Hostname: page-component-586b7cd67f-2plfb Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-11-25T18:18:08.053Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Is industrial relations reform the road to recovery in monopsonistic labour markets?

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  01 January 2023

David Peetz*
Affiliation:
Griffith University, Australia
*
David Peetz, Department of Employment Relations and Human Resources, Griffith University, Kessels Road, Nathan, QLD 4111, Australia. Email: [email protected]
Rights & Permissions [Opens in a new window]

Abstract

This article considers the national industrial relations policy aspects of the economic recovery agenda in Australia, in the context of the theory of monopsonistic competition, employment and productivity. This framework acknowledges the employer ability to exercise discretion in the setting of wages. The proposed reforms were unlikely to lead to any increase in economic growth through higher labour productivity or employment. Proposed agendas in enterprise bargaining, greenfields agreements and award simplification (as well as union regulation), would principally have reduced labour costs and incomes. In many circumstances, allowing employers to offer lower wages may lead to fewer filled jobs, higher labour turnover and absenteeism and lower employment. The incentive on employers to improve labour productivity may fall. Proposals to more energetically punish wage theft may have had the opposite effects, but these were abandoned by the government despite support from the other parties. In the end, the only part of the reform agenda to pass Parliament concerned changes to the definition and treatment of casual employees, but casual employment grew strongly before the Bill took effect, the crisis the Bill was meant to solve eased before the Bill was passed, and even if successful the changes would have done little to boost labour productivity.

Type
Rethinking work organisation and labour relations
Copyright
Copyright © The Author(s) 2021

The proven path for paying back debt is … by growing the economy through productivity enhancing reforms. Our focus will be on practical solutions to the most significant challenges [with]… industrial relations reform as a means of increasing our competitiveness.

So spoke the Australian Treasurer on 12 May 2020, identifying ‘industrial relations reform’ as central to recovery from the COVID-19 pandemic (Reference FrydenbergFrydenberg, 2020). To reinforce his message, in July he twice referred to, as inspirational, the policies of Ronald Reagan and Margaret Thatcher (Reference Bonyhady and DukeBonyhady and Duke, 2020; Reference BrinsdenBrinsden, 2020), possibly the Western leaders seen to have done the most to weaken unions (Reference GhilarducciGhilarducci, 1986). In November, his government introduced industrial relations (IR) legislation including, as part of its title, ‘Supporting Australia’s Jobs and Economic Recovery’. But how useful is such an agenda in seeking recovery?

The focus of this article is on the national IR public policy aspects of the recovery agenda in Australia. How did the national IR policy agenda react to the crisis, and how well formulated was the response? In particular, could this agenda promote economic recovery through higher employment and labour productivity? The agenda was only partially implemented, as the legislation was amended on its way through Parliament, prompting the Prime Minister to complain that there are ‘many in the Senate … who don’t share my passion for creating jobs’ (Reference Coorey and Marin-GuzmanCoorey and Marin-Guzman, 2021). Employers lamented the failure of the Bill and said ‘further efforts need to be made over the months ahead to secure support’ for its unfinished reforms (Reference Lambert, Willox and WestacottLambert et al., 2021). The politics of reform are not the main focus here. Instead, this article centres on the substantive areas proposed for IR reform in recovery from the pandemic and how that IR reform agenda could plausibly shape future labour productivity and employment growth. What was rejected in 2020 and 2021 could be reintroduced later. Key to assessing that agenda is a modern appreciation of how labour markets operate and shape decisions influencing employment and labour productivity. Central to the analysis are recent developments theorising the role of monopsony in labour markets and their implications for employment and labour productivity.

A brief consideration of theory

Monopsonistic competition and employment

Decades ago, it was conventional wisdom that lower wages led to higher employment, by making it cheaper to hire additional workers. The publication of Myth and Measurement by Reference Card and KruegerCard and Krueger (1995) was the first major challenge to this orthodoxy, making use both of recent American empirical evidence, including a two-state ‘natural experiment’ on minimum wage increases, and the theory of monopsony in labour markets. Since then, the evidence has swung quite substantially. There is little recent evidence that cutting minimum wages and conditions would boost employment (Reference BishopBishop, 2018). Likewise, although long debated in labour economic circles, it is now doubtful that minimum wage increases damage economic performance (Reference WinklerWinkler, 2019). In Britain, steady increases in the national minimum wage appear to have had no adverse employment effects (Reference MetcalfMetcalf, 2008).

What is monopsony? The key concept is of employer discretion. Analogous to a monopolist firm in a concentrated product market, a monopsonist firm in a concentrated labour market can lower wages below a ‘market clearing’ level. Employers do not pay a uniform single wage rate: they have a choice, within bounds, as to what wages they pay (Reference ManningManning, 2003). If they pay a lower wage they will have more vacancies and probably lower quality labour. If they pay a higher wage they will have fewer vacancies, higher quality labour, fewer product defects and higher labour costs. What they choose depends on what market niche they’re aiming for with their products, their personal preferences and beliefs and their tolerance for vacancies. What the monopsonistic firm loses in reduced output and revenue, it may more than make up in reduced labour costs (Council of Economic Advisers, 2016).

Most labour markets are not characterised by pure monopsony, but best described as manifesting ‘monopsonistic competition’, with features ranging from normal search frictions to active employer collusion against competition (Reference Krueger and PosnerKrueger and Posner, 2018). There is nothing new about employer collusion to push down wages: Adam Smith wrote of how ‘Masters are always and everywhere in a sort of tacit, but constant and uniform, combination, not to raise the wages of labour above their actual rate’ (Reference SmithSmith, 1776). Recent examples include agreements among Silicon Valley firms not to poach each others’ workers, similar arrangements between or within US restaurant chains, agreements between entertainment firms not to poach each others’ animators, and cases involving nurses in some American states (Reference KruegerKrueger, 2018). Even without collusion, there are plenty of search frictions (Economic Sciences Prize Committee, 2010). Workers cannot move jobs seamlessly. There are opportunity costs to job search. Moving homes is usually expensive, sometimes out of the question. Transport costs or times may put many alternative jobs out of viable reach. Some vacancies are not seen. Some involve unsuitable working hours. There may be difficulties accessing childcare. The present workplace may have congenial colleagues not guaranteed elsewhere.

All these barriers to workers’ likelihood of leaving a job for a better paid one elsewhere act to increase employer opportunities to lower wages below a perfect-competition market-clearing level. A firm paying slightly below some average wage would still have workers and so there is no single ‘going wage’ (just a range of plausible offers) (Reference KruegerKrueger, 2018). Hence neighbouring firms, paying different wages, may simultaneously experience labour shortages and labour surpluses (Reference PeetzPeetz, 1998).

There is ample evidence that monopsonistic competition, rather than perfect competition, is the rule in labour markets. Observers see no single wage for a specific type of labour, but instead considerable dispersion, even for people with similar skills doing similar jobs. Second, differences in pay rates received by men and women, and by people of different racial or ethnic backgrounds, even in the same job and between workers with similar labour productivity, would not occur in a perfectly competitive market (Reference BrosnanBrosnan, 1996). Laws, not perfectly competitive markets, act to end this discrimination in pay. Third, ‘skills shortages’ reflect the inability of wages to adjust as if in perfectly competitive markets, since employers resist raising wages to overcome them. A contemporary example is the reluctance of employers in agriculture to raise wages or change labour hire arrangements to attract labour, despite a ‘labour shortage’ (Reference Robinson and Felton-TaylorRobinson and Felton-Taylor, 2021; Reference SullivanSullivan, 2020). Hospitality employers claim a labour shortage despite recently succeeding in reducing penalty rates (Reference LambertLambert, 2020). Fourth, despite the predictions of the perfect competition model that employers will not pay for general training, firms often choose to pay for such training. Fifth, empirical estimates of the impact of minimum wage laws, mentioned above, do not support the perfectly competitive model. Sixth, empirical estimates of the elasticity of labour supply are well below 1.0, whereas in the perfectly competitive model elasticity should be infinite, with a firm losing all its workers if it drops wages below the going rate (Reference Booth and KaticBooth and Katic, 2010). Seventh, there is evidence of monopsony effects on wages. In one study, movement from a labour market on the 25th percentile of concentration to one on the 75th percentile was associated with a 17% decline in advertised wages (Reference Marinescu, Ouss and PapeMarinescu et al., 2020).

Monopsonistic characteristics in labour markets appear to be increasing. An Austrian study suggests that just one aspect of it accounts for two fifths of the decline in the wages share there over two decades (Reference Jarosch, Nimczik and SorkinJarosch et al., 2019). Other overseas research also points to increasing domination by a small number of buyers of labour – that is, employers (Reference Autor, Dorn and KatzAutor et al., 2017). In Australia, Treasury has estimated that job switching has reduced and attributes the decline in wages growth to this phenomenon (Reference DeutscherDeutscher, 2019). A decline in job switching, after controlling for other factors, is symptomatic of rising monopsony.

Labour productivity

A common rationale for IR reform is to enhance labour productivity (Reference PeetzPeetz, 2012). Productivity is the ratio between the quantity of output (goods and services produced) and the quantity of inputs. Measures of productivity are based on quantities, not prices. Productivity is not measured by the value of output, or the cost of input, or the amount of output not produced when there are no hours worked due to strikes. There are three main measures of productivity: labour, capital and multi-factor. In public debate, the main focus is on labour productivity: the ratio of output to labour input. Labour productivity is related to the quantity of labour input, not its cost. It is the focus of public debate mainly because it is easier to understand and measure than capital or multi-factor productivity, but it is also prominent among economists because it provides the foundation for increases in living standards. Higher labour productivity means greater output per worker, and the greater value from that output can be shared between workers and employers (Reference KrugmanKrugman, 1994).

Productivity is a widely misunderstood concept, including by workplace managers, who often mean something else when they answer questions about productivity – evidenced, for example, in the 1995 Australian Workplace Industrial Relations Survey (Reference Morehead, Steele and AlexanderMorehead et al., 1997). Labour productivity is not directly changed by movements in the value of either the output (its price) or of the input (the hourly wage). So if the price of the product goes up, that does not mean labour productivity has gone up. If the wage (base pay, penalty rate or overtime premium) paid to the workers producing it goes up, that does not mean that labour productivity has gone down.

It does not follow that changes in prices or wages have no indirect impact on labour productivity, but that does not always go the way preconceptions might lead. For example, if the price of labour (wage) goes up, then firms may have an incentive to re-organise firm production and invest in labour-saving technology, so that less labour is required to produce the same output. The introduction of new technology, improvements in workforce education and training, an increase in non-labour inputs relative to labour, and labour-saving devices, can all improve labour productivity (Australian Bureau of Statistics [ABS], 2008). Studies also identify ‘efficiency wages’ (Reference StiglitzStiglitz, 1976), whereby employers pay a higher wage to induce greater commitment, lower labour turnover and higher labour productivity from employees. By a similar logic, raising employment certainty for insecure workers might, over the long run, increase labour productivity. Reference Wolfers and ZilinskyWolfers and Zilinsky (2015) broadly reviewed the literature on the links between wage increases and labour productivity. They found a positive relationship — higher wages: motivated employees to work harder; attracted more capable and productive workers; reduced labour turnover; enhanced quality and customer service; reduced disciplinary problems and absenteeism; reduced the need for employee monitoring; and reduced employee concerns about income security.

Other things being equal, then, increasing the relative price of an input increases the incentive for firms to introduce technology to increase that input’s labour productivity. Conversely, reducing the price of labour reduces the incentive for investments to increase labour productivity. So, reducing wages, over the medium to longer term, reduces labour productivity. An alternative mechanism by which high(er) wages may affect labour productivity is by cutting the funds available for investment: if the increase in wages is so large as to starve firms of those resources, then labour productivity growth may stall and the firm may close. Empirically, the relative price effect appears to dominate. Hence, during the centralised period of the prices and incomes Accord in Australia (the 1980s), labour productivity growth slowed substantially (ABS, 2021) because there was a fall in real wages.

It might be argued that regulations requiring employers pay higher wages at certain times or in certain circumstances would change behaviour, and thereby suppress labour productivity below the optimal level a freely operating market would determine. In monopsonistic competition, however, there is no particular reason to assume that a productivity-maximising equilibrium would otherwise be reached. An employer may choose a low-wage production method with high labour turnover and absenteeism and low labour productivity. If monopsony means that employers ‘voluntarily’ experience a permanent labour ‘shortage’, then higher wages can lead both to higher employment (by increasing labour supply) and, over the medium term, higher labour productivity (by increasing the incentive to invest in labour-saving technology). Increased labour supply can also increase capital productivity (the ratio of output to capital input), through better utilisation of existing capital stock, but capital productivity is beyond the scope of this paper.

What about restricting the power of unions? There is a long history of studies of the links between unions and labour productivity, with the most famous, thorough review being over three decades ago (Reference Freeman and MedoffFreeman and Medoff, 1984). The subsequent consensus was that there was no consistent relationship evident between unions and productivity; but the direct impact of unions on productivity tended towards zero. The impact, it appeared, depended on circumstances (Reference FreemanFreeman, 2005; Reference KaufmanKaufman, 2005). Two of the most influential studies of labour productivity (Reference Appelbaum, Gittell and LeanaAppelbaum et al., 2011; Reference Black and LynchBlack and Lynch, 2001), consistent with a series of other investigations (e.g. Reference Alexander and GreenAlexander and Green, 1992; Reference MasMas, 2008), found that unionised firms that encouraged participation and consultation had higher productivity than counterparts, while those with confrontationist relations had lower. A recent study in Norway, where consultation prevails, found that ‘increasing union density at the firm level leads to a substantial increase in both productivity and wages’ (Reference Barth, Bryson and Dale-OlsenBarth et al., 2020). Some exclusively Australian studies had earlier found: a positive relationship between unionism and productivity at workplaces where unions are active (Reference WoodenWooden, 2000); higher levels of self-claimed productivity associated with collective bargaining coverage (Reference Fry, Jarvis and LoundesFry et al., 2002); and higher productivity in firms with high rates of union membership than in firms with no union members (Reference Tseng and WoodenTseng and Wooden, 2001). Unionism leads to higher wages (Reference Blanchflower and BrysonBlanchflower and Bryson, 2004; Reference StewartStewart, 1991) which, as mentioned above, appears to lead to higher labour productivity over the longer term. IR reforms aimed at improving the climate for cooperation probably do more to improve labour productivity that reforms trying to alter relative prices of inputs.

Implications for labour market reforms

What then are the labour market implications of commonly demanded reforms? At a general level, we can say that reforms that alter the cost of labour would have ambiguous and probably very small effects on employment in the context of monopsonistic labour markets. Those which reduce the cost of labour would also likely reduce the growth of labour productivity (though not necessarily its level, as the logic of capitalism is to constantly increase labour productivity through technological change: Reference MarxMarx, 1887). Reforms that increased the cost of labour would likely, at least within bounds, increase the rate of labour productivity growth.

Higher minimum wages reduce the room for monopsony power and may, in certain circumstances (such as perceived labour shortages), lead to higher employment by increasing the number of filled jobs. These conditions may not apply in a sudden, large supply-side shock (as in a pandemic) where the primary public policy response was fiscal (‘JobKeeper’), not regulatory. Our interest, though, is in the ‘recovery’ phase, as that is the context in which the proposed reforms are being introduced. When the economy is improving, lower wage minimums are likely to lead to reduced employment in monopsonistic labour markets, and higher wage minimums can lead to increased employment, especially in any areas of apparent labour shortage.

Of course, wages cannot be increased in all circumstances or by unlimited amounts without negative employment or labour productivity effects. Any wage increase obviously needs to be not so large as to send a firm out of business. So it depends on circumstances and amounts. An analogy might be drawn with water: most plants benefit from the addition of water, but too much can kill them (and indeed, too much water can even kill humans) (Reference KruszelnickiKruszelnicki, 2012).

Those are the general principles. What about the more specific agenda of IR reform that was embodied in Australia’s recent Omnibus Bill and Act? To analyse that, we first consider the context in which those reforms were introduced.

Context

The COVID-19 pandemic led to sharp deterioration in the Australian economy and the labour market, though not as severely as first anticipated, principally due to an expensive wage subsidy (‘JobKeeper’) introduced early in the pandemic, and fiscal stimulus. Quarterly growth in gross domestic product (GDP) went from + 0.4% to -7.0% between December quarter 2019 and June quarter 2020. Unemployment rose from 5.2% in March 2020 to peak at 7.5% in July. Employment fell by 872,000 or 6.7% over 2 months to May 2020, while underemployment rose from 9.3% to 14.1%. In the second half of 2020, a significant part of these effects reversed. GDP grew by 3.4% and 3.1% in September and December quarters of 2020, respectively. Unemployment fell to 6.3% by January 2021, by which time employment had grown 448,000 from July 2020. Underemployment fell to 8.7%. The biggest problem was continuing low wages growth (Reference KohlerKohler, 2021).

Industrial relations effects and problems in the pandemic

Especially during the peak of pandemic fears in the first half of 2020, a number of IR changes occurred (Reference KaineKaine, 2020; Reference MarkeyMarkey, 2020; Treasury, 2020; Workplace Express, 2020c). The Fair Work Commission (FWC) varied over 100 awards to provide for various forms of short-term pandemic leave. It also deferred the minimum wage increase to the majority of workers. Consideration of a union claim for special allowances for some at-risk workers was dragged out. Paid pandemic leave for several categories of health and aged care workers who had to miss work and had exhausted other leave entitlements was won in July, and extended in October to March 2021. It did not apply to ‘short term’ casuals. A campaign for paid leave for all casual workers who lose pay by following isolation rules after being exposed to COVID-19 was unsuccessful. Unfair dismissal claims rose by 60%. The second-largest airline, Virgin, went into receivership and the largest, Qantas, retrenched 6000 workers, stood down most of the remainder and faced disputes in the FWC over other aspects of its response. Child care became (briefly) free. Some universities, facing big drops in international student numbers, negotiated wage freezes or cuts with their staff, or tried (and often failed) to do so unilaterally.

The ‘JobKeeper’ wage subsidy scheme was introduced, a result of pressure from the Australian Council of Trade Unions (ACTU), supported by some business groups. Unemployment benefits (‘JobSeeker’) were temporarily increased. ‘Essential’ workers (for some, this was a new definition of their work) became exposed to unaccustomed occupational risks, and their low pay rates were exposed to public debate. Temporary flexibility provisions were inserted in awards, enabling 41% of employers to direct employees to work reduced hours, and another 29% made other directions, such as to work on different days to normal (Nous Group, 2020). Aside from the loss of working hours, or jobs, for hundreds of thousands of workers, probably the biggest change was in the location of work. For many (perhaps a third of the workforce), their place of work moved to their home. Some employers were forced to adapt to a form of flexibility they may have long resisted. There were negative effects that were also heavily gendered, especially when schools closed and the household division of labour saw women disproportionately interrupt their work to support other family members. This had measurable effects on the productivity of, for example, women academics (Reference MinelloMinello, 2020). The FWC indicated it would consider whether some award flexibilities to facilitate working from home should become permanent (Workplace Express, 2020b).

The pandemic also revealed a number of deficiencies in the IR system. Probably the most prominent was the role of employment precarity and multiple job holding, especially in aged care and hotel quarantine services, in spreading the virus. In aged care, many workers are employed in effect as ‘casuals’ (Reference Charlesworth and HoweCharlesworth and Howe, 2018) or classed as independent contractors, and due to inadequate hours in a single job many work in multiple jobs across the sector. Workers classed as independent contractors, and those formally classed as casuals, had no access to annual or sick leave. Independent contractors had no access to workers compensation, received little training and were outside the scope of the FWC. The vulnerability of these workers has implications for the health of all. Contracting and casual labour facilitated Australia’s second wave of COVID-19 (Reference HoldenHolden, 2020), and there is evidence that sick leave reduces the incidence of COVID-19 (Reference Pichler, Wen and ZiebarthPichler et al., 2020). Insecure workers, many of whom were underemployed (Reference BergBerg, 2016; Chartered Institute of Personnel and Development [CIPD], 2017) had a strong financial incentive to log on for work even with COVID symptoms or awaiting test results, with potentially fatal consequences (Reference ChristmassChristmass, 2020; Reference SmithSmith, 2020).

Platform firms are notorious for not providing training (Reference Alkhatib, Bernstein and LeviAlkhatib et al., 2017; Reference Broughton, Gloster and MarvellBroughton et al., 2018), and would not waste money on COVID-19 infection training – an issue critical in infection control in nursing homes and elsewhere (Reference CoatsworthCoatsworth, 2020; Reference Connolly, Carter and RobbConnolly et al., 2020). Many platform workers were expected to do infection training in their own time. Most of these problem areas were not addressed by the legislation seeking to implement the IR reform agenda (referred to as the ‘Omnibus Bill’), other than casual employment, and as discussed below the origins of that change long pre-date the pandemic. It can fairly be said that the stated purpose of IR reform was not to address pandemic-related problems with IR but to promote post-pandemic economic recovery.

The ambivalent approach to tripartism in the pandemic

‘We’re all in this together’ echoed as a cultural meme through the COVID-19 pandemic. One of the more unexpected but inconsistent manifestations of this approach was in IR policy. The approach was unexpected because, for most of the period since 2013, IR policy had been determined without meaningful consultation with trade unions, and was hostile towards unions (Reference BadhamBadham, 2017). Most recent had been an attempt to introduce the ‘Ensuring Integrity’ (EI) Bill, targeting union organisation. Under it, in various (and varying) circumstances: a union’s registration could be cancelled; it could be reconstituted with an administrator appointed; the government of the day could block union amalgamations; and a single employee, employer or industry lobbyist could initiate certain proceedings. These provisions reinforced a long-held perception of the majority governing party as the party of capital (Reference CrispCrisp, 1965). Attitudes towards unions divide candidates from the major parties by more than any other issue (Reference TaftTaft, 1998).

The approach was inconsistent because during the pandemic the government appeared to oscillate between a consensus approach to IR and its more usual agenda. Although publicly the Australian government strongly rejected emulating wage subsidy announcements of other conservative governments, the relevant Minister was reportedly conversing daily with the secretary of the ACTU (Reference MaleyMaley, 2020). The result was the ‘JobKeeper’ wage subsidy scheme. This engagement with the ACTU, and some other decisions, led some to suggest that the government had embraced ‘consensus politics’ (Reference GrattanGrattan, 2020). The burial of consensus by April-May 2020 seemed signified by reports that the government was pursuing its already-defeated EI Bill (Reference Marin-GuzmanMarin-Guzman, 2020a), and then the speech by the Treasurer that opened this article. Yet two weeks later, the Prime Minister (PM) relaunched the consensus rhetoric with the announcement of five tripartite working partiesFootnote 1 to ‘chart a practical reform agenda’ for Australia’s IR system. The PM also announced the withdrawal of the EI Bill, its philosophy being diametrically opposed to the rhetoric of consensus.

An omnibus Bill containing a package of reforms, reflecting the five topics covered by the working parties, was to be introduced late in the year (Workplace Express, 2020d). Like all such legislation, it would be ‘pragmatic, balanced and realistic’ and not ideologically-driven (Workplace Express, 2020e). The reform areas were casual employment, award simplification, enterprise bargaining, greenfields agreements and wage theft – but, as we shall see, in the end only the provisions on casuals survived Parliament and made it into the Fair Work Amendment (Supporting Australia’s Jobs and Economic Recovery) Act 2021.

Labour productivity, employment and the reform agendas

Five reform agendas, discussed below, were covered by the working parties. The working parties met from June through September 2020. There was no agreement on most of the matters at the end of the process, with some unexpected moments of agreement between the ACTU and some employers thwarted by other employer groups (Workplace Express, 2020f). After talks ended, employer bodies lobbied the government to adopt its own agenda, while the ACTU conducted much of its lobbying in the media and with crossbench Senators (Workplace Express, 2020d).

The text below discusses the broad agenda areas. The final content of the Act reflected the outcome of political processes, and so was much narrower than the reform agenda, though the history of the actors suggests the rest of the agenda would be revived if the political moment suited.

Award simplification

Award ‘simplification’ was the issue on which most employer attention focused before the pandemic. ‘Awards’ are legally binding instruments, issued by the main industrial tribunal, that set skill-based minimum pay and conditions for each industry and occupation. Lobbyists for large corporations had called for a ‘simpler’ IR system. Yet the number of awards had already been cut, from more than 2000 federally in 2006, to just 121 (Reference Mattson and MurphyMattson and Murphy, 2020). By 2020, after three decades of ‘award restructuring’, ‘award modernisation’ and ‘award simplification’, awards had similar rates of pay for similar types of work. Officials nonetheless argued that awards still appeared complex to employers, and the Minister flagged this would be addressed in his omnibus legislation (Workplace Express, 2020a).

In the IR reform agenda, ‘simplifying’ appeared more to be a euphemism for reducing or removing penalty rates, related concepts like overtime pay, shift premiums and provisions on starting or finishing times, or the minimum pay rates themselves (Australian Mines and Metals Association, 2015). Still, the potential employment effects of changes to penalty rates appeared complex, since recent research on both the supply side (Reference Peetz, Bruynius and MurrayPeetz et al., 2019) and the demand side (Reference PickeringPickering, 2020; Reference Yu and PeetzYu and Peetz, 2018) suggest that the main effect is likely to be an increase in hours worked per employee (at lower hourly pay) but no significant gain in the number of employees.

In the face of political difficulties, much of that ‘simplification’ agenda was set aside before the Bill entered Parliament. What remained was principally a proposal to enable hours for part-time employees to be increased without any overtime premium. The incentive effects would be twofold. First, employers would be able to reduce the guaranteed (and actual) hours of existing part-time employees, knowing that they could increase actual hours at a later stage if this suited, without the need to pay any overtime premium (the ‘guaranteed hours effect’). Second, employers would face a reduced incentive to take on additional workers, as they could cheaply increase hours for existing workers as demand increased without incurring the fixed costs of recruitment, induction and training (a ‘fixed costs effect’).

The net impact on employment would likely be negative. The fixed costs effect would reduce the number of people employed, especially as the previously-mentioned research on monopsony suggests that any positive demand impact on employment would likely probably be negligible. The guaranteed hours effect would probably reduce the number of hours worked. The impact on underemployment is ambiguous.Footnote 2 The impact of this policy on labour productivity would be small and negative, since reducing labour costs could be expected to reduce labour productivity.Footnote 3

Enterprise bargaining

Both unions and employers claimed the enterprise bargaining system was too complex, but without any agreement over how to simplify it. Some employers had called for the ‘better off overall test’ (BOOT) to be abolished (Reference Marin-GuzmanMarin-Guzman, 2020b). The BOOT meant a proposed agreement had to make any worker better off compared to how they were under their award. The Bill tried to override the BOOT for a specific group and for a specific time.Footnote 4 It provoked so much opposition that the Minister withdrew those provisions before they reached the Senate. Diminution or abolition of the BOOT, or reduced scrutiny of proposed agreements (as also proposed in the Bill), would reduce labour costs for employers, and expand EBA coverage but very likely through agreements with poor wages and conditions, possibly sub-award. Better paying EBAs would not be affected by any change to the BOOT. Again, neither increased employment nor increased labour productivity need follow.

If the purpose of enterprise bargaining is to achieve agreement between capital and labour, though, the major complexity issue is in the barriers facing worker representatives. The enterprise bargaining and industrial action provisions in the Fair Work Act occupy over 120 pages, not counting those relating to remedies and enforcement. The bar for prohibiting a strike is low (Reference McCrystalMcCrystal, 2019). Australia’s framework is much more complex than the comparable United Kingdom statute. Even the Productivity Commission (2015) questioned the ‘overly complex processes for secret ballots’.

There are further complexities that are uncommon in other collective bargaining systems. For example, unions are banned from engaging in pattern bargaining, though no comparable prohibitions are placed on employer behaviour. Over time, these provisions have restricted workers’ rights to take industrial action. While awards have been simplified, collective bargaining has become more complex. The level of detail in Australian legislation, beyond that in most other OECD countries, appears to principally influence the parties’ balance of power (Reference LongLong, 2017). Unless such complexity bias was addressed, the reform proposals would likely have created no employment gains and, very likely, labour productivity losses.

Greenfields agreements

Greenfields agreements are agreements that cover a new project, usually in construction, but also (less commonly) outsourced services, new ventures and, rarely, theatrical shows (Reference MayMay, 2016). The reform agenda here was to increase the duration of agreements on larger construction and new project sites (employers wanted ‘project life’ agreements: Reference Lambert, Willox and WestacottLambert et al., 2021). In the Bill, for up to 8 years, any employees recruited to a new ‘major’ project covered by one would be unable to negotiate better conditions through industrial action. A major project was anything worth above $250 million that the minister declares to be ‘major’ (about the size of a motorsport entertainment complex or a medicinal cannabis plant (Australian Government, 2021; Reference TabetTabet, 2020). Employees there would be denied the right to negotiate over a long period of eight years. Owing to an interaction with an earlier amendment to the Act,Footnote 5 an employer-drafted ‘agreement’ could be imposed upon employees by the tribunal, enabling a corporation a new ‘major’ project to unilaterally deny workers their rights to industrial action otherwise available to them for eight years. This would be somewhat reminiscent of the unilateral ‘employer greenfields agreements’ (EGAs) of the WorkChoices era, which cut penalty rates, overtime pay and shift premiums. As with other construction reforms (Reference Allan, Dungan and PeetzAllan et al., 2010), the biggest effect would mainly have been be upon the distribution of income between labour and capital in construction, not on enhancing labour productivity or employment.

Casual employees

The changes to casual employment were the only part of the original reform agenda that passed the Parliament, so special attention is given here. Two Federal Court cases in this area were probably the biggest single factor leading to the introduction of the Bill, owing to concern by some employer organisations about the potential cost. Employers claimed that failure to pass changes overturning the court would lead to ‘widespread business closures and mass job losses’ (Reference Lambert, Willox and WestacottLambert et al., 2021).

Two Federal Court cases in 2018 and 2020 (WorkPacPty Ltd v Skene (2018) FCAFC 131; WorkPac Pty Ltd v Rossato (2020) FCAFC 84) had challenged a situation whereby for decades, employees defined as casual by their employer were not entitled to paid annual leave or sick leave. So one in four Australian workers had no annual leave from their employer (ABS, 2021). Their employment contract effectively lasted for one shift. An employer who wanted to avoid invoking unfair dismissal laws – which technically only apply to those ‘employed on a regular and systematic basis’ – could simply reduce the casual’s hours, perhaps to zero. These workers’ power was diminished further by very low union density. Hence, casuals were generally paid at a lower rate than their ‘permanent’ equivalents, especially in low-paid occupations (Reference Laß and WoodenLaß and Wooden, 2019). Firms have also used casual employment as a probationary, low-wage pathway into permanent positions. In the mining industry, for example, companies have deployed labour-hire workers alongside permanent employees, full-time, doing identical work (Reference Murray and PeetzMurray and Peetz, 2010). Casual employment is not especially about flexibility of work. Most ‘casuals’ expect to be with their employer in a year’s time, and at least half work the same hours week to week. Their working arrangements are not a response to any employer’s need to flexibly deploy labour over short periods in a variety of situations (Reference PeetzPeetz, 2020). They are cheap and stable, but the option of reducing hours, or cutting off all work, has given the employer substantial power over these employees.

Eventually, after a leave-deprived mining employee sought compensation for unpaid leave from his former employer, the Federal Court determined he had not been a genuine casual, and should be paid for leave owed. Another leave-deprived employee won a similar case. Appeals against these two decisions are currently before the High Court. This High Court challenge, however, became largely irrelevant on 26 March 2021, when the Fair Work Act 2009 was finally amended. This amendment enshrined employers’ right to define someone as casual. If the employer does that at the start of the worker’s employment, and points out that there is no promise of continuing employment, then the employee is henceforth indisputably a casual. Employers can describe casual workers as casual even if they then have regular, continuing employment. The employee is without leave entitlements, and can have his or her hours cut, or cut out, at the decision of the employer. The newly-amended Act explicitly excludes consideration of what the employer actually does with the employee, making the only consideration at law what the employer claimed they would do, even if this was never actually implemented.Footnote 6

Employers’ organisations strongly advocated for these changes. In May 2020 they claimed that the Court decisions were ‘discouraging employers from retaining casuals [or] engaging new employees’ and ‘increasing the level of unemployment’ (Reference WilcoxWilcox, 2020). Failing to be discouraged, employers themselves increased ‘casual’ employment (i.e., of workers without leave entitlements) over the 6 months after that claim was made by 17.3%, while they increased that of workers with leave entitlements by just 3.0%.

While those data suggest no employment gain would come from the legislation to overturn the Court decision, it is noteworthy that, even if there was any gain, it would not be in jobs generally considered to have high ‘job quality’ (Reference Campbell and ChalmersCampbell and Chalmers, 2008). The stylised features of casual employment – high turnover, low commitment, low pay – are generally the opposite of ‘efficiency wage’ notions of how to boost labour productivity (Reference StiglitzStiglitz, 1976; Reference Wolfers and ZilinskyWolfers and Zilinsky, 2015), so it is unlikely the promotion of casual employment, if successful, would increase labour productivity.

Compliance and enforcement

Observers have long complained about systematic underpayment (‘wage theft’) by many employers (heightened since the loss of union rights of entry) and about business models, such as franchising and sub-contracting, that encourage it. The bill partly addressed this issue by criminalising certain deliberate instances of this behaviour. It would have overridden some state laws. These provisions were uncontroversial and indeed the only subject of agreement between employers, unions and government. They did not go far: the maximum penalty had been rarely used, not many offenders were caught, and punishments were light (Reference CorrCorr, 2017). The Bill proposed widening the range of matters that could be dealt with through the small claims process, rather than the full court system. This was a positive step but would not help those reluctant to devote the time and money to such a process. To the extent that it would have prevented sub-legal wages and conditions, it would have enhanced labour productivity and forced reasonable wage offers by employers.

It appeared, though, that this was not so much part of a reform agenda as it was a trade, offered to cross-benchers in return for support for the remaining reform agenda. When several other aspects of the Bill faced certain defeat, the Government withdrew from Parliament these provisions – probably the aspect of the Bill most likely to promote labour productivity – with observers suggesting ‘they may be now held in reserve to be used as leverage to try and drive further change’ (Reference Coorey and Marin-GuzmanCoorey and Marin-Guzman, 2021).

Conclusion

The existence and indeed the growth of monopsonistic features in labour markets renders irrelevant many old ideas about the economic consequences of IR reform. An understanding of how labour costs shape labour productivity reveals many assumptions to be false as well. Recent theoretical models and empirical data indicate that the IR reforms sought by the Australian government were unlikely to lead to any increase in economic growth through higher labour productivity or employment. In relation to proposed agendas in enterprise bargaining, greenfields agreements and award simplification (as well as union regulation), the principal effect would have been to reduce labour incomes. This may redistribute resources from labour to capital, but would not boost economic recovery. In many circumstances, allowing employers to offer lower wages may mean that fewer jobs are filled, labour turnover is higher, absenteeism is higher and employment is lower. It may reduce the incentive on employers to implement investments that would improve labour productivity. Proposals to more energetically punish wage theft may have had the opposite effects, but it turned out that these were incidental to the politics of reform, not a core part of the reform agenda. They were abandoned by the government despite support from the other parties.

In the end, the only part of the reform agenda that passed Parliament concerned changes to the definition and treatment of casual employees. But this was more about fixing a problem for employers who had misused casuals anyway, who feared having to compensate casuals for the leave entitlements they had been denied. Casual employment grew strongly before the Bill took effect, the crisis in employment the Bill was meant to solve eased before the Bill was passed, and even if successful this would have done little to boost labour productivity.

In some cases, claims about the labour productivity and employment gains from such an agenda might just be rhetoric to advance a cause. In some others, the view that such an agenda could produce higher employment and labour productivity might reflect an outdated understanding of labour markets, one that ignores the role of monopsony, and mistaken views about the drivers of labour productivity, for example by confusing it with costs or profitability. Or it may simply reflect cognitive dissonance (Reference FestingerFestinger, 1957), and the desire to believe what is in one’s interests. Among those in positions of power, it might reflect the particular incentives they face. The range of plausible national income distributions means that the highest income earners have a strong incentive to promote policies that reduce tax for the rich or increase the surplus generated by labour that can be transformed into profit (Reference MilanovicMilanovic, 2016). However, it is unwise to admit this as a motivation for policy, as it would not attract public support. So, policies aimed at redistributing income upwards are portrayed as promoting growth or recovery. Those aspects of the agenda that were frustrated by the Parliament remain on the business sector’s agenda and could, in favourable circumstances, be revived. Alternatively, the EI Bill could return to the agenda, but the literature discussed earlier suggests that, overall, it offers little, probably nothing, for labour productivity and not much more for employment.

In the meantime, other policy agendas receive inadequate attention. While some, such as economic stimulus, were considered and even enacted, others such as movement towards reconstruction (Reference Pennington and StanfordPennington and Stanford, 2020) receive little or no attention, and problems with the IR system that the pandemic exposed were not addressed. To the extent that it diverted attention from elsewhere, the focus on industrial relations reform as the vehicle for recovery probably reduced, rather than increased, economic growth and recovery.

Funding

The author(s) received no financial support for the research, authorship, and/or publication of this article.

Footnotes

Declaration of conflicting interests

The author(s) declared no potential conflicts of interest with respect to the research, authorship, and/or publication of this article.

1. Their composition varied, but all contained members from government, unions and employer organisations.

2. The guaranteed hours effect would increase underemployment, while the fixed costs would reduce it if the additional hours went to employees who wanted to work more hours (for instance, instead of two underemployed workers, there could be one fully employed and one unemployed person.)

3. The other main proposal in the Bill relevant to this heading would have allowed employers to give ‘flexible work directions’ to employees to perform new types of work, or at new locations, if such directions are reasonable to ‘assist in the revival of the employer’s enterprise’. ‘Revival’ was not defined.

4. For workers in firms that could claim they were affected by COVID-19, through agreements made within 2 years of passage of the Bill, though their effects could last many more.

5. A new subsection (4) was added to section 182, allowing a greenfields agreement to be deemed as approved, even if the relevant union had not signed off on the agreement, after a period of 6 months. In this iteration, however, employers eschewed the opportunity to make use of these unilateral greenfields instruments (Reference O’CallaghanO’Callaghan, 2017), presumably because the BOOT test made them of minimal value for cutting pay and conditions. Moreover, withholding the right to strike for 4 years would be of questionable benefit if employers felt vulnerable to retaliatory action once 4 years expired. This situation would likely change significantly if ‘project life’ agreements came into effect.

6. However, the new Act does hold out the prospect of a better life in some respects. If, after a period of 12 months, regular ‘casual’ employees want ‘permanent’ status, many can ask for it, and the employer should grant their wish unless there are reasonable grounds not to. Leave-deprived employees can at least take that question to court, if they have the money and persistence to do so.

References

Alexander, MJ, Green, R (1992) Workplace productivity and joint consultation. Australian Bulletin of Labour 18(2): 95118.Google Scholar
Alkhatib, A, Bernstein, MS, Levi, M (2017) Examining crowd work and gig work through the historical lens of piecework. In: CHI’17 – proceedings of the 2017 CHI conference on human factors in computing systems, Denver, CO, 6–11 May, pp. 45994616. New York: Association for Computing Machinery.Google Scholar
Allan, C, Dungan, A, Peetz, D (2010) ‘Anomalies’, damned ‘anomalies’ and statistics: construction industry productivity in Australia. Journal of Industrial Relations 52(1): 6179.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Appelbaum, E, Gittell, JH, Leana, C (2011) High-performance Work Practices and Sustainable Economic Growth. Memo to Obama Administration, Brandeis University, 20 March. Available at: https://cepr.net/report/high-performance-work-practices-and-sustainable-economic-growth/ (accessed 10 April 2021).Google Scholar
Australian Bureau of Statistics (ABS) (2008) Feature article: a spotlight on quarterly labour productivity. Australian Economic Indicators, Cat no 1350.0. Canberra, ACT, Australia: ABS.Google Scholar
Australian Bureau of Statistics (ABS) (2021) Australian system of national accounts. Cat no 5204.0. Canberra, ACT, Australia: ABS.Google Scholar
Australian Government (2021) Current Major Projects. Available at: https://business.gov.au/Grants-and-Programs/Major-Project-Status/Current-Major-Projects (accessed 10 April 2021).Google Scholar
Australian Mines and Metals Association (2015) Getting Back on Track: Delivering the Workplace Relations Framework Australia Needs (Submission to Productivity Commission Review of the workplace relations framework). Melbourne, VIC, Australia: Australian Mines and Metals Association.Google Scholar
Autor, D, Dorn, D, Katz, LF, et al. (2017) Concentrating on the fall of the labor share. American Economic Review 107(5): 180185.Google Scholar
Badham, V (2017) Turnbull’s latest bill expands the government’s industrial thuggery into every workplace. Guardian, 1 September. Available at: https://www.theguardian.com/commentisfree/2017/sep/01/turnbulls-latest-bill-expands-the-governments-industrial-thuggery-into-every-workplace (accessed 10 April 2021).Google Scholar
Barth, E, Bryson, A, Dale-Olsen, H (2020) Union density effects on productivity and wages. Economic Journal 130(631): 18981936.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Berg, J (2016) Income Security in the On-Demand Economy: Findings and Policy Lessons from a Survey of Crowdworkers. Geneva: Inclusive Labour Markets, Labour Relations and Working Conditions Branch, International Labour Office.Google Scholar
Bishop, J (2018) The effect of minimum wage increases on wages, hours worked and job loss. Research discussion paper RDP 2018-06. Sydney, NSW, Australia: Reserve Bank of Australia.Google Scholar
Black, SE, Lynch, LM (2001) How to compete: the impact of workplace practices and information technology on productivity. The Review of Economics and Statistics 83(3): 434445.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Blanchflower, DG, Bryson, A (2004) What effect do unions have on wages now and would freeman and medoff be surprised? Journal of Labor Research 25(3): 383414.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bonyhady, N, Duke, J (2020) Industrial relations fight threatens to break ceasefire between unions and government. Sydney Morning Herald, 23 July. Available at: https://www.smh.com.au/politics/federal/industrial-relations-fight-threatens-to-break-ceasefire-between-unions-and-government-20200723-p55es5.html (accessed 11 April 2021).Google Scholar
Booth, AL, Katic, P (2010) Estimating the wage elasticity of labour supply to a firm: what evidence is there for monopsony? IZA discussion paper no. 5167, September. Bonn: Forschungsinstitut zur Zukunft der Arbeit (Institute for the Study of Labor).Google Scholar
Brinsden, C (2020) Frydenberg inspired by Reagan, Thatcher. Canberra Times, 26 July. Available at: https://www.canberratimes.com.au/story/6849903/frydenberg-inspired-by-reagan-thatcher/ (accessed 11 April 2021).Google Scholar
Brosnan, P (1996) Labour markets and social deprivation. Labour and Industry 7(2): 334.Google Scholar
Broughton, A, Gloster, R, Marvell, R, et al. (2018) The Experiences of Individuals in the Gig Economy. London: Department for Business, Energy and Industrial Strategy, February.Google Scholar
Campbell, I, Chalmers, J (2008) Job quality and part-time work in the retail industry: an Australian case study. International Journal of Human Resource Management 19(3): 487500.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Card, D, Krueger, A (1995) Myth and Measurement: The New Economics of the Minimum Wage. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Charlesworth, S, Howe, J (2018) The enforcement of employment standards in Australia: successes and challenges in aged care. International Journal of Comparative Labour Law and Industrial Relations 34(2): 111140.Google Scholar
Chartered Institute of Personnel and Development (CIPD) (2017) To Gig or Not to Gig? Stories from the Modern Economy, March. London: CIPD.Google Scholar
Christmass, P (2020) Coronavirus Update: Uber Driver Dies after Woman ‘Coughed Repeatedly’ in His Car. Available at: https://7news.com.au/lifestyle/health-wellbeing/coronavirus-update-uber-driver-dies-after-woman-coughed-repeatedly-in-his-car-c-969817 Google Scholar
Coatsworth, N (2020) Deputy Chief Medical Officer Press Conference about COVID-19 on 4 August 2020. Canberra, ACT, Australia: Department of Health. Available at: https://www.health.gov.au/news/deputy-chief-medical-officer-press-conference-about-covid-19-on-19-august-2020 (accessed 11 April 2021).Google Scholar
Connolly, A, Carter, JS, Robb, K (2020) Melbourne aged care nurse who caught coronavirus says workers weren’t properly trained in PPE. ABC News, 14 August. Available at: https://www.abc.net.au/news/2020-08-14/covid-melbourne-aged-care-nurse-blames-lack-of-ppe-training/12540422 (accessed 11 April 2021).Google Scholar
Coorey, P, Marin-Guzman, D (2021) Gutted IR Bill Passes the Senate. Australian Financial Review, 18 March. Available at: https://www.afr.com/politics/federal/morrison-s-workplace-bill-faces-collapse-20210318-p57brl (accessed 11 April 2021).Google Scholar
Corr, R (2017) Criminal bosses belong in criminal courts. Overland, 29 November. Available at: https://overland.org.au/2017/11/criminal-bosses-belong-in-criminal-courts/ (accessed 10 April 2021).Google Scholar
Council of Economic Advisers (2016) Labor market monopsony: trends, consequences, and policy responses. Economic Brief, October. Washington, DC: Council of Economic Advisers.Google Scholar
Crisp, LF (1965) Australian National Government. Melbourne, VIC, Australia: Longman.Google Scholar
Deutscher, N (2019) Job-to-job transitions and the wages of Australian workers. Treasury working paper 2019-07, November. Available at: https://treasury.gov.au/publication/p2019-37418b (accessed 11 April 2021).Google Scholar
Economic Sciences Prize Committee (2010) Markets with Search Frictions. Scientifc Background on the Sveriges Riksbank Prize in Economic Sciences in Memory of Alfred Nobel 2010, 11 October. Stockholm: Royal Swedish Academy of Sciences.Google Scholar
Festinger, L (1957) A Theory of Cognitive Dissonance. Stanford, CA: Stanford University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Freeman, RB (2005) What do unions do? The 2004 M-Brane Stringtwister Edition. Journal of Labor Research 26(4): 642668.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Freeman, RB, Medoff, JL (1984) What Do Unions Do? New York: Basic Books.Google Scholar
Fry, TRL, Jarvis, K, Loundes, J (2002) Are IR reformers better performers? Melbourne Institute Working Paper No 18/02, September. Melbourne, VIC, Australia: Melbourne Institute of Applied Economic and Social Research.Google Scholar
Frydenberg, J (2020) The economic impact of the crisis. Ministerial statement on the economy, Parliament House, 12 May. Canberra, ACT, Australia: House of Representatives. Available at: https://joshfrydenberg.com.au/latest-news/ministerial-statement-on-the-economy-parliament-house-canberra-12-may-2020/ (accessed 11 April 2021).Google Scholar
Ghilarducci, T (1986) When management strikes: PATCO and the British miners. Industrial Relations Journal 17(2): 115128.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Grattan, M (2020) Can Scott Morrison keep this up as he descends the COVID-19 mountain? Canberra Times, 16 May. Available at: https://www.canberratimes.com.au/story/6758654/can-scott-morrison-keep-this-up-as-he-descends-the-covid-19-mountain/ (accessed 11 April 2021).Google Scholar
Holden, R (2020) Vital Signs: Victoria’s privatised quarantine arrangements were destined to fail. The Conversation, 24 July. Available at: https://theconversation.com/vital-signs-victorias-privatised-quarantine-arrangements-were-destined-to-fail-143169 (accessed 11 April 2021).Google Scholar
Jarosch, G, Nimczik, JS, Sorkin, I (2019) Granular search, market structure, and wages. IZA discussion paper no 12572. Bonn: IZA Institute of Labor Economics.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kaine, S (2020) Australian industrial relations and Covid-19. Journal of Australian Political Economy 85: 130137.Google Scholar
Kaufman, B (2005) What do unions do? Evaluation and commentary. Journal of Labor Research 26(4): 555596.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kohler, A (2021) Welcome to Australia’s economic fight club. New Daily, 4 February. Available at: https://thenewdaily.com.au/finance/finance-news/2021/02/04/alan-kohler-fight-club/ (accessed 11 April 2021).Google Scholar
Krueger, AB (2018) Reflections on dwindling worker bargaining power and monetary policy. Luncheon Address at the Jackson Hole economic symposium, 24 August. Kansas City, MO: Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City.Google Scholar
Krueger, AB, Posner, EA (2018) A proposal for protecting low‑income workers from monopsony and collusion. The Hamilton project policy proposal 2018-05. Washington, DC: Brookings Institution.Google Scholar
Krugman, P (1994) The Age of Diminished Expectations: US Economic Policy in the 1990S. Washington, DC: Washington Post Company.Google Scholar
Kruszelnicki, K (2012) Do you need eight glasses of water a day? ABC Science, 20 November. Available at: https://www.abc.net.au/science/articles/2012/11/20/3633741.htm (accessed 11 April 2021).Google Scholar
Laß, I, Wooden, M (2019) The Structure of the wage gap for temporary workers: evidence from Australian panel data. British Journal of Industrial Relations 57(3): 453478.Google Scholar
Lambert, J, Willox, I, Westacott, J, et al. (2021) Achievement of Casual Employment Certainty Is Welcome but Rest of IR omnibus bill must not be abandoned. 18 March. Canberra, ACT, Australia: Australian Chamber of Commerce and Industry, Australian Industry Group, Business Council of Australia, Australian Mines and Metals Association and Master Builders Australia.Google Scholar
Lambert, W (2020) quoted in ‘The true extent of Australia’s hospitality staff shortage’. 3AW Mornings, 10 December. Available at: https://www.3aw.com.au/the-true-extent-of-australias-hospitality-staff-shortage/ (accessed 11 April 2021).Google Scholar
Long, S (2017) Have Australia’s right to strike laws gone too far? ABC News, 21 March. Available at: https://www.abc.net.au/news/2017-03-21/have-the-right-to-strike-laws-gone-too-far/8370980 (accessed 11 April 2021).Google Scholar
McCrystal, S (2019) Why is it so hard to take lawful strike action in Australia? Journal of Industrial Relations 61(1): 129144.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Maley, J (2020) Turns out politicians can drop the ideology and fix things. Never let ‘em forget it. Sydney Morning Herald, 5 April. Available at: https://www.smh.com.au/politics/federal/turns-out-politicians-can-drop-the-ideology-and-fix-things-never-let-em-forget-it-20200403-p54gu7.html (accessed 11 April 2021).Google Scholar
Manning, A (2003) Monopsony in Motion: Imperfect Competition in Labour Markets. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Marinescu, I, Ouss, I, Pape, L-D (2020) Wages, hires and labour market concentration. IZA Discussion Paper 13244. Available at: http://ftp.iza.org/dp13244.pdf (accessed 11 April 2021).Google Scholar
Marin-Guzman, D (2020a) Unions slam pursuit of anti-union law in pandemic recovery. Australian Financial Review, 22 April. Available at: https://www.afr.com/work-and-careers/workplace/unions-slam-pursuit-of-anti-union-law-in-pandemic-recovery-20200422-p54m2s (accessed 11 April 2021).Google Scholar
Marin-Guzman, D (2020b) ‘Waste of time’: Bunnings boss slams EBA system. Australian Financial Review, 19 March. Available at: https://www.afr.com/work-and-careers/workplace/waste-of-time-bunnings-boss-slams-eba-system-20200319-p54bos (accessed 11 April 2021).Google Scholar
Markey, R (2020) The impact of the Covid-19 virus on industrial relations. Journal of Australian Political Economy 85: 147154.Google Scholar
Marx, K (1887) Capital, vol. 1. London: The Electric Book Company.Google Scholar
Mas, A (2008) Labour unrest and the quality of production: Evidence from the construction equipment resale market. The Review of Economic Studies 75(1): 229258.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mattson, J, Murphy, R (2020) Ch-ch-changes: Modern Awards amended in light of COVID-19. Available at: https://www.bartier.com.au/insights/articles/ch-ch-changes-modern-awards-amended-in-light-of-covid-19/ Google Scholar
May, M (2016) An Unusual Shade of Green: Greenfield Cases and Greenfield Agreements in Australia 2006 -2012. Brisbane, QLD, Australia: Griffith Business School, Griffith University.Google Scholar
Metcalf, D (2008) Why has the British National Minimum Wage had little or no impact on employment? Journal of Industrial Relations 50(3): 489512.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Milanovic, B (2016) Why might the rich be indifferent to income growth of their own countries? Economics Letters 147: 108111.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Minello, A (2020) The pandemic and the female academic. Nature. Available at: https://www.nature.com/articles/d41586-020-01135-9 (accessed 11 April 2021).Google Scholar
Morehead, A, Steele, M, Alexander, MJ, et al. (1997) Changes at Work: The 1995 Australian Workplace Industrial Relations Survey. Melbourne, VIC, Australia: Longman.Google Scholar
Murray, G, Peetz, D (2010) Women of the Coal Rushes. Sydney, NSW, Australia: University of NSW Press.Google Scholar
Nous Group (2020) Independent Review of the Temporary Jobkeeper Provisions of the Fair Work Act. Canberra, ACT, Australia: Attorney General’s Department. Available at: https://www.ag.gov.au/industrial-relations/publications/independent-review-temporary-jobkeeper-provisions-fair-work-act (accessed 11 April 2021).Google Scholar
O’Callaghan, M (2017) Greenfields Agreements Review. Canberra, ACT, Australia: Department of Employment.Google Scholar
Peetz, D (1998) The safety net and the role of the Australian Industrial Relations Commission. Journal of Industrial Relations 40(4): 533553.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Peetz, D (2012) Does industrial relations policy affect productivity? Australian Bulletin of Labour 38(4): 268292.Google Scholar
Peetz, D (2020) What do the Data on Casuals Really Mean? Brisbane, QLD, Australia: Centre for Work, Organisation and Wellbeing, 27 November. Available at: https://www.griffith.edu.au/__data/assets/pdf_file/0024/1212675/What-do-the-data-on-casuals-really-mean-v5.pdf (accessed 11 April 2021).Google Scholar
Peetz, D, Bruynius, S, Murray, G (2019) Choice and the impact of changes to weekend premiums in the Australian retail and hospitality industries. Journal of Industrial Relations 61(5): 657681.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Pennington, A, Stanford, J (2020) Rebuilding after COVID-19 will need a sustained national reconstruction plan. Journal of Australian Political Economy 85: 164174.Google Scholar
Pichler, S, Wen, K, Ziebarth, NR (2020) COVID-19 Emergency sick leave has helped flatten the curve in The United States. Health Affairs 39(12). Available at: https://www.healthaffairs.org/doi/full/10.1377/hlthaff.2020.00863 (accessed 11 April 2021).CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Pickering, C (2020) What really happened after penalty rates were cut. Inside Retail, 26 February. Available at: https://insideretail.com.au/news/what-really-happened-after-penalty-rates-were-cut-202002 (accessed 11 April 2021).Google Scholar
Productivity Commission (2015) Workplace Relations Framework: Productivity Commission Inquiry Report, vol. 1. Canberra, ACT, Australia: Productivity Commission.Google Scholar
Robinson, L, Felton-Taylor, A (2021) Would-be fruit picker calls for more flexible hiring practices as growers seek answers to worker shortage. ABC News, 6 February. Available at: https://www.abc.net.au/news/2021-02-06/fruit-pickers-call-for-more-flexibility-with-industry-shortage/13098362 (accessed 11 April 2021).Google Scholar
Smith, A (1776) An Inquiry into the Nature and Causes of the Wealth of Nations. London: Nelson.Google Scholar
Smith, JE (2020) A COVID-19 death renews questions of responsibility of Uber and Lyft to drivers. Los Angeles Times, 25 July. Available at: https://news.yahoo.com/covid-19-death-renews-questions-154222766.html (accessed 11 April 2021).Google Scholar
Stewart, MB (1991) union wage differentials in the face of changes in the economic and legal environment. Economica 58(230): 155172.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Stiglitz, JE (1976) The efficiency wage hypothesis, surplus labor, and the distribution of income in LDCs. Oxford Economic Papers 28(2): 185207.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sullivan, K (2020) Coronavirus restrictions could lead to 26,000-person shortfall for coming harvests, report says. ABC News, 30 September. Available at: https://www.abc.net.au/news/2020-09-30/coronavirus-farm-worker-shortage-coming-harvests/12714694 (accessed 11 April 2021).Google Scholar
Tabet, T (2020) Wagners’ $230m entertainment precinct races ahead. Urban Developer, 2 October. Available at: https://theurbandeveloper.com/articles/wagner-holdings-toowoomba-entertainment-precinct(accessed 10 April 2021).Google Scholar
Taft, P (1998) Does who wins matter more or less? Public Policy Program, discussion paper no. 57, July. Canberra, ACT, Australia: Australian National University.Google Scholar
Treasury (2020) The Jobkeeper Payment: Three-Month Review. Canberra, ACT, Australia: Australian Government.Google Scholar
Tseng, Y-P, Wooden, M (2001) Enterprise bargaining and productivity: evidence from the business longitudinal survey. Melbourne Institute working paper no 8/01. Melbourne, VIC, Australia: Melbourne Institute of Applied Economic and Social Research, University of Melbourne.Google Scholar
Wilcox, I (2020) Casual employment decision increases JobKeeper risks. Australian Industry Group, Sydney, 21 May. Available at: https://www.aigroup.com.au/policy-and-research/mediacentre/releases/casual-employment-jobkeeper-21May/ (accessed 11 April 2021).Google Scholar
Winkler, MA (2019) States with high minimum wages are doing just fine. Bloomberg, 26 July. Available at: https://www.bloombergquint.com/gadfly/minimum-wage-hikes-don-t-stifle-state-economic-booms (accessed 11 April 2021).Google Scholar
Wolfers, J, Zilinsky, J (2015) Higher wages for low–income workers lead to higher productivity. Available at: https://www.piie.com/blogs/realtime-economic-issues-watch/higher-wages-low-income-workers-lead-higher-productivity (accessed 11 April 2021).Google Scholar
Wooden, M (2000) Union wage effects in the presence of enterprise bargaining. Melbourne Institute working paper no 7/00, April. Melbourne, VIC, Australia: Melbourne Institute of Applied Economic and Social Research, University of Melbourne.Google Scholar
Workplace Express (2020a) Evidence employers baffled by awards: A-G’s department. Workplace Express, 23 October. Available at https://www.workplaceexpress.com.au/nl06_news_selected.php?act=2&stream=1&selkey=59475&hlc=2&hlw=Evidence%20employers%20baffled%20by%20awards:%20A-G%E2%80%99s%20department Google Scholar
Workplace Express (2020b) FWC boosts WFH campaign as award flexibilities extended. Workplace Express, 7 October. Available at: https://www.workplaceexpress.com.au/nl06_news_selected.php?selkey=59420 Google Scholar
Workplace Express (2020c) FWC set to extend paid pandemic leave until late March. Workplace Express, 20 October. Available at: https://www.workplaceexpress.com.au/nl06_news_selected.php?act=2&stream=7-4&selkey=59461&hlc=2&hlw= Google Scholar
Workplace Express (2020d) McManus joins jostling over IR changes. Workplace Express, 13 October. Available at: https://www.workplaceexpress.com.au/topics.php?stream=2-1-106 Google Scholar
Workplace Express (2020e) Porter pledges single IR Bill; Qantas win on stand downs; and more. Workplace Express, 6 October. Available at: https://www.workplaceexpress.com.au/nl06_news_selected.php?selkey=59416 Google Scholar
Workplace Express (2020f) Working group employers leery of ACTU-BCA pact. Workplace Express, 17 September. Available at: https://workplaceexpress.com.au/nl06_news_selected.php?act=2&stream=2&selkey=59358&hlc=2&hlw= Google Scholar
Yu, S, Peetz, D (2018) Non-standard timewage premiums and employment effects: evidence from an Australian natural experiment. British Journal of Industrial Relations 57(1): 3361.CrossRefGoogle Scholar