Hostname: page-component-586b7cd67f-2brh9 Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-11-28T06:36:26.077Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

British Industry and the West Indies Plantations

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  04 January 2016

Extract

Is it not notorious to the whole World, that the Business of Planting in our British Colonies, as well as in the French, is carried on by the Labour of Negroes, imported thither from Africa? Are we not indebted to those valuable People, the Africans for our Sugars, Tobaccoes, Rice, Rum, and all other Plantation Produce? And the greater the Number of Negroes imported into our Colonies, from Africa, will not the Exportation of British Manufactures among the Africans be in Proportion, they being paid for in such Commodities only? The more likewise our Plantations abound in Negroes, will not more Land become cultivated, and both better and greater Variety of Plantation Commodities be produced? As those Trades are subservient to the Well Being and Prosperity of each other; so the more either flourishes or declines, the other must be necessarily affected; and the general Trade and Navigation of their Mother Country, will be proportionably benefited or injured. May we not therefore say, with equal Truth, as the French do in their before cited Memorial, that the general Navigation of Great Britain owes all its Encrease and Splendor to the Commerce of its American and African Colonies; and that it cannot be maintained and enlarged otherwise than from the constant Prosperity of both those branches, whose Interests are mutual and inseparable?

[Postlethwayt 1968c: 6]

The atlantic slave trade remains oddly invisible in the commentaries of historians who have specialized in the sources and causes of British industrialization in the late eighteenth century. This curiosity contrasts sharply with the perspective of eighteenth-century strategists who, on the eve of the industrial revolution, placed great stock in both the trade and the colonial plantations as vital instruments for British economic progress. Specifically, Joshua Gee and Malachy Postlethwayt, once described by the imperial historian Charles Ryle Fay (1934: 2–3) as Britain’s major “spokesmen” for the eighteenth century, both placed the importation of African slaves into the Americas at the core of their visions of the requirements for national expansion. Fay (ibid.: 3) also described both of them as “mercantilists hardening into a manufacturers’ imperialism.” For such a “manufacturers’ imperialism” to be a success, both Gee and Postlethwayt saw the need for extensive British participation in the trade in Africans and in the maintenance and development of the West Indies.

Type
Research Article
Copyright
Copyright © Social Science History Association 1990 

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

Anderson, B. L., and Richardson, David (1983) “Market structure and profits of the British African trade in the late eighteenth century: A comment.Journal of Economic History 4: 713-21.Google Scholar
Anstey, Roger (1975) “The volume and profitability of the British slave trade, 1761-1807,” in Engerman, S. and Genovese, E. D. (eds.) Race and Slavery in the Western Hemisphere: Quantitative Studies. Princeton: Princeton University Press: 336.Google Scholar
Ashton, T. S. (1964) The Industrial Revolution, 1760-1830. New York: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Bailey, Ronald W. (1986) “Africa, the slave trade, and the rise of industrial capitalism in Europe and the United States: A historiographie review.” American History: A Bibliographic Review 2: 191.Google Scholar
Birnie, A. (1935) An Economic History of the British Isles. London: Methuen.Google Scholar
Child, Josiah (n.d.) A New Discourse of Trade. 4th ed., London: J. Hodges on London-Bridge.Google Scholar
Crafts, N. F. R. (1987) “British economic growth, 1700-1850: Some difficulties of interpretation.” Explorations in Economic History 24: 245-68.Google Scholar
Darity, William Jr., (1982) “A general equilibrium model of the eighteenth-century Atlantic slave trade: A least-likely test for the Caribbean school.Research in Economic History 7: 287326.Google Scholar
Darity, William Jr., (1985) “The numbers game and the profitability of the British trade in slaves.Journal of Economic History 45: 693703.Google Scholar
Darity, William Jr., (1989) “The profitability of the British trade in slaves once again.Explorations in Economic History 26: 380-84.Google Scholar
Deane, Phyllis (1965) The First Industrial Revolution. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Engerman, Stanley L. (1972) “The slave trade and British capital formation in the eighteenth century: A comment on the Williams thesis.Business History Review 46: 430-43.Google Scholar
Fay, C. R. (1934) Imperial Economy and Its Place in the Formation of Economic Doctrine, 1600-1932. Oxford: Clarendon.Google Scholar
Findlay, Ronald L. (1975) “Implications of growth theory for trade and development.” American Economic Review 65: 323-28.Google Scholar
Findlay, Ronald L. (1982) “Trade and growth in the industrial revolution,” in Kindleberger, C. and Telia, G. (eds.) Economics in the Long View: Essays in Honour of W. W. Rostow, vol. 1. New York: New York University Press.Google Scholar
Findlay, Ronald L. (1989) “The ‘triangular trade’ and the Atlantic economy of the eigh teenth century: A simple general equilibrium model.” Graham Lecture, Columbia University.Google Scholar
Floud, R. C. and McCloskey, D. N. (eds.) (1981) The Economic History of Britain since 1700, vol. 1. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Gee, Joshua (1750) The Trade and Navigation of Great Britain Considered. 5th ed., Glasgow: Robert Urie.Google Scholar
Gee, Joshua (1972 [1720]) “A letter to a member of Parliament concerning the naval store-bill,” in British Imperialism: Three Documents. New York: Arno: 343.Google Scholar
Gemery, Henry A., and Hogendorn, Jan S. (1979) “Introduction,” in Gemery, H. A. and Hogendorn, J. S. (eds.) The Uncommon Market: Essays in the Economic History of the Atlantic Slave Trade. New York: Academic: 119.Google Scholar
Inikori, Joseph E. (1976) “Measuring the Atlantic slave trade: An assessment of Curtin and Anstey.” Journal of African History 17: 197223.Google Scholar
Inikori, Joseph E. (1981) “Market structure and the profits of the British African trade in the late eighteenth century.Journal of Economic History 41: 745-76.Google Scholar
Inikori, Joseph E. (1988) “The credit needs of the African trade and the development of the credit economy in England.” Unpublished manuscript.Google Scholar
Kregel, Jan (1977) “Ricardo, trade, and factor mobility.” Economia Internazionale 30: 313.Google Scholar
Lewis, W. A. (1954) “Economic development with unlimited supplies of labour.” Manchester School of Economic and Social Studies 22: 139-91.Google Scholar
Lewis, W. A. (1978) The Evolution of the International Economic Order. Princeton: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
List, Friedrich (1983) The Natural System of Political Economy, 1837. London: Frank Cass.Google Scholar
Marx, Karl (1977) Capital, vol. 1. New York: Vintage Books.Google Scholar
Marx, Karl (1981) Capital, vol. 3. New York: Vintage Books.Google Scholar
McCloskey, Donald (1985) “The industrial revolution, 1760-1860: A survey,” in Mokyr, Joel (ed.) The Economics of the Industrial Revolution. London: George Allen and Unwin: 5374.Google Scholar
Minchinton, W. E. (1979) “The triangular trade revisited,” in Gemery, H. A. and Hogendorn, J. S. (eds.) The Uncommon Market: Essays in the Economic History of the Atlantic Slave Trade. New York: Academic: 331-52.Google Scholar
Mokyr, Joel (1985) “The industrial revolution and the new economic history,” in Mokyr, Joel (ed.) The Economics of the Industrial Revolution. London: George Allen and Unwin: 151.Google Scholar
Mokyr, Joel (1987) “Has the industrial revolution been crowded out? Some reflec tions on Crafts and Williamson.Explorations in Economic History 24: 293319.Google Scholar
O’Brien, Patrick (1982) “European economic development: The contribution of the periphery.Economic History Review 35: 118.Google Scholar
Postlethwayt, Malachy (1746) “Considerations on a future treaty of navigation and commerce with Spain (November 25, 1746).” MS. 493 (1), Palaeography Room (Sterling Library). Senate House, University of London Library.Google Scholar
Postlethwayt, Malachy (1750) “The advantages to the nation in general of the Royal Assiento, and to the South Sea Company in particular asserted and maintained (1750).MS. 493 (2), Palaeography Room (Sterling Library). Senate House, University of London Library.Google Scholar
Postlethwayt, Malachy (1768) “The sequel to considerations upon the measures necessary to be taken by the Court of Great Britain to obtain a very good and a very durable peace (1768).” Additional MS. 33053, folio 323-330, Newcastle Papers, vol. 343. British Library.Google Scholar
Postlethwayt, Malachy (1967 [1757]) Great Britain’s True System. New York: Augustus M. Kelley.Google Scholar
Postlethwayt, Malachy (1968a [1757]) Britain’s Commercial Interest Explained and Improved. 2 vols., New York: Augustus M. Kelley.Google Scholar
Postlethwayt, Malachy (1968b) Selected Works. Vol. 1, 1745-1751. London: Gregg International.Google Scholar
Postlethwayt, Malachy (1968c) Selected Works. Vol. 2, 1746-1759. London: Gregg International.Google Scholar
Postlethwayt, Malachy (1971 [1755]) The Universal Dictionary of Trade and Commerce. New York: Augustus M. Kelley.Google Scholar
Ricardo, David (1951 [1817]) On the Principles of Political Economy and Taxation. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Richardson, David (1987) “The slave trade, sugar, and British economic growth, 1748-1776,” in Solow, B. and Engerman, S. (eds.) British Capitalism and Caribbean Slavery: The Legacy of Eric Williams. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press: 130.Google Scholar
Rodney, Walter (1972) How Europe Underdeveloped Africa. London: Bogle L’Ouverture.Google Scholar
Sheridan, Richard B. (1958) “The commercial and financial organization of the British slave trade, 1750-1807.” Economic History Review 11: 249-63.Google Scholar
Smith, Adam (1976 [1776]) An Inquiry into the Nature and Causes of the Wealth of Nations. 2 vols., Chicago: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
Solow, Barbara (1985) “Caribbean slavery and British growth: The Eric Williams hypothesis.” Journal of Development Economics 17: 99115.Google Scholar
Solow, Barbara, and Engerman, Stanley, eds. (1987) British Capitalism and Caribbean Slavery: The Legacy of Eric Williams. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
U.S. Department of Commerce (1987) Survey of Current Business 67: 24.Google Scholar
Wax, Darold D. (1973) “Preferences for slaves in colonial America.” Journal of Negro History 58: 371401.Google Scholar
Williams, Eric (1966 [1944]) Capitalism and Slavery. New York: Capricorn Books.Google Scholar
Williams, Wilson E. (1938) “Africa and the rise of capitalism.” M.A. thesis, Howard University.Google Scholar
Williamson, Jeffrey (1987) “Debating the British industrial revolution.” Explorations in Economic History 24: 269-92.Google Scholar
Wolfe, Bertram (1935-36) “Marxism and the Negro.” Race 1: 3740.Google Scholar
World Bank (1988) World Development Report 1988. New York: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar