Hostname: page-component-6d856f89d9-4thr5 Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-07-16T03:36:07.871Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Lotta Lemmata

A Sour Harvest

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  04 January 2016

Abstract

We quantify the increasing use of complex mathematics and show that the increase is unique to economics in the social sciences. Donald F. Gordon hypothesized that mathematics in economics would most likely be useful in manipulating long chains of relationships, precisely in the instances where the theory was least likely to be valid. Time bedevils long chains of economic reasoning, because the ceteris paribus assumption requires the stability of all links. We find that the rate of hypothesis testing in articles citing mathematically complex articles is less than 2 percent and summarize a variety of tests and other evidence that supports Gordon’s hypothesis. A major factor in the rise in mathematical complexity may be the decline in comments, replies, and rejoinders debating earlier publications; the decline has been rapid, as editors have become increasingly “hostile” toward perspectives other than the ones they have previously published. We conclude by emphasizing that (1) prominent journals in economics are devoting more space to mathematically complex articles despite their inconsequential operational harvest; (2) the “appropriate” balance between mathematical complexity and operationalism, as well as the relative merits of “stylized facts” versus observational reality, should be considered in editorial decision making; and, finally, (3) the academic debate that addresses empirical replication and verification, the appropriateness of model formulation, and the crucial matters of history and circumstance, which are the measures of all research in the social sciences, is vital.

Type
Special Section: The Past, Present, and Future of Economics for History
Copyright
Copyright © Social Science History Association 2011 

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

Alchian, A. (1950) “Uncertainty, evolution, and economic theory.” Journal of Political Economy 58: 211–21.Google Scholar
Ashenfelter, Orley (1989) “Report of the editor.” American Economic Review 79: 405–13.Google Scholar
Azariadis, C. (1983) “Employment with asymmetric information.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 98 (supp.): 157–72.Google Scholar
Becker, G. (1991) “A note on restaurant pricing and other examples of social influence on price.” Journal of Political Economy 99: 1109–16.Google Scholar
Buchholz, Todd G. (1990) New Ideas from Dead Economists. New York: Penguin.Google Scholar
Chambers, E.Gordon, Donald F. (1966) “Primary products and economic growth: An empirical measure.” Journal of Political Economy 74: 315–32.Google Scholar
Cheung, Steven N. S. (1973) “The fable of the bees: An economic investigation.” Journal of Law and Economics 16: 1133.Google Scholar
Cho, I. and Kreps, D. (1987) “Signaling games and stable equilibria.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 102: 179222.Google Scholar
Coase, Ronald (1974) “The lighthouse in economics.” Journal of Law and Economics 17: 357–76.Google Scholar
Coelho, Philip R. P.Klein, D.McClure, James E. (2004) “Fashion cycles in economics.” Econ Journal Watch 1: 437–54.Google Scholar
Coelho, Philip R. P.Klein, D.McClure, James E. (2005) “Rejoinder to Pesendorfer.” Econ Journal Watch 2: 3241.Google Scholar
Coelho, Philip R. P.McClure, James E. (2005) “Theory versus application: Does complexity crowd out evidence?Southern Economic Journal 71: 556–65.Google Scholar
Coelho, Philip R. P.McClure, James E. (2008) “The market for lemmas: Evidence that complex models rarely operate in our world.” Econ Journal Watch 5: 7890.Google Scholar
Coelho, Philip R. P.McClure, James E.Worken-Eley, D. (2005) “Decline in critical commentary in economics: 1963–2004.” Econ Journal Watch 2: 355–61.Google Scholar
Cole, H.Mailath, G.Postlewaite, A. (1992) “Social norms, saving behavior, and growth.” Journal of Political Economy 100: 10921125.Google Scholar
Cole, H.Mailath, G.Postlewaite, A. (1995) “Response to ‘Aristocratic equilibria.’Journal of Political Economy 103: 439–43.Google Scholar
David, Paul (1985) “Clio and the economics of QWERTY.” American Economic Review 75: 332–37.Google Scholar
Dollery, B.Byrnes, J.Akimova, G. (2008) “The curtailment of critical commentary in Australian economics.” Econ Journal Watch 5: 349–51.Google Scholar
Ehrlich, I.Lui, F. (1991) “Intergenerational trade, longevity, and economic growth.” Journal of Political Economy 99: 1029–59.Google Scholar
Frazer, W. (1984) “Methodology: Reply.” American Economic Review 74: 793–94.Google Scholar
Girard, A. (2001) “Simultaneous ascending auctions and the Federal Communications Commission Spectrum Auction 35.” Telecommunications Review: 8391.Google Scholar
Gisser, M.Okten, G.McClure, J.Santoni, G. (2009) “Some anomalies arising from bandwagons that impart upward sloping segments to market demand.” Econ Journal Watch 6: 2134.Google Scholar
Gordon, Donald F. (1955) “Professor Samuelson on operationalism in economic theory.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 69: 305–10.Google Scholar
Gordon, Donald F. (1968 [1955]) “Operational propositions in economic theory,” in Breit, W.Hochman, H. (eds.) Readings in Microeconomics. New York: Holt, Rinehart, and Winston: 4859.Google Scholar
Harris, M. and Weiss, Y. (1984) “Job matching with finite horizon and risk aversion.” Journal of Political Economy 92: 758–79.Google Scholar
Hellwig, M. (1981) “Bankruptcy, limited liability, and the Modigliani-Miller theorem.” American Economic Review 71: 155–70.Google Scholar
Herberg, H. and Kemp, M. (1980) “In defense of some ‘paradoxes’ of trade theory.” American Economic Review 70: 812–14.Google Scholar
Hirschleifer, J. (1977) “Economics from a biological viewpoint.” Journal of Law and Economics 20: 152.Google Scholar
Journal Storage (2000–2002) JSTOR, www.jstor.orgGoogle Scholar
Khan, M. and Vohra, R. (1987) “An extension of the second welfare theorem to economics with nonconvexities and public goods.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 102: 223–41.Google Scholar
Kim, E.Morse, A. and Zingales, L. (2006) “What has mattered to economics since 1970?National Bureau of Economic Research Working Paper 12526. Cambridge, MA: National Bureau of Economic Research.Google Scholar
Klein, D. and Romero, P. (2007) “Model building versus theorizing: The paucity of theory in the Journal of Economic Theory.” Econ Journal Watch 4: 241–71.Google Scholar
Kuhn, T. (1962) The Structure of Scientific Revolutions. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
Laband, D.Tollison, R. and Karahan, G. (2002) “Quality control in economics.” Kyklos 55: 315–34.Google Scholar
Laffont, J. and Tirole, J. (1986) “Using cost observations to regulate firms.” Journal of Political Economy 94: 614–41.Google Scholar
Landsburg, S. (1995) “Aristocratic equilibria.” Journal of Political Economy 103: 434–38.Google Scholar
Leamer, E. (1978) Specification Searches: Ad Hoc Inferences with Nonexperimental Data. New York: Wiley.Google Scholar
Liebowitz, S. J. and Margolis, Stephen E. (1990) “The fable of the keys.” Journal of Law and Economics 33: 125.Google Scholar
Malcomson, J. (1984) “Work incentives, hierarchy, and internal labor markets.” Journal of Political Economy 92: 486507.Google Scholar
Marshall, Alfred (1964 [1920]) Principles of Economics. 8th ed. London: Macmillan.Google Scholar
McAfee, R. Preston and McMillan, J. (1996) “Analyzing the airwaves auction.” Journal of Economic Perspectives 10: 159–75.Google Scholar
McCloskey, Deirdre (1983) “The rhetoric of economics.” Journal of Economic Literature 21: 481517.Google Scholar
McCullough, B. D. (2007) “Got replicability? The Journal off Money, Banking, and Credit archive.” Econ Journal Watch 4: 326–37.Google Scholar
Pesendorfer, W. (1995) “Design innovations and fashion cycles.” American Economic Review 85: 771–92.Google Scholar
Pesendorfer, W. (2004) “Response to ‘Fashion cycles in economics.’” Econ Journal Watch 1: 455–64.Google Scholar
Pesendorfer, W. (2005) “Second reply to Coelho, Klein, and McClure.” Econ Journal Watch 2: 4246.Google Scholar
Popper, K. (1959 [1934]) Logic of Scientific Discovery. New York: Science Editions.Google Scholar
Posner, R. (1993) “Nobel laureate: Ronald Coase and methodology.” Journal of Economic Perspectives 7: 195210.Google Scholar
Roemer, J. (1986) “Equality of resources implies equality of welfare.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 101: 751–84.Google Scholar
Ross, S. (1987) “Arbitrage and martingales with taxation.” Journal of Political Economy 95: 371–93.Google Scholar
Samuelson, Paul A. (1952) “Economic theory and mathematics: An appraisal.” American Economic Review 42: 5666.Google Scholar
Samuelson, Paul A. (1965) Foundations in Economic Analysis. New York: Atheneum.Google Scholar
Sutter, D. and Pjesky, R. (2007) “Where would Adam Smith publish today? The near absence of math-free research in top journals.” Econ Journal Watch 4: 230–40.Google Scholar
Whaples, Robert (2006) “The cost of critical commentary in economic journals.” Econ Journal Watch 3: 275–82.Google Scholar