Article contents
Bureaucracy and Ideology: Britain and India in the Nineteenth Century
Published online by Cambridge University Press: 11 May 2009
Extract
Historians love to sail under bare poles with the spares tophamper of theoretical disquisition. Yet in the last resort their differences resolve themselves largely into differences of methodology, and nowhere more patently than in the history of bureaucracy where contingency and a priori ideas have long contested for the key position in historical explanation. This must be the excuse for an historian of colonial rule who finds himself driven to study the richer historiography of bureaucracy in metropolitan Britain and to trace out its movement with the simplicity of caricature before he can settle to his satisfaction the mechanics of historical causation in government house and secretariat.
- Type
- Research Article
- Information
- Copyright
- Copyright © Royal Historical Society 1980
References
1 Dicey, A. V., Law and Opinion in England (London, 2nd edn., 1914), pp. 22 ff.Google Scholar
2 Ibid., p. 450 ff.
3 MacDonagh, O., A Pattern of Government Growth: The Passenger Acts and their Enforcement (London, 1961), p. 348.Google Scholar
4 Robinson, R. and Gallagher, J., ‘The Imperialism of Free Trade’, Econ. H. R., 2nd ser., vi (1) (1953).Google Scholar
5 See Parris, H., ‘The Nineteenth-Century Revolution in Government: A Reappraisal Reappraised’, Historical Journal, iii (1960).Google Scholar
6 On the support of Buller, Hume and other Radicals for the Opium Wars, see Semmel, B., The Rise of Free Trade Imperialism (Cambridge, 1970), p. 153.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
7 See The Classical Economists and Economic Policy, ed. Coats, A. W. (London, 1971)Google Scholar; Great Britain and the Colonies, ed. Shaw, A. G. L. (London, 1970)Google Scholar; Halévy, E., La formation du radicalisme philosophique (Paris, 1904)Google Scholar; Redlich, J. and Hirst, F. W., Local Government in England (2 vols., London, 1903).Google Scholar
8 Supple, B., ‘Legislation and Virtue’, Historical Perspectives: Studies in English Thought and Society in Honour of J. H. Plumb, ed. McKendrick, N. (London, 1974), p. 212.Google Scholar
9 MacDonagh, O., ‘The Nineteenth-Century Revolution in Government: A Reappraisal’, Historical Journal, i (1958)Google Scholar; reprinted in The Victorian Revolution, ed. Stansky, P. (New York, 1973), p. 23.Google Scholar
10 MacDonagh, , Pattern of Government Growth, pp. 16–17.Google Scholar
11 Ibid., pp. 327, 344.
12 Robinson, R. and Gallagher, J., Africa and the Victorians (London, 1961), pp. 20–1.Google Scholar
13 Ibid., p. 19.
14 Ibid., p. 20.
15 Cf. Vincent, J., The Governing Passion: Cabinet Government and Party Politics in Britain, 1885–86 (London, 1974), pp. xiii–xivGoogle Scholar: ‘… all our evidence tends to show the rarity of contact between politicians and administrators, and the degree to which politicians lost interest in questions once they had turned from matters of cabinet antagonism into administrative grind.’
16 MacDonagh, O., Early Victorian Government, 1830–1870 (London, 1977), pp. 34 ff.Google Scholar
17 Finer, S. E., ‘The Transmission of Benthamite Ideas’, Studies in the Growth of Nineteenth-Century Government, ed. Sutherland, G. (London, 1972), p. 12.Google Scholar
18 Hilton, B., Corn, Cash, Commerce: The Economic Policies of the Tory Governments, 1815–1830 (Oxford, 1977), pp. 304–5.Google Scholar
19 Brown, L., The Board of Trade and the Free Trade Movement, 1830–42 (Oxford, 1958), p. 4Google Scholar; Hilton, , Corn, Cash, Commerce, p. 79.Google Scholar
20 Brown, , Board of Trade, p. 220.Google Scholar
21 Vincent, Even (Governing Passion, pp. 10, 18)Google Scholar allows that despite ‘the inner nihilism’ of party managers, the main actors were not necessarily always playing false, their ‘trades’ of ‘moral authority’ (Gladstone) or ‘intelligent traditionalism’ (Salisbury) also being ‘to some extent their genuine private selves’.
22 Cowling, M., The Impact of Hitler (Cambridge, 1975), p. 428.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
23 Cf. MacDonagh, , Early Victorian Government, p. 9Google Scholar: ‘… taking a broad view of the period as a whole, we find that the initial waves of centralizing and administrative bustle in 1830–50 are followed by two decades of relative indifference and inaction.’
24 MacDonagh, , Pattern of Government Growth, p. 320Google Scholar; ‘Nineteenth-Century Revolution’, Victorian Revolution, ed. Stansky, , p. 6.Google Scholar
25 See Roberts, D., Victorian Origins of the British Welfare State (Yale, 1960), pp. 12 ff.Google Scholar; Lubenov, W. C., The Politics of Government Growth (Newton Abbot, 1971), p. 15.Google Scholar
26 Peacock, A. T. and Wiseman, J., The Growth of Public Expenditure in the United Kingdom (London, 1967), Table 1, p. 37Google Scholar; Mitchell, B. R. and Deane, P., Abstract of British Historical Statistics (Cambridge, 1962), pp. 396–7.Google Scholar
27 Parliamentary Papers, 1833, xxiii, 458–9Google Scholar; 1849, xxx, 163–6; 1854–5, xx 439. The figures are vitiated by the absence of a consistent scheme of classification.
28 Abramovitz, M. and Eliasberg, V. F., The Growth of Public Employment in Great Britain (Princeton, 1957), p. 17.Google Scholar
29 Ibid., p. 39. Figures of non-industrial civil servants for 1900, 1939 and 1955 are taken from Gladden, E. N., Civil Services of the U.K. 1853–1970 (London, 1967), Table I, p. 4.Google Scholar
30 Mitchell, and Deane, , British Historical Statistics, pp. 396, 410.Google Scholar
31 Ibid., pp. 397, 416.
32 Peacock, and Wiseman, , Growth of Public Expenditure, pp. 101, 108.Google Scholar
33 See Brundage, A., The Making of the New Poor Law (London, 1978), pp. 25 ff.Google Scholar; Levy, S. Leon, Nassau W. Senior, 1790–1864 (Newton Abbot, 1970), pp. 80 ff., 247, ff.Google Scholar
34 Finer, S. E., The Life and Times of Sir Edwin Chadwick (London, 1952), p. 43n.Google Scholar
35 S. and Webb, B., English Poor Law History. Part II: The Last Hundred Years, I (London, 1929), p. 32n.Google Scholar
36 Ibid., p. 72.
37 Finer, , Chadwick, pp. 91–2.Google Scholar On p. 18 he ascribes the statement to ‘1832 MSS’.
38 Edinburgh Review, xliii (1836), 520.Google Scholar
39 Finer, , Chadwick, p. 91.Google Scholar
40 Senior already appreciated these problems in January 1833, and re-emphasized them in 1846 (Levy, , Nassau W. Senior, pp. 260–1, 274 ff.).Google Scholar The arguments are repeated in the Poor Law Report (1834), pp. 179–80Google Scholar, cited by B. and Webb, S., English Poor Law History, I, pp. 74–5.Google Scholar
41 Cited by Finer, , Chadwick, p. 51.Google Scholar
42 Ibid., p. 79.
43 30 July 1833 (Hansard, XX, p. 176).Google Scholar
44 Poor Law Report (1834), pp. 296–7, 331Google Scholar; cited by B. and Webb, S., English Poor Law History, I, pp. 78–9, 82.Google Scholar
45 Chadwick, E., On the Evils of Disunity in Central and Local Administration … and also on the New Centralization for the People … (London, 1885).Google Scholar
46 Hart, J, ‘The Genesis of the Northcote-Trevelyan Report’, Growth of Nineteenth-Century Government, ed. Sutherland, p. 72.Google Scholar
47 MacDonagh, , ‘Nineteenth-Century Revolution’Google Scholar, cited in Victorian Revolution, ed. Stansky, , p. 24.Google Scholar
48 Chadwick, , On the Evils of Disunity, pp. 78–9.Google Scholar
49 Smith, J. Toulmin, Considerations in Respect to the Public Health Act, 1848 (printed for private use only, 03 1853: Cambridge University Library)Google Scholar; Centralization or Representation (1848)Google Scholar; Government by Commissions, Illegal and Pernicious (1849)Google Scholar; Local Self-Government and Centralization (1851).Google Scholar
50 Mill, J. S., Considerations on Representative Government (1861)Google Scholar, Collected Works, ed. Robson, J. M., XIX (Toronto and Buffalo, 1977), p. 544.Google Scholar
51 Mill, J. S., Centralisation (1862)Google Scholar, Collected Works, XIX, pp. 609–10.Google Scholar
52 MacDonagh, , Early Victorian Government, p. 20.Google Scholar
53 Ibid., pp. 169, 178 fr.
54 MacDonagh, , Pattern of Government Growth, pp. 348–9.Google Scholar
55 MacDonagh, , Early Victorian Government, p. 21.Google Scholar
56 Lambert, R., Sir John Simon, 1816–1904, and English Social Administration (London, 1963), p. 605 fr.Google Scholar
57 MacDonagh, , Pattern of Government Growth, pp. 347–8Google Scholar: ‘The mere fact that (speaking not loosely but exactly) a prototype of present-day government can be found in the 1850s is arresting.’ Cf. ibid., p. 345: ‘The more or less conscious Fabianism, which had growth up since 1842, was by then [the end of the 1840s] working itself out in modes of regulation which resemble, often astonishingly, our modern systems.’
58 See Thomas, W., The Philosophical Radicals (Oxford, 1979).Google Scholar
59 Hobsbawm, E. J., Industry and Empire (London, 1968), p. 148.Google Scholar
60 Robinson, and Gallagher, , ‘The Imperialism of Free Trade’Google Scholar, reprinted Great Britain and the Colonies, ed. Shaw, , p. 147.Google Scholar
61 Weber, M., General Economic History (New York, 1961), pp. 221–4Google Scholar; van Leur, J. C., Indonesian Trade and Society (The Hague, 1955).Google Scholar
62 Cited by Marshall, P. J., East Indian Fortunes (Oxford, 1976), pp. 180–1.Google Scholar
63 Speech on impeachment of Warren Hastings, 15 February 1788, cited by Chapman, G. W., Edmund Burke: The Practical Imagination (Cambridge, Mass., 1967), p. 253.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
64 Roseveare, H., The Treasury (London, 1969)Google Scholar; Sutherland, L., The East India Company and Eighteenth-Century Politics (Oxford, 1952), p. 57.Google Scholar
65 Selections from the State Papers of the Governors-General of India: Lord Cornwallis, ed. Forrest, G. (Oxford, 1926), II, pp. 174–5Google Scholar; Aspinall, A., Cornwallis in Bengal (Manchester, 1931). pp. 81–2.Google Scholar
66 Selections from the State Papers, ed. Forrest, , pp. 95, 108.Google Scholar
67 Guha, Ranajit, A Rule of Properly for Bengal: An Essay on the Idea of Permanent Settlement (Paris and The Hague, 1963), pp. 170–1.Google Scholar
68 Aspinall, , Comwallis in Bengal, p. 81.Google Scholar
69 Selections from the State Papers, ed. Forrest, I, p. 123.Google Scholar
70 Regulation II, 1793 (cited by Stokes, E. T., The English Utilitarians and India (Oxford, 1959), p. 6).Google Scholar
71 For Munro, see Beaglehole, T. H., Thomas Munro and the Development of Administrative Policy in Madras, 1792–1818 (Cambridge, 1966), p. 28.Google Scholar See also Baden-Powell, B. H., The Indian Village Community (London, 1896), pp. 430 ff.Google Scholar
72 For the history of administrative developments, see Misra, B. B., The Central Administration of the East India Company 1773–1834 (Manchester, 1959), especially pp. 267 ff.Google Scholar
73 In 1827 the Court of Directors sent out orders to reduce expenditure to the 1823–4 standard (viz., pre-Burmese War). In two years Bentinck slashed expenditure from £18m to £16m (Chas. Grant, 13 June 1833 (Hansard, XVIII, p. 725)).Google Scholar
74 The Correspondence of Lord William Cavendish Bentinck, ed. Philips, C. H. (Oxford, 1977), II, p. 977.Google Scholar
75 The Correspondence of Lord William Bentinck, II, p. 1288.Google Scholar
76 See Ellenborough, to Bentinck, , 2 01 1830Google Scholar (Correspondence of Bentinck, ed. Philips, I, p. 380).Google Scholar
77 On Mackenzie's influence at the Board of Control, see Letters of T. B. Macaulay, ed. Pinney, T., II (Cambridge, 1974), pp. 266, 272, 274.Google Scholar
78 P.P., 1831–2, X, pt i, p. 18.
79 Cited by Stokes, , English Utilitarians and India, p. 152.Google Scholar
80 Ibid., p. 174; Rosselli, J., Lord William Bentinck (London, 1974), p. 323.Google Scholar
81 Cited by Hughes, E., ‘Civil Service Reform 1853–5’, History, n.s. xxvii (1942), 62.Google Scholar
82 Correspondence of Bentinck, ed. Philips, I, pp. 111 ff.Google Scholar
83 Evidence of Mill, James, 21 02 1832Google Scholar (P.P., 1831–2, X, pp. 42 fr.).
84 Hansard, XX, pp. 308 ffGoogle Scholar; XIX, pp. 667–71. Charles Buller cited Holt Mackenzie as a weighty authority for the abolition of councils at the subordinate presidencies.
85 See Black, R. D. Collison, Economic Thought and the Irish Question 1817–70 (Cambridge, 1960).Google Scholar
86 Ellenborough, to Bentinck, , 12 01 1830Google Scholar (Correspondence of Bentinck, ed. Philips, I, p. 382).Google Scholar
88 Moore, R. J., ‘Imperialism and “Free Trade” in India, 1835–4’, Econ. H. R., 2nd ser., xvii (1964), 135–45Google Scholar, and Sir Charles Wood's Indian Policy 1853–66 (London, 1966), ch. 7.Google Scholar
89 See Howlett, D. J., ‘Policy and Practice between Bentinck and Dalhousie: Public Works Policy’Google Scholar (unpublished paper in School of Oriental and African Studies Study Group on ‘Policy and Practice under Bentinck and Dalhousie’, 07 1978).Google Scholar
90 Cited P.P., 1852, X, p. 448.Google Scholar
91 Private Letters of the Marquess of Dalhousie, ed. Baird, J. G. A. (Edinburgh and London, 1910), pp. 284, 369Google Scholar; P.P. 1856, XLV, p. 113.Google Scholar
92 P.P., 1851–3, LXIX, p. 64; House of Lords Papers, 1857 (138); 1852 (105(e)).Google Scholar
93 Minute of Prinsep, H. T., 10 11, 1842Google Scholar (House of Lords Papers, 1852 (105(b))Google Scholar; Rosselli, , Bentinck, p. 202.Google Scholar
94 Cited by Stokes, , English Utilitarians and India, pp. 253–4.Google Scholar
95 Thomas, P. J., The Growth of Federal Finance in India (Madras, 1939), pp. 141 ff.Google Scholar; Moore, , Sir Charles Wood's Indian Policy, ch. 11.Google Scholar
96 Trevelyan's evidence, 7 July 1852 (P.P., 1852–1853, XXVIII, p. 490).Google Scholar See Minute of Trevelyan, 13 July 1859 (ibid., 1860, XLIX, p. 316).
97 P.P., 1873, XII, p. 98.Google Scholar
98 SirStrachey, John, India (1903 edn.), p. 115.Google Scholar
99 See Misra, B. B., The Administrative History of India, 1834–1947 (New Delhi, 1970), pp. 389–90.Google Scholar
100 Strachey, , India (1894 edn.), p. 63Google Scholar; ibid. (1903 edn.), p. 82. The Government of India laid down as official policy that the strength of the covenanted service was to be restricted to the numbers ‘absolutely necessary to fill the supervising and controlling offices for which Europeans are required’ (Memo, of Government of India to Secretary of State, i November 1892, para. 3 (P.P., 1894, LX, p. 71)).Google Scholar
- 9
- Cited by