Hostname: page-component-78c5997874-v9fdk Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-11-19T11:45:30.261Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

The Rise of Behavioral Economics: A Quantitative Assessment

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  25 July 2017

Abstract

This article is devoted to the issue of operationalizing and empirically measuring the development of behavioral economics, focusing on trends in the academic literature. The main research goal is to provide a quantitative, bibliometric assessment to answer the question of whether the relative importance of behavioral economics has increased over the past decades. After an introduction and a short summary of the history of behavioral economics, several studies are laid out and evaluated. The results generally provide a quantitative confirmation of the story of a rise of behavioral economics that can be found in the literature, and add some notable additional insights.

Type
Articles
Copyright
Copyright © Social Science History Association, 2017 

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

Akerlof, G. A. (1970) “The market for ‘lemons’: Quality uncertainty and the market mechanism.” The Quarterly Journal of Economics 84 (3): 488500.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Akerlof, G. A. (2002) “Behavioral macroeconomics and macroeconomic behavior.” The American Economic Review 92 (3): 411–33.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Akerlof, G. A., and Shiller, R. J. (2009) Animal Spirits: How Human Psychology Drives the Economy, and Why It Matters for Global Capitalism. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Alberts, B. (2013) “Impact factor distortions.” Science 340 (6134): 787.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Altman, M. (2004) “The Nobel Prize in behavioral and experimental economics: A contextual and critical appraisal of the contributions of Daniel Kahneman and Vernon Smith.” Review of Political Economy 16 (1): 341.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Altman, M., ed. (2006) Handbook of Contemporary Behavioral Economics: Foundations and Developments. New York: M. E. Sharpe.Google Scholar
Angner, E., and Loewenstein, G. (2012) “Behavioral economics,” in Mäki, U. (ed.) Philosophy of Economics, Volume 13 of Handbook of the Philosophy of Science. Amsterdam, The Netherlands: Elsevier: 641–89.Google Scholar
Arrow, K. J. (1982) “Risk perception in psychology and economics.” Economic Inquiry 20 (1): 19.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ashraf, N., Camerer, C. F., and Loewenstein, G. (2005) “Adam Smith, behavioral economist.” The Journal of Economic Perspectives 19 (3): 131–45.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Aversa, E. S. (1985) “Citation patterns of highly cited papers and their relationship to literature aging: A study of the working literature.” Scientometrics 7 (3–6): 383–89.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Barberis, N. C. (2013) “Thirty years of prospect theory in economics: A review and assessment.” The Journal of Economic Perspectives 27 (1): 173–96.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Becker, G. S. (1993) “Nobel Lecture: The economic way of looking at behavior.” The Journal of Political Economy 101 (3): 385409.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Benartzi, S., and Thaler, R. H. (1995) “Myopic loss aversion and the equity premium puzzle.” The Quarterly Journal of Economics 110 (1): 7392.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Berg, N. (2010) “Behavioral economics,” in Free, R. C. (ed.) 21st Century Economics: A Reference Handbook, Volume 2. SAGE Publishing: 861–72.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Berg, N. (2014) “The consistency and ecological rationality approaches to normative bounded rationality.” Journal of Economic Methodology 21 (4): 375–95.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Berg, N., and Gigerenzer, G. (2007) “Psychology implies paternalism? Bounded rationality may reduce the rationale to regulate risk-taking.” Social Choice and Welfare 28 (2): 337–59.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Berg, N., and Gigerenzer, G. (2010) “As-if behavioral economics: Neoclassical economics in disguise?History of Economic Ideas 18 (1): 133–66.Google Scholar
Böhm-Bawerk, E. (1889) Kapital und Kapitalzins. Zweite Abteilung: Positive Theorie des Kapitales. Innsbruck, Austria: Verlag der Wagner'schen Universitäts-Buchhandlung.Google Scholar
Bowles, S., ed. (2003) Microeconomics: Behavior, Institutions, and Evolution. Roundtable Series in Behavioral Economics. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Brandstätter, E., Gigerenzer, G., and Hertwig, R. (2006) “The priority heuristic: Making choices without trade-offs.” Psychological Review 113 (2): 409–32.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Brandstätter, E., Gigerenzer, G., and Hertwig, R. (2008) “Risky choice with heuristics: Reply to Birnbaum (2008), Johnson, Schulte-Mecklenbeck, and Willemsen (2008), and Rieger and Wang (2008).” Psychological Review 115 (1): 281–90.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bruni, L., and Sugden, R. (2007) “The road not taken: How psychology was removed from economics, and how it might be brought back.” The Economic Journal 117 (516): 146–73.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cahlik, T. (2000) “Search for fundamental articles in economics.” Scientometrics 49 (3): 389402.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Camerer, C. F. (1999) “Behavioral economics: Reunifying psychology and economics.” Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences of the United States of America 96 (19): 10575–77.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Camerer, C. F. (2000) “Prospect theory in the wild: Evidence from the field,” in Kahneman, D. and Tversky, A. (eds.) Choices, Values, and Frames. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press: 288300.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Camerer, C. F., ed. (2003) Behavioral Game Theory: Experiments in Strategic Interaction. Roundtable Series in Behavioral Economics. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Camerer, C. F., and Loewenstein, G. (2003) “Behavioral economics: Past, present, future,” in Camerer, C. F., Loewenstein, G., and Rabin, M. (eds.) Advances in Behavioral Economics. Roundtable Series in Behavioral Economics. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press: 351.Google Scholar
Camerer, C. F., Loewenstein, G., and Rabin, M. L., eds. (2003) Advances in Behavioral Economics. Roundtable Series in Behavioral Economics. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Cardoso, A. R., Guimaraes, P., and Zimmermann, K. F. (2010) “Trends in economic research: An international perspective.” Kyklos 63 (4): 479–94.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Costas, R., van Leeuwen, T. N., and van Raan, A. F. J. (2010) “Is scientific literature subject to a ‘sell-by-date’? A general methodology to analyze the ‘durability’ of scientific documents.” Journal of the American Society for Information Science and Technology 61 (2): 329–39.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cyert, R. M., and March, J. G. (1963) A Behavioral Theory of the Firm. Englewood Cliffs, NJ: Prentice-Hall.Google Scholar
De Solla Price, D. J. (1963) Little Science, Big Science. New York and London: Columbia University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Diamond, A. M. (2009) “Schumpeter vs. Keynes: ‘In the long run, not all of us are dead.’” Journal of the History of Economic Thought 31 (4): 531–41.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Duarte, P. G., and Giraud, Y. (2016) “The place of the history of economic thought in mainstream economics, 1991–2011, viewed through a bibliographic survey.” Journal of the History of Economic Thought 38 (4): 431–62.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Düppe, T. (2012) “Arrow and Debreu de-homogenized.” Journal of the History of Economic Thought 34 (4): 491514.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fehr, E., and Schmidt, K. M. (1999) “A theory of fairness, competition, and cooperation.” The Quarterly Journal of Economics 114 (3): 817–68.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fehr, E., Kirchsteiger, G., and Riedl, A. (1993) “Does fairness prevent market clearing? An experimental investigation.” The Quarterly Journal of Economics 108 (2): 437–59.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fisher, I. (1930) The Theory of Interest. London: Macmillan.Google Scholar
Garfield, E. (1955) “Citation indexes for science: A new dimension in documentation through association of ideas.” Science 122 (3159): 108–11.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Geiger, N. (2016) ““Psychological” elements in business cycle theories: Old approaches and new insights.” The European Journal of the History of Economic Thought 23 (3): 478507.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gigerenzer, G., and Goldstein, D. G. (1996) “Reasoning the fast and frugal way: Models of bounded rationality.” Psychological Review 103 (4): 650–69.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Gilovich, T., Griffin, D. W., and Kahneman, D., eds. (2002) Heuristics and biases: The psychology of intuitive judgment. Cambridge and New York: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hands, D. W. (2010) “Economics, psychology and the history of consumer choice theory.” Cambridge Journal of Economics 34: 633–48.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Heukelom, F. (2011) “Behavioral economics,” in Davis, J. B. and Hands, D. W. (eds.) The Elgar Companion to Recent Economic Methodology. Cheltenham, UK: Edward Elgar: 1938.Google Scholar
Heukelom, F. (2012a) “A sense of mission: The Alfred P. Sloan and Russell Sage Foundations’ behavioral economics program, 1984–1992.” Science in Context 25 (2): 263–86.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Heukelom, F. (2012b) “Three explanations for the Kahneman-Tversky Programme of the 1970s.” The European Journal of the History of Economic Thought 19 (5): 797828.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Heukelom, F. (2014) Behavioral Economics: A History. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hoover, K. D. (2014) “On the reception of Haavelmo's econometric thought.” Journal of the History of Economic Thought 36 (1): 4565.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kahneman, D. (2003a) “Maps of bounded rationality: Psychology for behavioral economics.” The American Economic Review 93 (5): 1449–75.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kahneman, D. (2003b) “A perspective on judgment and choice: Mapping bounded rationality.” American Psychologist 58 (9): 697720.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Kahneman, D. (2003c) “A psychological perspective on economics.” The American Economic Review 93 (2): 162–68.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kahneman, D. (2011) Thinking, Fast and Slow. London: Allen Lane.Google Scholar
Kahneman, D., and Tversky, A. (1979) “Prospect theory: An analysis of decision under risk.” Econometrica 47 (2): 263–91.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kahneman, D., and Tversky, A., eds. (2000) Choices, Values, and Frames. Cambridge and New York: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kahneman, D., Knetsch, J. L., and Thaler, R. H. (1986) “Fairness as a constraint on profit seeking: Entitlements in the market.” The American Economic Review 76 (4): 728–41.Google Scholar
Kahneman, D., Knetsch, J. L., and Thaler, R. H. (1991) “Anomalies: The endowment effect, loss aversion, and status quo bias.” The Journal of Economic Perspectives 5 (1): 193206.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kahneman, D., Tversky, A., and Slovic, P., eds. (1982) Judgment under Uncertainty: Heuristics and Biases. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Katona, G. (1946) “Psychological analysis of business decisions and expectations.” The American Economic Review 36 (1): 4462.Google Scholar
Katona, G. (1951) Psychological Analysis of Economic Behavior. New York: McGraw-Hill.Google Scholar
Katona, G. (1953) “Rational behavior and economic behaviour.” Psychological Review 60 (5): 307– 18.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Katona, G. (1968) “On the function of behavioral theory and behavioral research in economics.” The American Economic Review 58 (1): 146–50.Google Scholar
Katona, G. (1975) Psychological Economics. Oxford: Elsevier.Google Scholar
Keynes, J. M. (1936) The General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money, Volume 7 of The Collected Writings of John Maynard Keynes. London (1973): Macmillan.Google Scholar
Kim, E. H., Morse, A., and Zingales, L. (2006) “What has mattered to economics since 1970.” The Journal of Economic Perspectives 20 (4): 189202.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kufenko, V., and Geiger, N. (2016) “Business cycles in the economy and in economics: An econometric analysis.” Scientometrics 107 (1): 4369.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Laibson, D. (1997) “Golden eggs and hyperbolic discounting.” The Quarterly Journal of Economics 112 (2): 443–77.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Laibson, D., and Zeckhauser, R. (1998) “Amos Tversky and the ascent of behavioral economics.” Journal of Risk and Uncertainty 16 (1): 747.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Loewenstein, G. (1992) “The fall and rise of psychological explanations in the economics of intertemporal choice,” in Lowenstein, G. and Elster, J. (eds.) Choice over Time. New York: Russell Sage Foundation: 334.Google Scholar
McCain, K. W. (2014) “Assessing obliteration by incorporation in a full-text database: JSTOR, Economics, and the concept of ‘bounded rationality.’” Scientometrics 101 (2): 1445–59.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mehra, R., and Prescott, E. C. (1985) “The equity premium: A puzzle.” Journal of Monetary Economics 15 (2): 145–61.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Merton, R. K. (1988) “The Matthew effect in science, II: Cumulative advantage and the symbolism of intellectual property.” Isis 79 (4): 606–23.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mullainathan, S., and Thaler, R. H. (2000) “Behavioral economics.” NBER Working Paper 7948.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Oehler, K. (1990) “Speaking axiomatically: Citation patterns to early articles in general equilibrium theory.” History of Political Economy 22 (1): 101–12.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rabin, M. (1998) “Psychology and economics.” Journal of Economic Literature 36 (1): 1146.Google Scholar
Rabin, M. (2002) “A perspective on psychology and economics.” European Economic Review 46 (4–5): 657–85.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rabin, M. (2013) “An approach to incorporating psychology into economics.” The American Economic Review 103 (3): 617–22.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rieskamp, J., and Reimer, T. (2007) “Ecological rationality,” in Baumeister, R. F. and Vohs, K. D. (eds.) Encyclopedia of Social Psychology. Thousand Oaks, CA: Sage: 273–75.Google Scholar
Sargent, T. J. (1993) Bounded Rationality in Macroeconomics. Oxford: Oxford University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Selten, R. (1990) “Bounded rationality.” Journal of Institutional and Theoretical Economics/Zeitschrift für die gesamte Staatswissenschaft 146 (4): 649–58.Google Scholar
Selten, R. (1999) “What is bounded rationality?” SFB Discussion Paper B-454.Google Scholar
Sent, E.-M. (1997) “Sargent versus Simon: Bounded rationality unbound.” Cambridge Journal of Economics 21 (3): 323–38.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sent, E.-M. (2004) “Behavioral economics: How psychology made its (limited) way back into economics.” History of Political Economy 36 (4): 735–60.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sent, E.-M. (2008) “Rationality, history of the concept,” in Durlauf, S. N. and Blume, L. E. (eds.) The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics, 2nd ed. London: Palgrave Macmillan: 895902.Google Scholar
Shiller, R. J. (1981) “Do stock prices move too much to be justified by subsequent changes in dividends?The American Economic Review 71 (3): 421–36.Google Scholar
Simon, H. A. (1955) “A behavioral model of rational choice.” The Quarterly Journal of Economics 69 (1): 99118.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Simon, H. A. (1956) “Rational choice and the structure of the environment.” Psychological Review 63 (2): 129–38.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Simon, H. A. (1957) Models of Man: Social and Rational. New York: Wiley.Google Scholar
Simon, H. A. (1978) “Rationality as process and as product of thought.” The American Economic Review 68 (2): 116.Google Scholar
Simon, H. A. (1979) “Rational decision making in business organizations.” The American Economic Review 69 (4): 493513.Google Scholar
Simon, H. A. (1986) “Rationality in psychology and economics.” The Journal of Business 59 (4): S209–S224.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Simon, H. A. (1991) Models of My Life. New York: Basic Books.Google Scholar
Smith, A. (1759) The Theory of Moral Sentiments, Volume 1 of The Glasgow Edition of the Works and Correspondence of Adam Smith. Oxford (1976): Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Smith, V. L. (1962) “An experimental study of competitive market behavior.” The Journal of Political Economy 70 (2): 111–37.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Smith, V. L. (1976) “Experimental economics: Induced value theory.” The American Economic Review 66 (2): 274–79.Google Scholar
Smith, V. L. (1991) “Rational choice: The contrast between economics and psychology.” The Journal of Political Economy 99 (4): 877–97.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Smith, V. L. (2003) “Constructivist and ecological rationality in economics.” The American Economic Review 93 (3): 465508.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Thaler, R. H. (1980) “Toward a positive theory of consumer choice.” Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization 1 (1): 3960.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Thaler, R. H. (1985) “Mental accounting and consumer choice.” Marketing Science 4 (3): 199214.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Thaler, R. H. (1992) The Winner's Curse: Paradoxes and Anomalies of Economic Life. New York: Free Press.Google Scholar
Thaler, R. H. (1997) “Irving Fisher: Modern behavioral economist.” The American Economic Review 87 (2): 439–41.Google Scholar
Thaler, R. H. (1999) “Mental accounting matters.” Journal of Behavioral Decision Making 12 (3): 183206.3.0.CO;2-F>CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Thaler, R. H. (2000) “From homo economicus to homo sapiens.” The Journal of Economic Perspectives 14 (1): 133–41.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Thaler, R. H. (2008a) “Commentary: Mental accounting and consumer choice: Anatomy of a failure.” Marketing Science 27 (1): 1214.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Thaler, R. H. (2008b) “Mental accounting and consumer choice.” Marketing Science 27 (1): 1525.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Thaler, R. H., ed. (2005) Advances in Behavioral Finance: Volume II. Roundtable Series in Behavioral Economics. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Thaler, R. H., and Sunstein, C. R. (2003) “Libertarian paternalism.” The American Economic Review 93 (2): 175–79.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Thaler, R. H., and Sunstein, C. R. (2008) Nudge: Improving Decisions about Health, Wealth, and Happiness (reworked and extended ed.). New Haven, CT: Yale University Press.Google Scholar
Tversky, A., and Kahneman, D. (1974) “Judgment under uncertainty: Heuristics and biases.” Science 185 (4157): 1124–31.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Tversky, A., and Kahneman, D. (1981) “The framing of decisions and the psychology of choice.” Science 211 (4481): 453–58.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Tversky, A., and Kahneman, D. (1986) “Rational choice and the framing of decisions.” The Journal of Business 59 (4): S251–S278.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Tversky, A., and Kahneman, D. (1987) “Rational choice and the framing of decisions,” in Hogarth, R. M. and Reder, M. W. (eds.) Rational Choice: The Contrast between Economics and Psychology. Chicago: University of Chicago Press: 6794.Google Scholar
Tversky, A., and Kahneman, D. (1992) “Advances in prospect theory: Cumulative representation of uncertainty.” Journal of Risk and Uncertainty 5 (4): 297323.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wilkinson, N., and Klaes, M. (2012) An Introduction to Behavioral Economics. London: Palgrave Macmillan.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Supplementary material: Image

Geiger supplementary material

Geiger supplementary material 1

Download Geiger supplementary material(Image)
Image 1.1 MB
Supplementary material: Image

Geiger supplementary material

Geiger supplementary material 2

Download Geiger supplementary material(Image)
Image 1.5 MB
Supplementary material: Image

Geiger supplementary material

Geiger supplementary material 3

Download Geiger supplementary material(Image)
Image 1.6 MB