Hostname: page-component-cd9895bd7-gvvz8 Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-12-25T05:05:40.019Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Modeling Asymmetric Relationships from Symmetric Networks

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  06 November 2018

Arturas Rozenas
Affiliation:
New York University, New York, NY 10003, USA. Email: [email protected]
Shahryar Minhas
Affiliation:
Michigan State University, East Lansing, MI 48823, USA. Email: [email protected]
John Ahlquist*
Affiliation:
University of California, San Diego, La Jolla, CA 92093, USA. Email: [email protected]
Rights & Permissions [Opens in a new window]

Abstract

Many bilateral relationships requiring mutual agreement produce observable networks that are symmetric (undirected). However, the unobserved, asymmetric (directed) network is frequently the object of scientific interest. We propose a method that probabilistically reconstructs the latent, asymmetric network from the observed, symmetric graph in a regression-based framework. We apply this model to the bilateral investment treaty network. Our approach successfully recovers the true data generating process in simulation studies, extracts new, politically relevant information about the network structure inaccessible to alternative approaches, and has superior predictive performance.

Type
Letter
Copyright
Copyright © The Author(s) 2018. Published by Cambridge University Press on behalf of the Society for Political Methodology. 

1 Introduction

Social actors are often embedded in webs of relationships that profoundly shape political and economic outcomes (Franzese and Hays Reference Franzese and Hays2008; Ward, Stovel, and Sacks Reference Ward, Stovel and Sacks2011). One challenge in analyzing networks arises in situations where an analyst cannot fully observe the nature of relational ties. In many dyadic interactions—treaties, marriages—outsiders can observe ties only if both agents agree, that is, the payoff for forming a tie exceeds its cost for both members of a dyad (Jackson and Wolinsky Reference Jackson and Wolinsky1996). The observed network is therefore composed of symmetric (“undirected”) ties even though the social process at work contains important relational asymmetries. The pursuit of a tie by one party may not be reciprocated to the same extent by another.

As an illustration, suppose $A$ , $B$ , and $C$ are three warring factions deciding whether to sign bilateral peace agreements. We observe a network in which dyads $(A,C)$ and $(B,C)$ have signed agreements, but the dyad $(A,B)$ continues fighting. This observed network of “peaceful” ties could be generated from any of three unobserved sets of relations: it may be that $B$ failed to reciprocate $A$ ’s pursuit of peace, or vice versa, or neither $A$ nor $B$ pursued peace. To identify conditions that drive factions to sign peace agreements we must account for these unobserved asymmetries. Here, the observed symmetric graph is an incomplete representation of the underlying, asymmetric network, which is frequently the object of scientific interest. We refer to this situation as “partial observability.”

We present the partial observability generalized bilinear mixed effects model (P-GBME) to address this challenge. The model is a synthesis of the generalized bilinear mixed effects (GBME) model (Hoff Reference Hoff2005) and the bivariate or “partial observability” probit model (Poirier Reference Poirier1980; Przeworski and Vreeland Reference Przeworski and Vreeland2002). The model can probabilistically reconstruct the directed network from which the observed, undirected graph emerged. The model enables the study of network ties in a regression framework by accounting for interdependencies as well as unobserved asymmetries in network relations. The stochastic actor-oriented model (SAOM) for networks (Snijders and Pickup Reference Snijders, Pickup, Nicoll Victor, Montgomery and Lubell2017) also allows for partial observability. However, SAOM was designed to assess how specific network features (e.g., $k$ -star triangles) give rise to an observed network. The latent network approach is not used to study the role of specific network statistics. Rather, latent network models aim to account for broad patterns of network interdependence using a variance decomposition regression framework.Footnote 1

We illustrate the P-GBME model by applying it to the bilateral investment treaties (BIT) network for each year in 1990–2012. The model substantially improves predictive accuracy relative to both conventional logit and standard GBME. P-GBME extracts new information about the factors that drive treaty preferences, identifies important structural changes in the network, and highlights possible “hidden” agreements that are easily overlooked when latent network asymmetries are ignored.

2 The Model

Building on the random utility framework (McFadden Reference McFadden1980), we model an actor $i=1,\ldots ,N$ as having net utility from forming a tie with another actor $j$ : $z_{ij}=\unicode[STIX]{x1D707}_{ij}+\unicode[STIX]{x1D716}_{ij}$ with $\unicode[STIX]{x1D707}_{ij}$ representing the systematic component (that depends on observables) and $\unicode[STIX]{x1D716}_{ij}$ representing the stochastic error. To account for interdependencies in actors’ utilities from having ties, we use the “latent space” approach (Hoff Reference Hoff2005) and model these utilities as follows:

(1) $$\begin{eqnarray}\left(\begin{array}{@{}c@{}}z_{ij}\\ z_{ji}\end{array}\right)\sim {\mathcal{N}}\left(\begin{array}{@{}c@{}}\unicode[STIX]{x1D707}_{ij}+a_{i}+b_{j}+\boldsymbol{u}_{i}^{\prime }\boldsymbol{v}_{j}\\ \unicode[STIX]{x1D707}_{ji}+a_{j}+b_{i}+\boldsymbol{u}_{j}^{\prime }\boldsymbol{v}_{i}\end{array},\left[\begin{array}{@{}cc@{}}\unicode[STIX]{x1D70E}^{2} & \unicode[STIX]{x1D70C}\unicode[STIX]{x1D70E}^{2}\\ \unicode[STIX]{x1D70C}\unicode[STIX]{x1D70E}^{2} & \unicode[STIX]{x1D70E}^{2}\end{array}\right]\right).\end{eqnarray}$$

The correlation, $\unicode[STIX]{x1D70C}$ , captures the “reciprocity” between the utilities that actors derive from tie formation. Parameters $a_{i}$ and $b_{j}$ are sender- and receiver-specific random effects, respectively, and they capture second-order network dependencies. The vectors $\boldsymbol{u}_{i}$ and $\boldsymbol{v}_{i}$ represent the location of actor $i$ in the latent space of “senders” and “receivers,” respectively. These random effects capture higher-order dependencies in network ties: $i$ derives a large utility from forming a tie with $j$ , if $i$ ’s location in the latent space of “senders” $\boldsymbol{u}_{i}$ is close to $j$ ’s location in the latent space of “receivers” $\boldsymbol{u}_{j}$ (so that the cross product $\boldsymbol{u}_{i}^{\prime }\boldsymbol{v}_{j}$ is large).Footnote 2 We express the systematic components of actors’ utilities as linear functions of predictors:

(2) $$\begin{eqnarray}\displaystyle & \displaystyle \unicode[STIX]{x1D707}_{ij}=\unicode[STIX]{x1D737}^{(s)}\boldsymbol{x}_{i}^{(s)}+\unicode[STIX]{x1D737}^{(r)}\boldsymbol{x}_{j}^{(r)}+\unicode[STIX]{x1D737}^{(d)}\boldsymbol{x}_{ij}^{(d)}, & \displaystyle\end{eqnarray}$$
(3) $$\begin{eqnarray}\displaystyle & \displaystyle \unicode[STIX]{x1D707}_{ji}=\unicode[STIX]{x1D737}^{(s)}\boldsymbol{x}_{j}^{(s)}+\unicode[STIX]{x1D737}^{(r)}\boldsymbol{x}_{i}^{(r)}+\unicode[STIX]{x1D737}^{(d)}\boldsymbol{x}_{ji}^{(d)}. & \displaystyle\end{eqnarray}$$

A researcher cannot directly observe net utility (the $z$ ’s). We only observe agents’ behaviors, in this case undirected bilateral ties. A directional tie $i\rightarrow j$ is formed if and only if $i$ ’s net gain from doing so is strictly positive, $z_{ij}>0$ . Accordingly, the bilateral tie $i\leftrightarrow j$ is formed if and only if both actors derive a net positive payoff from having a tie so that $z_{ij}>0$ and $z_{ji}>0$ . A researcher observes an undirected (bilateral) tie $y_{ij}=y_{ji}=\{0,1\}$ arising from the following data generating process:

(4) $$\begin{eqnarray}y_{ij}=y_{ji}=\left\{\begin{array}{@{}ll@{}}1\quad & \text{if }z_{ij}>0\text{ and }z_{ji}>0,\\ 0\quad & \text{else}.\end{array}\right.\end{eqnarray}$$

Under a standard identifying restriction $\unicode[STIX]{x1D70E}^{2}=1$ , the model is a partially observable probit regression (Poirier Reference Poirier1980), augmented with random effects to capture unobserved heterogeneity and interdyadic dependencies. Vectors $\boldsymbol{x}_{i}^{(s)}$ and $\boldsymbol{x}_{i}^{(r)}$ represent the sender-specific and receiver-specific covariates, respectively. A model for the directional link $i\rightarrow j$ (Equation (2)), uses variables $\boldsymbol{x}_{i}$ as sender-specific predictors, but these same predictors become receiver-specific in the model for the directional link $j\rightarrow i$ (Equation (3)). Vector $\boldsymbol{x}_{ij}^{(d)}$ contains dyad-specific variables. These dyad-specific variables might be symmetric, $x_{ij}=x_{ji}$ (e.g., distance between countries), or not (e.g., export–import).

A partially observed probit model requires at least one of the following identifying restrictions: (a) regression Equations (2) and (3) must have the same parameters and/or (b) one equation contains a predictor not included in another equation (Poirier Reference Poirier1980). If the dyadic predictors are asymmetric, $\boldsymbol{x}_{ij}\neq \boldsymbol{x}_{ji}$ , then condition (2) is satisfied. Furthermore, regression Equations (2) and (3) have the same parameters, and so condition (1) holds as well; thus, the above model is parametrically identified. However, we impose an additional restriction that $\unicode[STIX]{x1D70C}=0$ . While this restriction is not required for parametric identification, Rajbhandari (Reference Rajbhandari, Jeliazkov and Yang2014) showed that finite sample estimates of $\unicode[STIX]{x1D70C}$ are sensitive to the starting values and generally cannot be treated as reliable.Footnote 3

We estimate the model in a Bayesian framework using Markov chain Monte Carlo. In the supplemental materials give a more detailed exposition of the model, prior assumptions, the sampling algorithm. We also provide results from a simulation study demonstrating that the model successfully recovers true parameter values.

3 Application: Bilateral Investment Treaties

We apply the P-GBME model to the network of bilateral investment treaties (BITs) from 1990 to 2012 using the standard United Nations BIT database. There is a vibrant debate on whether BITs boost FDI (Jandhyala, Henisz, and Mansfield Reference Jandhyala, Henisz and Mansfield2011; Simmons Reference Simmons2014; Minhas Reference Minhas2016), but a proper resolution of this debate requires a convincing empirical model of treaty formation (Rosendorff and Shin Reference Rosendorff and Shin2012). Partial observability is one key challenge in building such model: the observed network of signed bilateral treaties is symmetric, while the underlying preferences for these treaties are asymmetric.

We fit the P-GBME model separately for each year of data using a suite of covariates that closely follows the existing empirical literature (see supplementary materials).Footnote 4 Our model improves on the previous literature by accounting for both network interdependence and partial observability.

3.1 Predictive Performance

In Table 1 we compare the in-sample and out-of-sample predictive performance of the P-GBME to that of pooled probit, which assumes dyadic independence and ignores partial observability, and GBME, which models dyadic interdependencies, but not partial observability. The predictive accuracy of the GBME model in this case is similar to the pooled probit. Adding the partial observability component to the GBME model, however, produces an additional substantial improvement in the predictive accuracy as shown by all metrics for the P-GBME model.

3.2 Regression Parameters

Existing models, including GBME, estimate a single coefficient for each predictor when the outcome is represented as a symmetric matrix. This assumes away the possibility that the same factor differentially “affects” $i$ ’s demand for a treaty with $j$ and $i$ ’s attractiveness to $j$ . The P-GBME recovers directed sender and receiver effects for node-level covariates. For instance, our estimates suggest that, countries with faster growth in GDP per capita were no more inclined to sign BITs with others (sender effect). But high-growth countries were more attractive BIT partners to others (receiver effect). Supplementary materials describes regression parameter estimates in detail.

Figure 1. Each panels displays the posterior mean probability that China demands and will be demanded as a BIT partner. Country labels in black designate those that had formed a BIT with China by the specified year.

Table 1. Predictive performance in BIT data: area under the receiver operating characteristic curve (ROC) and area under the precision recall curve (PR).

3.3 The Structure of Latent Treaty Preferences

The P-GBME model allows us to extract “latent preferences” for treaty formation—the estimated probability that country $i$ demands a treaty from $j$ , and vice versa. Figure 1 displays the mean posterior predicted probabilities relevant to China in 1995 and 2010. The horizontal axis represents a country’s attractiveness to China as a BIT partner and the vertical axis is China’s attractiveness to that country. Countries above the diagonal line find China a more attractive BIT partner than China finds them, and vice versa. Heavier color identifies observed BITs.

The plots reveal how China’s position in the BIT network changed over time. In 1995, China was moving aggressively to demand BITs around the world, forming ties that the model views as relatively unlikely. By 2010, China had many more BITs in place and is more likely to be a treaty target of the remaining countries, an indication of China’s expanded role in the global economy.

Figure 2 illustrates a different use of the P-GBME model. It shows the predicted probabilities that the USA is demanded (left) and demands (right) a BIT in 2010. Observe that the model predicts Peru, Mexico, and Chile—the top 3 non-BITs—demand a BIT with the USA at probabilities close to one, and are also likely BIT targets of the USA with probabilities of about $0.5$ . Closer inspection of UN treaty data reveals that, by 2010, all three had signed other agreements with the US that contain provisions functionally equivalent to BITs; these agreements do not appear in the BIT dataset commonly used in the literature.Footnote 5 The P-GBME model nevertheless highlights these “hidden” agreements as dyads likely to have a BIT. This suggests that researchers studying BITs need to carefully examine the dataset they employ and perhaps expand the set of treaties considered relevant.

Figure 2. The posterior probability a country demands a BIT (left) and is demanded (right) with the USA in 2010 (the top and bottom decile of countries). P-GBME is good at separating likely from unlikely treaties as well as identifying “hidden agreements.”

4 Conclusion

Partial observability occurs whenever the observed graph is undirected yet the underlying process implies directed relationships. We introduced a model that can reconstruct the latent directed network ties, and illustrated its advantages on an example of bilateral trade agreements. The future work in this area could focus on several extensions. First, we accounted for network dependencies using bilinear mixed effects framework (GBME), which could be generalized using the recently developed additive and multiplicative effects network model (Hoff Reference Hoff2015; Minhas, Hoff, and Ward Reference Minhas, Hoff and Ward2016). Second, estimating this type of network model in a fully dynamic setting (as opposed to slicing data by time, as we did here) remains a challenge, especially when the set of nodes changes through time.

Supplementary material

To view supplementary material for this article, please visit https://doi.org/10.1017/pan.2018.41.

Footnotes

Author’s note: Versions of this paper were presented at the 2015 meetings of the International Political Economy Society, the 2016 meetings of the Society for Political Methodology, and WardFest. We thank James Fowler, Jenn Larson, and Mike Ward for useful comments. Micah Dillard provided excellent research assistance. Ahlquist benefitted from a fellowship at Stanford’s Center for Advanced Study in the Behavioral Sciences during the writing of this paper. Installation instructions for the P-GBME package and files to replicate the analyses in this paper are available at http://github.com/s7minhas/pgbmeRepl and on the Dataverse associated with this paper (Rozenas, Minhas, and Ahlquist 2018).

Contributing Editor: Jeff Gill

1 See Minhas, Hoff, and Ward (Reference Minhas, Hoff and Ward2016) for detailed discussion. Other approaches based on generalized spatio-temporal dependence can also recover directed predicted probabilities Franzese, Hays, and Kachi (Reference Franzese, Hays and Kachi2012).

2 As in previous literature, these random effects are modeled as $(a_{i},b_{i})\sim {\mathcal{N}}(0,\unicode[STIX]{x1D72E}_{ab})$ , $\boldsymbol{u}_{i}\sim {\mathcal{N}}_{K}(\mathbf{0},\unicode[STIX]{x1D70E}_{u}^{2}\boldsymbol{I})$ , and $\boldsymbol{v}_{i}\sim {\mathcal{N}}_{K}(\mathbf{0},\unicode[STIX]{x1D70E}_{v}^{2}\boldsymbol{I})$ , where $\unicode[STIX]{x1D72E}_{ab}$ , $\unicode[STIX]{x1D70E}_{u}^{2}$ , and $\unicode[STIX]{x1D70E}_{v}^{2}$ are unknown parameters. The choice of $K$ , dimensionality of the latent space, is discussed supplementary materials https://doi.org/10.1017/pan.2018.41.

3 The estimation algorithm provided with this paper allows $\unicode[STIX]{x1D70C}$ to be estimated, but caution should be used when utilizing this option.

4 Data and replication materials are available at Rozenas, Minhas, and Ahlquist (Reference Rozenas, Minhas and Ahlquist2018).

5 The treaties are 2006 Peru–USA Free Trade Agreement (FTA), NAFTA in 1992, and the 2003 Chile–USA FTA. These agreements included investment provisions that mirror the terms of a BIT almost exactly (see http://investmentpolicyhub.unctad.org/ Download/TreatyFile/5454).

References

Franzese, Robert J., and Hays, Jude C.. 2008. Interdependence in comparative politics: substance, theory, empirics, substance. Comparative Political Studies 41(4/5):742780.Google Scholar
Franzese, Robert J., Hays, Jude C., and Kachi, Aya. 2012. Modeling history dependence in network-behavior coevolution. Political Analysis 20(2):175190.Google Scholar
Hoff, Peter D. 2005. Bilinear mixed-effects models for dyadic data. Journal of the American Statistical Association 100(4690):286295.Google Scholar
Hoff, Peter D.2015 Dyadic Data Analysis with amen. arXiv:1506.08237:1–48.Google Scholar
Jackson, Matthew O., and Wolinsky, Asher. 1996. A strategic model of social and economic networks. Journal of Economic Theory 71(1):4474.Google Scholar
Jandhyala, Srividya, Henisz, Witold J., and Mansfield, Edward D.. 2011. Three waves of BITs: the global diffusion of foreign investment policy. Journal of Conflict Resolution 55(6):10471073.Google Scholar
McFadden, Daniel. 1980. Econometric models for probabilistic choice among products. Journal of Business 53(3):S13S29.Google Scholar
Minhas, Shahryar. 2016 Learning from incredible commitments: evolution and impact of bilateral investment treaties. PhD Thesis, Duke University, Durham, North Carolina.Google Scholar
Minhas, Shahryar, Hoff, Peter D., and Ward, Michael D.. 2016. Let’s say Amen for latent factor models. Working Paper. https://arxiv.org/abs/1611.00460.Google Scholar
Poirier, Dale J. 1980. Partial observability in bivariate probit models. Journal of Econometrics 12(2):2090217.Google Scholar
Przeworski, Adam, and Vreeland, James Raymond. 2002. A statistical model of bilateral cooperation. Political Analysis 10(2):101112.Google Scholar
Rajbhandari, Ashish. 2014. Identification and MCMC estimation of bivariate probit models with partial observability. In Bayesian Inference in the Social Sciences , ed. Jeliazkov, Ivan and Yang, Xin-She. Hoboken, NJ: Wiley, pp. 299316.Google Scholar
Rosendorff, B. Peter, and Shin, Kongjoo. 2012. Importing transparency: the political economy of BITs and FDI flows. Manuscript, New York University Political Science Department. New York, NY: NYU.Google Scholar
Rozenas, Arturas, Minhas, Shahryar, and Ahlquist, John S.. 2018. Replication data for: modeling asymmetric relationships from symmetric networks. https://doi.org/10.7910/DVN/VFDCJV, Harvard Dataverse, V1.Google Scholar
Simmons, Beth A. 2014. Bargaining over BITs, Arbitrating awards: the regime for protection and promotion of international investment. World Politics 66(1):1246.Google Scholar
Snijders, Tom A. B., and Pickup, Mark. 2017. Stochastic actor oriented models for network dynamics. In Oxford Handbook of Politicial Networks , ed. Nicoll Victor, Jennifer, Montgomery, Alexander H., and Lubell, Mark. New York: Oxford University Press, pp. 221248.Google Scholar
Ward, Michael D, Stovel, Katherine, and Sacks, Audrey. 2011. Network analysis and political science. Annual Review of Political Science 14:245264.Google Scholar
Figure 0

Figure 1. Each panels displays the posterior mean probability that China demands and will be demanded as a BIT partner. Country labels in black designate those that had formed a BIT with China by the specified year.

Figure 1

Table 1. Predictive performance in BIT data: area under the receiver operating characteristic curve (ROC) and area under the precision recall curve (PR).

Figure 2

Figure 2. The posterior probability a country demands a BIT (left) and is demanded (right) with the USA in 2010 (the top and bottom decile of countries). P-GBME is good at separating likely from unlikely treaties as well as identifying “hidden agreements.”

Supplementary material: File

Rozenas et al. supplementary material

Rozenas et al. supplementary material 1

Download Rozenas et al. supplementary material(File)
File 747.3 KB