Hostname: page-component-cd9895bd7-fscjk Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-12-25T16:54:23.116Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

‘Toward the Iron Cage of Future Serfdom’? On the Methodological Status of Max Weber's Ideal-Typical Concept of Bureaucratization

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  11 May 2009

Extract

The terms bureaucracy and bureaucratization are altogether loaded with emotional connotations. In order to get beyond this and to reach an understanding of what is actually meant when we talk of bureaucracy and bureaucratization it is worth while turning to Max Weber. Weber was among the first sociologists to discuss systematically the consequences of bureaucratization for Western societies. He developed an ideal-typical theory bureaucratization which has been extremely influential far beyond the confines of sociology as such. Undoubtedly it is of major interest to historians as well, for though systematic in its intent, it draws on a wide range of historical cases; furthermore, it was intended to throw light on significant historical developments, in particular the processes nowadays associated with the concept of modernization. Indeed, Günther Roth pointed out recently with good reason that Max Weber's retreat from history was in fact strategic rather than fundamental; his ideal-typical systematizations were meant to serve as tools and guidelines for empirical historical research just as much as for sociological analysis. ‘Socio-historical models (such as bureaucracy, patrimonialism, feudalism or the charismatic community) are useful to us in so far as they organize historical knowledge in a specifically sociological way, that is, in the form of generalizations that emphasize the general and repetitive side of history without assuming the existence of laws in any strict sense.’ Moreover, in Weber's methodology ideal types are then used in a genuine historical manner.

Type
Research Article
Copyright
Copyright © Royal Historical Society 1980

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

1 On this issue see, for instance, Miller, S., ‘Bureaucracy Baiting’, The American Scholar, 47 (1977), 205–22.Google Scholar

2 Roth, G. and Schluchter, W., Max Weber's Vision of History, Ethics and Methods (London: Berkeley, 1979), p. 197.Google Scholar

3 Ibid., p. 126.

4 Weber, Max, Gesammelte Aufsätze zur Wissenschaftlehre [hereafter WL] (Tübingen, 1968), p. 202Google Scholar, here quoted from Shils, E. A. and Finch, H. A., Max Weber. The Methodology of the Social Sciences (New York, 1949).Google Scholar

5 See Weber, Max, Gesammelte Aufsätze zur Religionssoziologie [hereafter RS, I], I (Tübingen, 1920), p. 204.Google Scholar

6 A more detailed exposition of this central theme of Weber is to be found in Mommsen, W. J., The Age of Bureaucracy. Perspectives on the Political Sociology of Max Weber (Oxford, 1974), p. 56Google Scholar. See also Mommsen, W. J., Max Weber. Gesellschaft, Politik und Geschichte (Frankfurt, 1974), p. 97Google Scholar, and Wilson, H. T., ‘Reading Max Weber: The Limits of Sociology’, Sociology, 10 (1976), 308.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

7 For a more detailed assessment of these attitudes, see Mommsen, W. J., Max Weber und die deutsche Politik (Tübingen, 1974), pp. 115–16.Google Scholar

8 ‘Karl Löwith, Max Weber und Karl Marx’, K. Löwith, Gesammelte Abhandlungen. Zur Kritik der geschichtlichen Existenz (Cologne, 1969), p. 3Google Scholar. A partial English translation is in Max Weber, ed. Wrong, D. H. (Englewood Cliffs, 1970), pp. 101–23.Google Scholar

9 It is impossible to give here a full account of the extensive scholarly debate on these issues. For a survey of it, see Mommsen, W. J., ‘“Verstehen” und “Ideal typus”Google Scholar. Zur Methodologie einer historischen Sozialwissenschaft’, Max Weber. Gesellschaft, Politik und Geschichte, pp. 208–32Google Scholar. See also Burger, T., Max Weber's Theory of Concept Formation. History, Laws, and Ideal-Types (Durham, North Carolina, 1976)Google Scholar, and Runciman, W. G., A Critique of Max Weber's Philosophy of Social Science (Cambridge, 1972).Google Scholar

10 WL, pp. 146214Google Scholar. See also Shils, and Finch, , Methodology, pp. 50112Google Scholar, although the translation leaves much to be desired.

11 Weber, Max, Wirtschaft und Gessellschaft. Grundriβ einer verstehenden Sozialökonomie [hereafter WuG] (Tübingen, 1976), p. 4Google Scholar. The author's translation is based upon the English edition by Roth, G. and Wittich, C., Max Weber, Economy and Society, An Outline of Interpretative Sociology [hereafter EaS] (New York, 1968), I, p. 9.Google Scholar

12 WL, p. 191Google Scholar; Shils, and Finch, , Methodology, p. 90.Google Scholar

13 WL, p. 194Google Scholar (author's translation); Shils, and Finch, , Methodology, p. 94.Google Scholar

14 The most serious objection which can be raised against Weber's ideal-typical method, and one which has been made, is that he tended to confuse theoretical preconceptions which are, as it were, essential initial premisses for any kind of research, with what he described, in terminology taken from Rickert, ‘Wertbeziehung’. See Runciman, , Critique, p. 33Google Scholar. Indeed it could be argued that Weber ought to have distinguished more clearly between such ideal-typical models constructed only in accordance with formal rational principles and those constructed in accordance with substantive rational, that is to say value-oriented principles. However, Weber was convinced that formal rational and substantive rational perspectives could, in particular instances, cover the same field; formal rationalization of bureaucratic institutions can be seen as an inherent element of their own formal rational ‘telos’, and as a factor carrying far-reaching significance from a value-rational point of view.

15 Runciman, , Critique, p. 5.Google Scholar

16 Mommsen, , Max Weber, Gesellschaft, Politik und Geschichte, p. 132.Google Scholar

17 WuG, p. 123Google Scholar; EaS, p. 223.Google Scholar

18 WuG, p. 561Google Scholar; EaS, p. 973.Google Scholar

19 See WuG, p. 130.Google Scholar

20 For the conflict between a formal rational and a substantive rational analysis, see WuG, p. 130.Google Scholar

21 WuG, p. 563Google Scholar; EaS, p. 975.Google Scholar

22 See WuG, p. 130.Google Scholar

23 WuG, pp. 565, 570Google Scholar; also p. 128.

24 Gesammelte Politische Schriften (Tübingen, 1958), p. 332.Google Scholar

25 We follow here Schluchter's suggestion that a distinction should be made between mere social change which takes place within closed social systems, and social developments which result in substantial changes of a given social system (Schluchter, W., Die Entwicklung des okzidentalen Rationalismus. Eine Analys von Max Webers Gesellschaftsgeschichte (Tübingen, 1979), p. 1, n.)Google Scholar

26 RS, I, p. 204Google Scholar (author's translation).

27 Friedrich, K. J., ‘Some Observations of Weber's Analysis of Bureaucracy’, Reader in Bureaucracy, ed. Merton, R. K. et al. (Glencoe, 1952), p. 31.Google Scholar

28 See in particular Blau, P. M., ‘Critical Remarks on Weber's Theory of Authority’, Max Weber, ed. Wrong, p. 147Google Scholar. See also Blau, , The Dynamics of Bureaucracy (Chicago, 1963), pp. 261, 269Google Scholar, and Udy, S. H., ‘“Bureaucracy” and “Rationality”. Weber's Organization Theory: An Empirical Study’, The Formal Organization, ed. Gall, R. H. (London, 1972), p. 17.Google Scholar

29 See the author's essay, ‘Max Weber and Robert Michels: an Asymmetrical Partnership’, After Michels, ed. S. Lukes, forthcoming.

30 WuG, p. 868Google Scholar; EaS, p. 1118.Google Scholar

31 We borrow this formulation, which appears to be very suitable, from Wiener, J. M., ‘Max Weber's “Marxism”: The Theory of Capitalist Development in Weber's Agrarian Sociology of Ancient Civilizations’, a paper read at the annual meeting of the American Political Science Association, Washington, D.C., 09 1979, p. 11Google Scholar. However, the passage in brackets had to be inserted, for otherwise the fact that the ideal types are purely nomological concepts would be obscured.

32 On the difficult issue of the history of Wirtschaft und Gesellschaft, and in particular the various versions of the theory of the ‘Three Pure Types of Legitimate Rule’, see Mommsen, , The Age of Bureaucracy, p. 16, n. 22Google Scholar, and recently Roth, G., ‘Abschied oder Wiedersehn?’Google Scholar, review of the fifth edition of Wirtschaft und Gesellschaft by Winckelman, J.Kölner Zeitschrift für Soziologie und Sozialpsychologie, 2 (1979), 318–26.Google Scholar

33 Gesammelte Politische Schriften, ed. Winckelman, J. (Tübingen, 1971)Google Scholar [hereafter PS], p. 118Google Scholar (author's translation).

34 Ibid., p. 333.

35 Gesammelte Aufsätze zur Soziologie und Sozialpolitik (Tübingen, 1924), p. 414Google Scholar (author's translation).

36 A more elaborate discussion of this point is in Mommsen, , Max Weber und die deutsche Politik, p. 118.Google Scholar

37 See WuG, p. 129.Google Scholar

38 PS, p. 544Google Scholar. For the concept of the ‘leadership democracy’, see in particular Mommsen, , Max Weber und die deutsche Politik, p. 416Google Scholar, and Beetham, D., Max Weber and the Theory of Modern Politics (London, 1974), p. 226.Google Scholar

39 Burger, , Weber's Theory of Concept Formation, p. 175.Google Scholar

40 See, among others, Blau, , Dynamics of BureaucracyGoogle Scholar; Blau, P. M. and Scott, W. R., Formal Organizations (San Francisco, 1962)Google Scholar; Cohen, J., The Demonics of Bureaucracy (Iowa, 1962)Google Scholar; Crozier, M., The Bureaucratic Phenomena (Chicago, 1964)Google Scholar; The Formal Organization, ed. Hall, R. H. (London: New York, 1972)Google Scholar; Etzioni, A., A Comparative Analysis of Complex Organizations (London: New York, 1971)Google Scholar; Mayntz, R., ‘Max Weber Idealtypus der Bürokratie und die Organisationssoziologie’, Bürokratische Organization, ed. Mayntz, R. (Cologne, 1969), p. 27.Google Scholar

41 See, in particular, Hall, R. H., ‘Professionalisation and Bureaucratization’, The Formal Organization, ed. Hall, p. 143.Google Scholar

42 See, for instance, Thompson, V. A., Bureaucracy and Innovation (Alabama, 1976).Google Scholar

43 See, for the apparent continuity from Weber's work to the present day, ‘Empirical Social Research in Organisations?’, Kieser, A. and Kubicek, H., Organisationstheorien Wissenschaftstheoretische Anforderungen und kritische Analyse. Organisationstheorien II. Kritische Analysen neuerer sozialwissenschaftlicher Ansätze (Stuttgart, 1978)Google Scholar. See also McNeil, K., ‘Understanding Organizational Power: Building on the Weberian Legacy’, Administrative Science Quarterly, 23 (1978), 6590.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

44 WL, p. 214Google Scholar (author's translation). See Shils, and Fince, , Methodology, p. 112.Google Scholar