Hostname: page-component-586b7cd67f-t7czq Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-12-01T01:53:29.251Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Origins of the American Corporate Network

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  04 January 2016

David Bunting*
Affiliation:
Eastern Washington University

Extract

Numerous studies have shown that since about 1900 the largest industrial, financial, and transportation companies have interlocked extensively through a sharing of directors and, much less often, officers (e.g., Bunting and Barbour, 1971; Bunting, 1976a, 1976b; Dooley, 1969). In fact, this interlocking has been so extensive that a virtual network exists whereby nearly any large corporation in principle is able to participate either directly or indirectly, once or twice removed, in the top-level policy deliberations of any other large concern (Mizruchi, 1982; Pennings, 1980).

Little is known about the origins of this network. Most research implicitly assumes that the network has resulted from some relatively recent decline in competition and subsequent movement toward economic concentration. This conclusion follows from the commonly accepted proposition that competition precedes monopoly in industrial development. Scherer (1979:47), an authority on modern American industrial organization, cites Marx for the essence of this notion: “‘One capitalist always kills many’ (creating) a ‘constantly diminishing number of the magnates of capital, who usurp and monopolize all the advantages of this process.’” In less colorful but more factual terms, Burns (1936:1-42) and many others have described the “decline of competition” and the factors leading to the domination of many industries by relatively few large corporations (literature reviewed in Scherer, 1979:67-70; Blumberg, 1975:16-83).

Type
Research Article
Copyright
Copyright © Social Science History Association 1983 

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

Berle, A. A. Jr. and Means, G. C. (1932) The Modern Corporation and Private Property. New York: Macmillan.Google Scholar
Blumberg, P. I. (1975) The Megacorporation in American Society: The Scope of Corporate Power. Englewood Cliffs, NJ: Prentice-Hall.Google Scholar
Bunting, D. (1976a) “Corporate interlocking, Part I—the money trust.” Directors & Boards 1, 1: 615.Google Scholar
Bunting, D. (1976b) “Corporate interlocking, Part II—the modern money trust.” Directors & Boards 1, 1: 2737.Google Scholar
Bunting, D. (1979) “Efficiency, equity, and the evolution of Big Business.” Paper presented at the annual meeting of the Western Economics Association, Las Vegas, Nevada.Google Scholar
Bunting, D. and Barbour, J. (1971) “Interlocking directorates in large American corporations, 1896-1964.” Business History Review 45: 317335.Google Scholar
Burns, A. R. (1936) The Decline of Competition. New York: McGraw-Hill.Google Scholar
Carosso, V. P. (1970) Investment Banking in America. Cambridge: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Callender, G. S. (1902) “The early transportation and banking enterprises of the states in relation to the growth of corporations.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 17: 111162.Google Scholar
Davis, J. S. (1917) Essays in the Earlier History of American Corporations, Book Two. Cambridge: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Dixon, F. H. (1914) “The economic significance of interlocking directorates in railway finance.” Journal of Political Economy 22: 937954.Google Scholar
Dooley, P. C. (1969) “The interlocking directorate.” American Economic Review 69: 314323.Google Scholar
Hofstadter, R. (1965) The Paranoid Style in American Politics and Other Essays. New York: A. A. Knopf.Google Scholar
Meyer, B. H. (1904) “Trusts—discussion.” Publications of the American Economic Association, 3rd series, 5: 108113.Google Scholar
Mizruchi, M. S. (1982) The American Corporate Network: 1904-1974. Beverly Hills, CA: Sage.Google Scholar
Noyes, A. D. (1909) Forty Years of American Finance. New York: Putnam.Google Scholar
Pennings, J. M. (1980) Interlocking directorates. San Francisco: Jossey-Bass.Google Scholar
Scherer, F. M. (1979) Industrial Market Structure and Economic Performance. Chicago: Rand McNally.Google Scholar
State of New York in Assembly (1843) No. 34. Annual Report of the Bank Commissioners, January 30, 1843. Albany, New York.Google Scholar
State of New York in Assembly (1832) No. 70. Annual Report of the Bank Commissioners, January 31, 1832. Albany, New York.Google Scholar
Thorelli, H. B. (1955) The Federal Antitrust Policy. Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University Press.Google Scholar