Published online by Cambridge University Press: 13 June 2011
The authors present a theory of the general enabling conditions for war which predicts that war is possible, though not inevitable, when the conditions of the theory are satisfied. Whether a war will actually occur depends upon the idiosyncratic situational factors that are outside the scope of the theory. Three conditions make war possible: (i) Aspirations do not match achievements: governments only initiate wars when their achieved share of global capabilities differs from their aspired share of capabilities. (2) Salience: governments only initiate wars against other governments when there is a history of substantial interaction. (3) Power: governments never initiate wars against other governments that have a substantially greater military capacity. These conditions may be viewed as a series of three filters that identify pairs of countries between which war is possible. The theory predicts that wars will not occur in any dyad that does not pass through all the filters. In testing this theory for all nations between 1816 and 1980, the authors allowed for the fact that governments may preemptively initiate wars against other governments that meet these conditions.
1 Lakatos, Imre, “Falsification and the Methodology of Scientific Research Programmes,” in Lakatos, Imre and Musgrave, Alan, eds., Criticism and the Growth of Knowledge (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1970), 91–196CrossRefGoogle Scholar.
2 de Mesquita, Bruce Bueno, The War Trap (New Haven: Yale University Press, 1981)Google Scholar. Bueno de Mesquita's theory has undergone two revisions since 1981: de Mesquita, Bruce Bueno, “The War Trap Revisited: A Revised Expected Utility Model,” American Political Science Review 79 (March 1985), 156–77CrossRefGoogle Scholar, and de Mesquita, Bruce Bueno and Lalman, David, “Reason and War,” American Political Science Review 80 (December 1986), 1113–29CrossRefGoogle Scholar. Because the original 1981 version has the broadest empirical test, we use it as our point of comparison.
3 Majeski, Steven J. and Sylvan, David J., “Simple Choices and Complex Calculations: A Critique of the War Trap,” Journal of Conflict Resolution 28 (June 1984), 316–40CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Maoz, Zeev, “The Expected Utility of International Conflict: Some Theoretical Problems and Empirical Surprises in ‘The War Trap,’ ” mimeo (Pittsburgh: Carnegie-Mellon University, 1982)Google Scholar; Wagner, R. Harrison, “War and Expected-Utility Theory,” World Politics 36 (April 1984), 407–23CrossRefGoogle Scholar.
4 Allison, Graham T., Essence of Decision: Explaining the Cuban Missile Crisis (Boston: Little, Brown, 1971)Google Scholar; Anderson, Paul A., “Decision Making by Objection and the Cuban Missile Crisis,” Administrative Science Quarterly 28 (June 1983), 201–22CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Cyert, Richard and March, James G., A Behavioral Theory of the Firm (Englewood Cliffs, NJ: Prentice-Hall, 1963)Google Scholar; March, James G. and Olsen, Johan P., Ambiguity and Choice in Organizations (Bergen, Norway: Universitetsforlaget, 1976)Google Scholar; Simon, Herbert A., Administrative Behavior, 3rd ed. (New York: Free Press, 1976)Google Scholar.
5 Bueno de Mesquita (fn. 2, 1981), 5.
6 Lebow, Richard Ned, Between Peace and War: The Nature of International Crisis (Baltimore: The Johns Hopkins University Press, 1981)Google Scholar.
7 Allison (fn. 4); Cyert and March (fn. 4); March, James G. and Simon, Herbert A., Organizations (New York: Wiley, 1958)Google Scholar.
8 Organski, A.F.K. and Kugler, Jacek, The War Ledger (Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1980)Google Scholar.
9 Lenin, V. I., Imperialism, The Highest Stage of Capitalism (Peking: Foreign Languages Press, 1969)Google Scholar.
10 Day, Richard H. and Groves, Theodore, eds., Adaptive Economic Models (New York: Academic Press, 1975)Google Scholar; Davies, James C., “Toward a Theory of Revolution,” American Sociological Review 27 (February 1962), 5–19CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Estes, William K., “Individual Behavior in Uncertain Situations: An Interpretation in Terms of Statistical Association Theory,” in Thrall, Robert M., Coombs, Clyde H., and Davis, Robert L., eds., Decision Processes (New York: Wiley, 1954), 127–38Google Scholar.
11 Most, Benjamin A. and Starr, Harvey, “Case Selection, Conceptualizations and Basic Logic in the Study of War,” American Journal of Political Science 26 (November 1982), 834–56CrossRefGoogle Scholar.
12 Hildebrand, David K., Laing, James D., and Rosenthal, Howard, “Prediction Analysis in Political Research,” American Political Science Review 60 (June 1976), 509–35CrossRefGoogle Scholar.
13 Bueno de Mesquita (fn. 2, 1981) uses Yule's Q. We believe that this is not a particularly helpful statistic for our purposes because, unlike Bueno de Mesquita, we examine all nationyears for the period. Although it is certainly true that Q = 1.0 when only one of the offdiagonal cells equals o, this is not by itself a sufficiently attractive property to overcome what we view as its most important weakness. Q is maximized by minimizing the product of the off-diagonal elements, bc. But a crucial question in a model of necessary conditions is how each of the variables b and c contributes to that minimization. If b represents cases where war has occurred when it was predicted not to, then those cases are clear prediction failures, as we have noted above. However, c must then represent cases where war was predicted but none has occurred. A low value for c means that the model is rather stringent in its conditions; in fact, a value of 0 for c would suggest that one has an excellent model of sufficient conditions. But if one is serious about claiming to have a model of necessary conditions, minimizing the value of b must take precedence over minimizing c. We contend that, since stringency is logically independent of prediction accuracy, two measures of performance are really needed.
14 Bueno de Mesquita (fn. 2, 1981), 27–28.
15 Cyert and March (fn. 4); Halperin, Morton H., Bureaucratic Politics and Foreign Policy (Washington, DC: Brookings Institution, 1974)Google Scholar; Simon (fn. 4).
16 Bremer, Stuart A., “National Capabilities and War Proneness,” in Singer, J. David, ed., The Correlates of War II: Testing some Realpolitik Models (New York: Free Press, 1980), 59–61Google Scholar; Organski and Kugler (fn. 8); Singer, J. David, Bremer, Stuart A., and Stuckey, John, “Capability Distribution, Uncertainty, and Major Power War, 1816–1965,” in Russett, Bruce M., ed., Peace, War, and Numbers (Beverly Hills, CA: Sage, 1972), 19–48Google Scholar.
17 Baldwin, David A., “Power Analysis and World Politics: New Trends versus Old Tendencies,” World Politics 31 (January 1979), 161–94CrossRefGoogle Scholar.
18 March, James G., “Decision Making Perspective: Decisions in Organizations and Theories of Choice,” in Van de Ven, Andrew H. and Joyce, William F., eds., Perspectives on Organizational Design and Behavior (New York: Wiley, 1981), 214–15Google Scholar.
19 In early runs we also tried using a finer increment—.005—at times. This resulted in only modest improvements in number of cases filtered out, and generally no improvement in the error count.
20 Singer et al. (fn. 16).
21 The war years 1914–1918 and 1939–1945 were largely devoid of data in the original dataset. We have remedied this to a small extent.
22 Details on dataset revisions are available from the authors.
23 Singer et al. (fn. 16); Bueno de Mesquita (fn. 2, 1981), 103.
24 The weights decline in linear fashion. We also developed a method for handling missing data within the five-year period by using only those data that were present, and automatically making the appropriate adjustment in weights to reflect the missing year.
25 Nisbett, Richard E. and Ross, Lee, Human Inference: Strategies and Shortcomings in Social Judgment (Englewood Cliffs, NJ: Prentice-Hall, 1980), 18–23Google Scholar.
26 Ibid., 51–52; Zinnes, Dina A., “The Expression and Perception of Hostility in Prewar Crisis: 1914,” in Singer, J. David, ed., Quantitative International Politics: Insights and Evidence (New York: Free Press, 1968), 85–122Google Scholar.
27 Cyert and March (fn. 4); Anderson, Paul A., “Justifications and Precedents as Constraints in Foreign Policy Decision Making,” American Journal of Political Science 25 (November 1981), 738–61CrossRefGoogle Scholar.
28 Ibid.
29 Bueno de Mesquita (fn. 2, 1981); Morgenthau, Hans J., Politics Among Nations: The Struggle for Power and Peace, 5th ed. (New York: Knopf, 1978)Google Scholar.
30 Richardson, Lewis F., Statistics of Deadly Quarrels (Pittsburgh: Boxwood Press, 1960)Google Scholar.
31 Bueno de Mesquita (fn. 2, 1981).
32 Small, Melvin and Singer, J. David, “The Diplomatic Importance of States, 1816–1970: An Extension and Refinement of the Indicator,” World Politics 25 (July 1973), 577–99CrossRefGoogle Scholar.
33 Wallace, Michael and Singer, J. David, “Intergovernmental Organization in the Global System, 1815–1964: A Quantitative Description,” International Organization 24 (No. 2, 1970), 239–87CrossRefGoogle Scholar.
34 Bueno de Mesquita (fn. 2, 1981), 115–18.
35 For work on another part of the model we updated the alliance dataset to reflect alliances formed up to 1980, but ran this part of the model using data supplied by Bueno de Mesquita on Europe and the Middle East only.
36 Gochman, Charles S. and Maoz, Zeev, “Militarized Interstate Disputes, 1816–1976: Procedures, Patterns, and Insights,” Journal of Conflict Resolution 28 (December 1984), 585–616CrossRefGoogle Scholar.
37 Siverson, Randolph M. and King, Joel, “Attributes of National Alliance Membership and I War Participation, 1815–1965,” American Journal ofPolitical Science 24 (February 1980), 1–15CrossRefGoogle Scholar.
38 Bueno de Mesquita (fn. 2, 1981), 105–8.
39 Kehr, Eckert, Economic Interest, Militarism, and Foreign Policy, Craig, Gordon A., ed., Grete Heinz, trans. (Berkeley: University of California Press, 1977), 62–63Google Scholar.
40 Lebow, Richard Ned, “The Paranoia of the Powerful: Thucydides on World War III,” PS 17 (Winter 1984), 10–17CrossRefGoogle Scholar.
41 Grofman, Bernard N. and Muller, Edward N., “The Strange Case of Relative Gratification and Potential for Political Violence: The V-Curve Hypothesis,” American Political Science Review 67 (June 1973), 514–39CrossRefGoogle Scholar.
42 Midlarsky, Manus I., “Preventing Systemic War,” Journal of Conflict Resolution 28 (December 1984), 563–84CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Houweling, Henk W. and Siccama, Jan G., “The Arms Race—War Relationship: Why Serious Disputes Matter,” Arms Control 2 (September 1981), 157–97CrossRefGoogle Scholar.
43 If we set the cutpoint at the “region” as defined by Bueno de Mesquita (an ad hoc modification of geographic regions) we obtain the following results: WW=77 ;
44 In no permuted version did the accuracy of the war predictions change; the largest shift in scope occurred when we ran the sequence 2–1–3. This increased the final scope by 18 cases, an improvement of approximately 0.1%.
45 Maoz (fn. 3).
46 Bueno de Mesquita (fn. 2, 1981), 94–96.
47 lbid., 129.
48 Maoz (fn. 3), 27.
49 Bueno de Mesquita (fn. 2, 1981), 129.
50 Maoz (fn. 3), Table 2.
51 Doran, Charles F. and Parsons, Wes, “War and the Cycle of Relative Power,” Amerkm Political Science Review 74 (December 1980), 947CrossRefGoogle Scholar.
52 Ibid., 962.
53 Steven Rosen, “War Power and the Willingness to Suffer,” in Russett (fn. 16), 167–84.
54 Bueno de Mesquita (fn. 2, 1981), 143.