should call these “revealed positions” rather than “ideal points” to acknowledge that their position is not solely driven by personal preferences but also by institutional factors such as the electoral system. The Prussian parliament is akin to a presidential system in which the political leader (Bismarck) builds issue-by-issue coalitions. Consequently, in line with models of spatial voting behavior, we can assume that the Prussian parliament resembles a floor agenda model without restrictions to agenda setting (Hix and Noury Reference Hix and Noury2016).

49 Sixty-one MPs switch between parties in our dataset. In (unreported) regressions we find that party switching is unrelated to vote inequality and other constituency characteristics.

50 We are confident that we identified all RCVs in the period because the voting sequence of MPs systematically rotates over the alphabet restarting with the letter A after each election or recess. This procedure helped us ensure that we are not overlooking any RCVs. From 1883, RCVs are also listed in the index of the parliamentary minutes.

51 Changing the minimum vote requirements comes with a trade-off between the precise estimation of ideal points and the number of MPs who cast a sufficient number of votes. The choice of a minimum of 15 RCVs follows Häge (Reference Häge2019) who analyzes RCVs in the Reichstag. He also notes that although the number of roll calls in each term is relatively small compared to many contemporary legislatures, they are generally very informative. In fact, the average margin between yea and nay votes in our sample is 70 votes (21.6 percent) and therefore substantially closer than, for example, in the U.S. House of Representatives, where it was 35 percent during the period 1867–1903 (own calculation based on RCVs listed in voteview.com (Lewis et al. Reference Lewis, Keith, Howard, Adam, Aaron and Sonnet2020)).

52 Noel (Reference Noel2013, p. 78) gives the following intuitive definition of the APRE: “The APRE compares the error rate from a naïve model, in which we have no information about how people decided except the margin between supporters and opponents, with the estimated model, in which we have the ideal point. In the naïve model, we assume everyone is with the majority, and we are wrong on everyone in the minority. […] The Proportional Reduction in Error for each vote is what percentage of the errors from the naïve model are eliminated with the ideological dimension, and the APRE estimates the reduction across all votes.” Formally: $\sum\nolimits_{j = 1}^n {{{{{({\rm{minority}}\,{\rm{votes}} - {\rm{classification}}\,{\rm{errors}})}_j}} \over {{{{\rm{(minority votes)}}}_j}}}} $ .

53 Eigenvalues are computed on the basis of the so-called agreement matrix between representatives, in other words, the square matrix where entry (i, j) is the fraction of roll call votes where representatives i and j vote the same way. The faster the eigenvalues fall off, the stronger the evidence that only a small number of dimensions is required to describe systematic variation in voting patterns.

54 Figure E.1a in the Online Appendix shows the corresponding “scree plot” following Cattell (Reference Cattell1966). Online Appendix Figure E.1b presents the cutting lines that show how different roll calls bring together different groups of representatives on the yea or nay sides. The angle of the crossing lines with respect to the horizontal axis gives us an indication of whether the issues voted on are more divided along the first dimension or along the second dimension. Another way to present the same information is by virtue of Online Appendix Figure E.1c, which shows a histogram of cutting line angles.

55 Our choice of the anchors in each dimension is guided by the research question (MPs standing for a certain “orientation”), the length of tenure in parliament, and the number of votes cast in roll calls (for representativeness and stability of estimation). We use one MP from the Conservative Party (Friedrich von Wedell-Malchow) to define a “conservative” orientation of the policy space, and one MP from the Centre Party (Ludwig Windthorst) to define the “religious” orientation of the policy space.

56 Rotating the policy space is a common practice to ease graphical presentation and does not affect the political orientation of MPs within parties or the relative position of MPs to each other (see, e.g., Häge Reference Häge2019).

57 To address the concern that the distribution of MPs across the policy space is driven by specific periods that constitute outliers, we executed a “jackknife” analysis, that means consecutively dropping each period to probe sensitivity. Results of this procedure are presented in Figure E.2 in the Online Appendix.

58 While cultural factors such as religion and linguistic fractionalization are slow moving indicators that change only in the long run, development indicators such as urbanization and the size of the industrial sector can adjust more quickly and may therefore be endogenous to the political process. That being said, we are aware of the fact that some of our control variables are measured concurrent to political orientation and may be considered “bad controls.” To address this issue, in Table E.1 in the Online Appendix, we show that results also hold in the smaller sample of Prussia in its pre-1867 borders, where we can use control variables from the censuses in 1849 and 1861, which pre-date our outcome variables.

59 This relates to the reasoning by Boppart et al. (Reference Boppart, Falkinger, Grossmann, Woitek and Wüthrich2013) who find that differences in educational outcomes between Protestants and Catholics in late nineteenth century Switzerland are most pronounced in conservative milieus.

60 Vote inequality has a standard deviation of 0.039, liberal-conservative political orientation has a standard deviation of 0.395. Using the coefficient reported in Column (7), the magnitude can be calculated as 0.039 × 1.793/0.395 = 0.177.

61 Unfortunately, data on direct taxes payments are unavailable for constituencies that consisted only of one city (Stadtkreise = urban counties), which is why we lose these observations. The finding is robust to using a pre-1866 measure of income tax per capita, which is observed for all constituencies, but not for the provinces annexed after 1866.

62 This finding is unaltered by using protests from the period 1867 to 1903 as the control variable.

63 Plausibility is further increased by conditioning on our set of control variables.

64 Results are qualitatively similar when using 1893 vote inequality. Results are also similar when using the share of voters in the first and second class as an instrument.

65 Alternatively, we can base quartiles on the number of large firms in a constituency and find very similar results.

References

REFERENCES

Acemoglu, Daron, Johnson, Simon, and Robinson, James. “The Colonial Origins of Comparative Development: An Empirical Investigation.American Economic Review 91, no. 5 (2001): 1369–401.10.1257/aer.91.5.1369CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Acemoglu, Daron, Johnson, Simon, and Robinson, James. “Reversal of Fortune: Geography and Institutions in the Making of the Modern World Income Distribution.Quarterly Journal of Economics 117, no. 4 (2002): 1231–94.10.1162/003355302320935025CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Acemoglu, Daron, and Robinson, James. “Why Did the West Extend the Franchise? Democracy, Inequality, and Growth in Historical Perspective.Quarterly Journal of Economics 115, no. 4 (2000): 1167–99.10.1162/003355300555042CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Aidt, Toke S., and Raphaël Franck. “Democratization under the Threat of Revolution: Evidence from the Great Reform Act of 1832.” Econometrica 83, no. 2 (2015): 505–47.10.3982/ECTA11484CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Aidt, Toke S., and Peter S. Jensen. “From Open to Secret Ballot.” Comparative Political Studies 50, no. 5 (2017): 555–93.10.1177/0010414016628268CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ashraf, Quamrul H., Francesco, Cinnirella, Oded, Galor, Boris, Gershman, and Hornung, Erik. “Capital-Skill Complementarity and the Emergence of Labor Emancipation.CESifo Working Paper No. 7740, Munich, Germany, 2017.Google Scholar
Asmussen, Nicole, and Jo, Jinhee. “Anchors Away: A New Approach for Estimating Ideal Points Comparable across Time and Chambers.Political Analysis 24 (2016): 172–88.10.1093/pan/mpw003CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bartels, Charlotte. “Top Incomes in Germany, 1871–2014.Journal of Economic History 79, no. 3 (2019): 669707.10.1017/S0022050719000378CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bauernschuster, Stefan, Driva, Anastasia, and Hornung, Erik. “Bismarck’s Health Insurance and the Mortality Decline.” Journal of the European Economic Association, forthcoming 2020.Google Scholar
Becker, Sascha O., Francesco, Cinnirella, Erik, Hornung, and Woessmann, Ludger. “iPEHD–The ifo Prussian Economic History Database.Historical Methods: A Journal of Quantitative and Interdisciplinary History 47, no. 2 (2014): 5766.10.1080/01615440.2013.852370CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Becker, Sascha, Cinnirella, Francesco, and Woessmann, Ludger. “The Trade-Off between Fertility and Education: Evidence from before the Demographic Transition.Journal of Economic Growth 15, no. 3 (2010): 177204.10.1007/s10887-010-9054-xCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Becker, Sascha O., and Hornung, Erik. “The Political Economy of the Prussian Three-Class Franchise.” CAGE Working Paper No. 438, Coventry, UK, 2019.10.1017/S0022050720000443CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Becker, Sascha O., and Hornung, Erik. Replication data for: The Political Economy of the Prussian Three-Class Franchise. Ann Arbor, MI: Inter-university Consortium for Political and Social Research [distributor], 2020-08-24. https://doi.org/10.3886/E120745V1 CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Becker, Sascha O., Erik, Hornung, and Woessmann, Ludger. “Education and Catch-Up in the Industrial Revolution.American Economic Journal: Macroeconomics 3, no. 3 (2011): 92126.Google Scholar
Becker, Sascha O., Markus, Nagler, and Woessmann, Ludger. “Education and Religious Participation: City-Level Evidence from Germany’s Secularization Period 1890–1930.Journal of Economic Growth 22, no. 3 (2017): 273311.10.1007/s10887-017-9142-2CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Becker, Sascha O., and Ludger Woessmann. “Not the Opium of the People: Income and Secularization in a Panel of Prussian Counties.” American Economic Review 103, no. 3 (2013): 539–44.10.1257/aer.103.3.539CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Boix, Carles. Democracy and Redistribution. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 2003.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Boppart, Timo, Falkinger, Josef, Grossmann, Volker, Woitek, Ulrich, and Wüthrich, Gabriela. “Under Which Conditions Does Religion Affect Educational Outcomes?Explorations in Economic History 50, no. 2 (2013): 242–66.10.1016/j.eeh.2012.12.001CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Carrubba, Clifford J., Matthew, Gabel, Lacey Murrah, Ryan Clough, Elizabeth Montgomery, and Rebecca Schambach. “Off the Record: Unrecorded Legislative Votes, Selection Bias and Roll-Call Vote Analysis.” British Journal of Political Science 36, no. 4 (2006): 691704.10.1017/S0007123406000366CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cattell, Raymond B.The Scree Test for the Number of Factors.Multivariate Behavioral Research 1, no. 2 (1966): 245–76.10.1207/s15327906mbr0102_10CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Clark, Christopher. Iron Kingdom: The Rise and Downfall of Prussia, 1600–1947. Cambridge: Harvard University Press, 2006.Google Scholar
de Tocqueville, Alexis. The Old Regime and the Revolution. New York: Harper and Brothers, 1856.Google Scholar
Debus, Marc, and Ejnar Hansen, Martin. “Representation of Women in the Parliament of the Weimar Republic: Evidence from Roll Call Votes.Politics & Gender 10, no. 3 (2014): 341–64.10.1017/S1743923X1400021XCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Doepke, Matthias, and Zilibotti, Fabrizio. “Occupational Choice and the Spirit of Capitalism.Quarterly Journal of Economics 123, no. 2 (2008): 747–93.10.1162/qjec.2008.123.2.747CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Engerman, Stanley L., and Kenneth L. Sokoloff. “The Evolution of Suffrage Institutions in the New World.” Journal of Economic History 65, no. 4 (2005): 891921.10.1017/S0022050705000343CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fowler, James. “Dynamic Responsiveness in the U.S. Senate.American Journal of Political Science 49, no. 2 (2005): 299312.10.1111/j.0092-5853.2005.00124.xCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fowler, James, and Smirnov, Oleg. “Dynamic Parties and Social Turnout.American Journal of Sociology 110, no. 4 (2005): 1070–94.10.1086/426554CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gall, Lothar. “Liberalismus und ‘bürgerliche Gesellschaft.’ Zu Charakter und Entwicklung der liberalen Bewegung in Deutschland.Historische Zeitschrift 220, no. 1 (1975): 324–56.Google Scholar
Galloway, Patrick R. “Galloway Prussia Database 1861 to 1914.” (2007), http://www.patrickgalloway.com/prussia.htm.Google Scholar
Galor, Oded, and Moav, Omer. “Das Human-Kapital: A Theory of the Demise of the Class Structure.Review of Economic Studies 73, no. 1 (2006): 85117.10.1111/j.1467-937X.2006.00370.xCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gerschenkron, Alexander. Bread and Democracy in Germany, new ed. New York: Fertig, 1966.Google Scholar
Grant, Oliver. “Does Industrialization Push up Inequality? New Evidence on the Kuznets Curve from Nineteenth-Century Prussian Tax Statistics.Discussion Papers in Economic and Social History 48, University of Oxford, Oxford, UK, 2002.Google Scholar
Gross, Michael B. The War against Catholicism: Liberalism and the Anti-catholic Imagination in Nineteenth-Century Germany. Ann Arbor, MI: University of Michigan Press, 2004.10.3998/mpub.17623CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Häge, Frank M.Political Conflict in Bismarck’s Germany: An Analysis of Parliamentary Voting, 1867–1890.Party Politics 25, no. 2 (2019): 179–91.10.1177/1354068817702058CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hallerberg, Mark. “The Political Economy of Taxation in Prussia, 1871–1914.Jahrbuch für Wirtschaftsgeschichte 2 (2002): 1134.Google Scholar
Hansen, Martin Ejnar, and Debus, Marc. “The Behaviour of Political Parties and MPs in the Parliaments of the Weimar Republic.Party Politics 18, no. 5 (2012): 709–26.10.1177/1354068810389645CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Heckelman, Jac C., and Keith L. Dougherty. “A Spatial Analysis of Delegate Voting at the Constitutional Convention.” Journal of Economic History 73, no. 2 (2013): 407–44.10.1017/S0022050713000314CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Herrmann, Michael, and Sieberer, Ulrich. “The Basic Space of a Revolutionary Parliament: Scaling the Frankfurt Assembly of 1848/49.Party Politics 25, no. 6 (2019): 841–53.10.1177/1354068817749778CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hill, Joseph A.The Prussian Income Tax.Quarterly Journal of Economics 6, no. 2 (1892): 207–26.10.2307/1882547CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hinnerich, Björn Tyrefors, Lindgren, Erik, and Pettersson-Lidbom, Per, “Political Power, Resistance to Technological Change and Economic Development: Evidence from the 19th Century Sweden.” IFN Working Paper No. 1172, Stockholm, Sweden, 2017.Google Scholar
Hix, Simon, and Noury, Abdul. “Government-Opposition or Left-Right? The Institutional Determinants of Voting in Legislatures.Political Science Research and Methods 4, no. 2 (2016): 249–73.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Jackman, Robert W.Political Institutions and Voter Turnout in the Industrial Democracies.American Political Science Review 81, no. 2 (1987): 405–23.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Königlich Preußisches Statistisches Bureau. Zeitschrift des Königlich Preußischen Statistischen Bureaus, vol. 1–44. Berlin: Verl. d. Königl. Statist. Bureaus, 1861–1904.Google Scholar
Königlich Preußisches Statistisches Bureau. Zeitschrift des Königlich Preußischen Statistischen Bureaus - Ergänzungshefte, vol. 1–23. Berlin: Verl. d. Königl. Statist. Bureaus, 1864–1905.Google Scholar
Kühne, Thomas. Dreiklassenwahlrecht und Wahlkultur in Preussen 1867–1914. Landtagswahlen Zwischen Korporativer Tradition und Politischem Massenmarkt. Düsseldorf: Droste, 1994a.Google Scholar
Kühne, Thomas. Handbuch der Wahlen zum Preussischen Abgeordnetenhaus 1867–1918. Düsseldorf: Droste, 1994b.Google Scholar
Kurlander, Eric. “Liberalism.” In The Ashgate Research Companion to Imperial Germany, edited by Jefferies, Matthew, ch. 5. London and New York: Routledge, 2015.Google Scholar
Kuznets, Simon. “Economic Growth and Income Inequality.American Economic Review 45, no. 1 (1955): 128.Google Scholar
Langewiesche, Dieter. “German Liberalism in the Second Empire, 1871–1914.” In In Search of a Liberal Germany: Studies in the History of German Liberalism from 1789 to the Present, edited by Jarausch, Konrad and Jones, Larry Eugene, 217–35. New York, Oxford, and Munich: Berg Publishers, 1990.Google Scholar
Langewiesche, Dieter. “The Nature of German Liberalism.” In Modern Germany Reconsidered: 1870–1945, edited by Martel, Gordon, 96116. London and New York: Routledge, 1992.Google Scholar
Lehmann, Sibylle H.Chaotic Shop-Talk or Efficient Parliament? The Reichstag, the Parties, and the Problem of Governmental Instability in the Weimar Republic.Public Choice 144 (2010a): 83104.10.1007/s11127-009-9505-0CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lehmann, Sibylle H.The German Elections in the 1870s: Why Germany Turned from Liberalism to Protectionism.Journal of Economic History 70, no. 1 (2010b): 146–78.10.1017/S0022050710000082CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lehmann-Hasemeyer, Sibylle, Hauber, Philipp, and Opitz, Alexander. “The Political Stock Market in the German Kaiserreich—Do Markets Punish the Extension of the Suffrage to the Benefit of the Working Class? Evidence from Saxony.Journal of Economic History 74, no. 4 (2014): 1140–67.10.1017/S0022050714000886CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lehmann-Hasemeyer, Sibylle, and Streb, Jochen. “Does Social Security Crowd Out Private Savings? The Case of Bismarck’s System of Social Insurance.” European Review of Economic History (2017): 124.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lewis, Jeffrey B., Keith, Poole, Howard, Rosenthal, Adam, Boche, Aaron, Rudkin, and Sonnet, Luke. “Voteview: Congressional Roll-Call Votes Database,” 2020, https://voteview.com/.Google Scholar
Llavador, Humberto, and Oxoby, Robert J.. “Partisan Competition, Growth, and the Franchise.Quarterly Journal of Economics 120, no. 3 (2005): 1155–89.Google Scholar
Mares, Isabela. From Open Secrets to Secret Voting. Democratic Electoral Reforms and Voter Autonomy. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 2015.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mares, Isabella, and Queralt, Didac. “Autocratic Taxation: Examining the Adoption of Income Taxes in Imperial Germany and Prussia.Working Paper, Columbia University, 2014.Google Scholar
Mork, Gordon R.Bismarck and the ‘Capitulation’ of German Liberalism.Journal of Modern History 43, no. 1 (1971): 5975.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Nafziger, Steven. “Did Ivan’s Vote Matter? The Political Economy of Local Democracy in Tsarist Russia.European Review of Economic History 15, no. 3 (2011): 393441.10.1017/S1361491611000074CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Nipperdey, Thomas. Deutsche Geschichte, vol. 2: Machtstaat vor der Demokratie. München: Verlag C. H. Beck, 1992.Google Scholar
Noel, Hans. Political ideologies and political parties in America. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 2013.10.1017/CBO9781139814775CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Palmowski, Jan. Urban Liberalism in Imperial Germany: Frankfurt Am Main, 1866–1914. Oxford: Oxford University Press, 1999.10.1093/acprof:oso/9780198207504.001.0001CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Persson, Torsten, and Tabellini, Guido. “Constitutions and Economic Policy.Journal of Economic Perspectives 18, no. 1 (2004): 7598.10.1257/089533004773563449CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Plate, August. Die Geschäftsordnung des Preussischen Abgeordnetenhauses, ihre Geschichte und ihre Anwendung. Berlin: Verlag von Max Pasch, 1903.Google Scholar
Poole, Keith T.Nonparametric Unfolding of Binary Choice Data.Political Analysis 8, no. 2 (2000): 211–37.10.1093/oxfordjournals.pan.a029814CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Richter, Hedwig. Moderne Wahlen: Eine Geschichte der Demokratie in Preussen und den USA im 19. Jahrhundert. Hamburg: Hamburger Edition, 2017.Google Scholar
Rosenthal, Howard, and Voeten, Erik. “Analyzing Roll Calls with Perfect Spatial Voting: France 1946–1958.American Journal of Political Science 48, no. 3 (2004): 620–32.10.1111/j.0092-5853.2004.00091.xCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Schonhardt-Bailey, Cheryl. “Parties and Interests in the ‘Marriage of Iron and Rye’.British Journal of Political Science 28, no. 2 (1998): 291330.10.1017/S0007123498000179CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Squicciarini, Mara P., and Nico, Voigtländer. “Knowledge Elites and Modernization: Evidence from Revolutionary France.” NBER Working Paper No. 22779, Cambridge, MA, 2016.Google Scholar
Treue, Wolfgang. Die deutschen Parteien: Vom 19. Jahrhundert bis zur Gegenwart. Frankfurt am Main: Ullstein, 1975.Google Scholar
Weber, Max. “Das preussische Wahlrecht.Europäische Staats- und Wirtschafts-Zeitung 2, no. 16 (1917): 398402.Google Scholar
Yordanova, Nikoleta, and Mühlböck, Monika. “Tracing the Selection Bias in Roll Call Votes: Party Group Cohesion in the European Parliament.European Political Science Review 7, no. 3 (2015): 373–99.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ziblatt, Daniel. “Does Landholding Inequality Block Democratization?: A Test of the ‘Bread and Democracy’ Thesis and the Case of Prussia.World Politics 60, no. 4 (2008): 610–41.10.1353/wp.0.0021CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ziblatt, Daniel. “Shaping Democratic Practice and the Causes of Electoral Fraud: The Case of Nineteenth-Century Germany.American Political Science Review 103, no. 1 (2009): 121.10.1017/S0003055409090042CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Figure 0

Table 1 PARTY AFFILIATION FREQUENCY

Figure 1

Figure 1 SPATIAL VARIATION IN INEQUALITIES IN PRUSSIANotes: The figure shows the spatial distribution of vote inequality and landownership inequality. Vote inequality is a Gini coefficient calculated using the county-level number of voters in each class in the three-class franchise system of 1893 assuming that the tax burden of each class amounts to exactly one-third. Landownership inequality is a Gini coefficient calculated using the county-level number of farms with arable land by size-class (up to 1 hectare, 1 to 2 ha, 2 to 10 ha, 10 to 50 ha, 50 to 100 ha, and more than 100 ha) in 1882.Source: See Online Appendix C for data sources.

Figure 2

Table 2 RESULTS FOR SELECTED ROLL CALL VOTES

Figure 3

Table 3 PREDICTION OF VOTING BEHAVIOR ACROSS PARLIAMENTS FROM 1867–1903

Figure 4

Figure 2 THE PRUSSIAN POLICY SPACE DURING ELECTION PERIODS 10–19Notes: Positions of MPs in the Prussian House of Representatives. Each shape represents the political orientation of an MP based on his voting behavior during all roll calls in the period 1867–1903. Figure (b) is rotated to fix the centroid of the Conservative Party (K) to the horizontal axis. Figure (c) is rotated to fix the centroid of the Centre Party (Z) to the vertical axis.Source: See Online Appendix C for data sources.

Figure 5

Table 4 PARTY AFFILIATION AND POLITICAL ORIENTATION

Figure 6

Table 5 VOTE INEQUALITY AND LIBERAL-CONSERVATIVE ORIENTATION

Figure 7

Table 6 VOTE INEQUALITY AND SECULAR-RELIGIOUS ORIENTATION

Figure 8

Table 7 ROBUSTNESS CHECKS

Figure 9

Table 8 MITIGATING ENDOGENEITY CONCERNS

Figure 10

Table 9 VOTE INEQUALITY AND INDUSTRIAL ELITES

Supplementary material: PDF

Becker and Hornung supplementary material

Online Appendix

Download Becker and Hornung supplementary material(PDF)
PDF 838.1 KB