Hostname: page-component-cd9895bd7-fscjk Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-12-23T08:01:33.120Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Why Are Some Institutions Replaced while Others Persist? Evidence from State Constitutions

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  25 January 2021

Adam Cayton*
Affiliation:
University of Colorado–Boulder, Boulder, CO, USA
*
Adam Cayton, University of Colorado–Boulder, UCB 333, Boulder, CO 80309, USA. Email: [email protected]

Abstract

Why are some institutions quickly replaced while others endure for more than a century? Majority cycling over institutions is theoretically unavoidable, but politics provides few opportunities to study it empirically. Using data on state constitutional characteristics and legislative composition from 1834 to 2012, this article advances the theory that institutions are more likely to be endogenously replaced when the society of actors differs from the time of enactment, and that institutional characteristics can exacerbate or mitigate these risks. Results show that political change interacts with institutional particularism to preserve or undermine state constitutions. More particularistic constitutions have shorter life spans because they are more vulnerable to changes in the political environment.

Type
Research Article
Copyright
Copyright © The Author(s) 2015

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

Aldrich, John H. 1995. Why Parties? Chicago: University of Chicago Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Arrow, Kenneth J. 1951. Social Choice and Individual Values. New Haven: Yale University Press.Google Scholar
Beck, Nathaniel, Katz, Jonathan N., and Tucker, Richard. 1998. “Taking Time Seriously: Time-Series Cross-Section Analysis with a Binary Dependent Variable.” American Journal of Political Science 42 (4): 1260–88..CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Berkowitz, Daniel, and Clay, Karen. 2005. “American Civil Law Origins: Implications for State Constitutions.” American Law and Economics Review 7 (1): 6282..CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bernholz, Peter. 1973. “Logrolling, Arrow Paradox and Cyclical Majorities.” Public Choice 15 (1): 8795..CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Berry, Christopher R., Burden, Barry C., and Howell, William G.. 2010. “After Enactment: The Lives and Deaths of Federal Programs.” American Journal of Political Science 54 (1): 117..CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Black, Duncan. 1948. “On the Rationale of Group Decision Making.” Journal of Political Economy 56:2334.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Black, Duncan. 1958. The Theory of Committees and Elections. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Box-Steffensmeier, Janet M., and Jones, Bradford S.. 2004. Event History Modeling: A Guide for Social Scientists. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Buchanan, James M., and Bush, Winston C.. 1974. “Political Constraints on Contractual Redistribution.” The American Economic Review 64 (2): 153–57..Google Scholar
Buchanan, James M., and Tullock, Gordon. 1962. The Calculus of Consent. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press.Google Scholar
Burden, Barry C. 2007. Personal Roots of Representation. Princeton: Princeton University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Burnham, W. Dean. 1985. Partisan Division of American State Governments, 1834-985. Conducted by Massachusetts Institute of Technology. ICPSR ed. Ann Arbor, MI: Inter-university Consortium for Political and Social Research [producer and distributor], 198? doi:10.3886/ICPSR00016.v1.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Campbell, Angus, Converse, Phillip E., Miller, Warren E., and Stokes, Donald M.. 1960. The American Voter. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
Cohen, Marty, Karol, David, Noel, Hans, and Zaller, John. 2008. The Party Decides: Presidential Nominations before and after Reform. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Converse, Philip E. 1964. “The Nature of Belief Systems in Mass Publics,” in Ideology and Discontent, David Apter, ed. New York: Free Press.Google Scholar
Cox, David R. 1972. “Regression Models and Life Tables.” Journal of the Royal Statistical Society: Series B 34:187220.Google Scholar
Cox, Gary M., and McCubbins, Matthew D.. 1993. Legislative Leviathan: Party Government in the House. Berkeley: University of California Press.Google Scholar
Cox, Gary M., and McCubbins, Matthew D.. 2005. Setting the Agenda: Responsible Party Government in the U.S. House of Representatives. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Delli Carpini, Michael X., and Keeter, Scott. 1996. What Americans Know about Politics and Why It Matters. New Haven: Yale University Press.Google Scholar
Denzau, Arthur T. 1985. “Constitutional Change and Agenda Control.” Public Choice 47 (1): 183217..CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Denzau, Arthur T., and MacKay, Robert J.. 1981. “Structure-Induced Equilibria and Perfect-Foresight Expectations.” American Journal of Political Science, 25(4): 762–79.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Elazar, Daniel J. 1982. “The Principles and Traditions Underlying American State Constitutions.” Publius 12:1125.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Elkins, Zachary, Ginsburg, Tom, and Melton, James. 2009. The Endurance of National Constitutions. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fenno, Richard F. [1978] 2003. Home Style: House Members in Their Districts. New York: Longman.Google Scholar
Grambsch, Patricia M., and Therneau, Terry M.. 1994. “Proportional Hazards Tests and Diagnostics Based on Weighted Residuals.” Biometrika 81 (3): 515–26..CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Grant, Shannon, Chen, Ying Qing, and May, Susanne. 2014. “Performance of Goodness-of-Fit Tests for the Cox Proportional Hazards Model with Time-Varying Covariates.” Lifetime Data Analysis 20 (3): 355–68..CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Hammons, Christopher. 1999. “Was James Madison Wrong? Rethinking the American Preference for Short, Framework-Oriented Constitutions.” American Political Science Review 93 (4): 837–49..CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Jenkins, Jeffrey A., and Patashnik, Eric M., eds. 2012. Living Legislation: Durability, Change, and the Politics of American Lawmaking. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Keller, Morton. 1981. “The Politics of State Constitutional Revision, 1820–1930.” In The Constitutional Convention as an Amending Device, eds. Hall, Kermit L., Hyman, Harold M., and Sigal, Leon V.. Washington, DC: American Historical Association and American Political Science Association, pp. 6772.Google Scholar
Klarner, Carl E. 2003. “Measurement of the Partisan Balance of State Government.” State Politics & Policy Quarterly 3 (Fall): 309–19.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Krehbiel, Keith. 1991. Information and Legislative Organization. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Layman, Geoffrey C., and Carsey, Thomas M.. 2002. “Party Polarization and Conflict Extension in the American Electorate.” American Journal of Political Science 46 (4): 786802..CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lenz, Gabriel. 2012. Follow the Leader? How Voters Respond to Politicians' Policies and Performance. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lewis, David. 2005. Presidents and the Politics of Agency Design: Political Insulation in the United States Government Bureaucracy, 1946-1997. Stanford: Stanford University Press.Google Scholar
Lijphart, Arend. 1999. Patterns of Democracy: Government Forms and Performance in Thirty-Six Countries. New Haven: Yale University Press.Google Scholar
Lorenz, Astrid. 2005. “How to Measure Constitutional Rigidity: Four Concepts and Two Alternatives.” Journal of Theoretical Politics 17 (3): 339–61..CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lutz, Donald. 1994. “Toward a Theory of Constitutional Amendment.” American Political Science Review 88 (2): 355–70..CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Maltzman, Forrest, and Shipan, Charles R.. 2008. “Change, Continuity, and the Evolution of the Law.” American Journal of Political Science 52 (2): 252–67..CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Masket, Seth E. 2009. No Middle Ground: How Informal Party Organizations Control Nominations and Polarize Legislatures. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mayhew, David R. 1974. Congress: The Electoral Connection. New Haven: Yale University Press.Google Scholar
McKelvey, Richard D. 1976. “Intransitivities in Multidimensional Voting Models and Some Implications for Agenda Control.” Journal of Economic Theory 12:472–82.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Moe, Terry. 1989. “The Politics of Bureaucratic Structure.” In Can the Government Govern, eds. Chubb, John E. and Peterson, Paul E.. Washington, DC: The Brookings Institution, pp. 267–85.Google Scholar
Patashnik, Eric M. 2003. “After the Public Interest Prevails: The Political Sustainability of Policy Reform.” Governance 16 (April): 203–34.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Patashnik, Eric M. 2008. Reforms at Risk: What Happens after Major Policy Changes Are Enacted. Princeton: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Pierson, Paul. 2000. “Increasing Returns, Path Dependence, and the Study of Politics.” American Political Science Review, 94(2):251–67.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Popkin, Samuel L. 1991. The Reasoning Voter: Communication and Persuasion in Presidential Campaigns. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Posner, Daniel N. 2004. “Measuring Ethnic Fractionalization in Africa.” American Journal of Political Science 48 (4): 849–63..CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ragusa, Jordan Michael. 2010. “The Lifecycle of Public Policy: An Event History Analysis of Repeals to Landmark Legislative Enactments, 1951-2006.” American Politics Research 38 (6): 1015–51..CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Riker, William H. 1980. “Implications from the Disequilibrium of Majority Rule Voting Systems.” American Political Science Review 74 (2): 432–46..CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Romer, Thomas, and Rosenthal, Howard. 1978. “Political Resource Allocation, Controlled Agendas, and the Status Quo.” Public choice 33 (4): 2743..CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Shepsle, Kenneth A. 1979. “Institutional Arrangements and Equilibrium in Multidimensional Voting Models.” American Journal of Political Science 23 (1): 2759..CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Shepsle, Kenneth A. 1986. “Institutional Equilibrium and Equilibrium Institutions.” In Political Science: The Science of Politics, ed. Weisburg, Herbert. New York: Agathon Press, pp. 5181.Google Scholar
Shepsle, Kenneth A., and Weingast, Barry R.. 1981. “Structure Induced Equilibrium and Legislative Choice.” Public Choice 37:503–19.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Tarr, G. Alan. 1998. Understanding State Constitutions. Princeton: Princeton University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Tullock, Gordon. 1981. “Why So Much Stability.” Public Choice 37 (2): 189204..CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wall, Audrey. 2013. “State Constitutions.” In Council of State Governments Knowledge Center. 2013. The Book of the States. Washington, DC: The Council of State Governments. http://knowledgecenter.csg.org/kc/content/book-states-2013-chapter-1-state-constitutions.Google Scholar
Weingast, Barry R., and Marshall, William J.. 1988. “The Industrial Organization of Congress; or, Why Legislatures, Like Firms, Are Not Organized as Markets.” Journal of Political Economy 96 (11): 132–63..CrossRefGoogle Scholar