Hostname: page-component-586b7cd67f-r5fsc Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-11-28T22:55:27.005Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

The Capitalist Epoch

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  03 June 2015

Abstract

This presidential address argues that capitalism must be understood as an epochal phenomenon, that is, as a historically specific and temporally limited form of life with social and temporal dynamics that set it off from previous eras of history and that are not destined to last indefinitely. Capitalism's most distinctive feature—sustained secular economic growth in per capita terms—has brought great benefits to the human race, not only increasing economic well-being but endowing people with bigger, stronger, and more resilient bodies and radically increased life spans. It has also made possible an astounding increase in society's technical, educational, and scientific powers. The experience of sustained economic growth has led to a particular sense of time as open-ended and progressive—making possible modern historical consciousness. Meanwhile, the relentless commodification of social relations under capitalism has tended to free people from domination based on personal status, but also to subject them to more abstract forms of domination. Creative destruction, which is capitalism's key mechanism for producing sustained economic growth, has also produced an unmasterable cyclical pattern of boom and bust, creating new forms of insecurity at the same time that it tends to lift people out of absolute poverty. Capitalist development has always been spatially uneven. There is reason, however, to think that the capitalist era may be approaching its end. The shape of the postcapitalist era will depend on how well we collectively make use of the powers that the capitalist era has produced—science and technology, to be sure, but also the critical historical consciousness that lies at the heart of social science history.

Type
Presidential Address
Copyright
Copyright © Social Science History Association 2015 

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

Arrighi, Giovanni (1994) The Long Twentieth Century: Money, Power, and the Origins of Our Times. London: Verso.Google Scholar
Aston, T. H., and Philpin, C. H. E., eds. (1985) The Brenner Debate: Agrarian Class Structure and Economic Development in Pre-Industrial Europe. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Berman, Marshall (1982) All That Is Solid Melts into Air: The Experience of Modernity. New York: Simon and Schuster.Google Scholar
Bourguignon, François, and Morrison, Christian (2002) “Inequality among world citizens: 1820–1992.” American Economic Review 92 (4): 727–44.Google Scholar
Chrakabarty, Dipesh (2009) “The climate of history: Four theses.” Critical Inquiry 35: 197222.Google Scholar
de Vries, Jan (2008) The Industrious Revolution: Consumer Behavior and the Household Economy, 1650 to the Present. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Floud, Roderick, Fogel, Robert William, Harris, Bernard, and Hong, Sok Chul (2011) The Changing Body: Health, Nutrition, and Human Development in the Western World since 1700. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Fogel, Robert William (2004) The Escape from Hunger and Premature Death, 1700–2100: Europe, America, and the Third World. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Gramsci, Antonio (1971) Selections from the Prison Notebooks, ed. and trans. Quintin Hoare and Geoffrey Nowell Smith. New York: International Publishers.Google Scholar
Harvey, David (1999) The Limits to Capital. London: Verso.Google Scholar
Koselleck, Reinhart (2002) “The eighteenth century as the beginning of modernity,” in The Practice of Conceptual History: Timing History, Spacing Concepts, trans. Todd Samuel Presner, Kerstin Behnke, and Jobst Welge. Foreword by Hayden White. Stanford, CA: Stanford University Press: 154–69.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Le Roy Ladurie, Emmanuel (1974) “L'histoire immobile.” Annales: Économies, Sociétés, Civilisations 29 (3): 673–92.Google Scholar
Marx, Karl (1977) Capital. Vol. 1. Introduction by Ernest Mandel, trans. Ben Fowkes. New York: Vintage Books.Google Scholar
Marx, Karl and Engels, Friedrich (1962) “Manifesto of the Communist Party,” in Selected Works, Vol. 1. Moscow: Foreign Languages Publishing House: 21–69.Google Scholar
North, Douglas C. (1981) Structure and Change in Economic History. New York: W. W. Norton.Google Scholar
North, Douglas C. (1990) Institutions, Institutional Change, and Economic Performance. New York: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
North Douglas, C., and Thomas, Robert Paul (1973) The Rise of the Western World: A New Economic History. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Pomerantz, Kenneth (2000) The Great Divergence: China, Europe, and the Making of the Modern World Economy. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Postone, Moishe (1993) Time, Labor, and Social Domination: A Reinterpretation of Marx's Critical Theory. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Schumpeter, Joseph A. (1950) Capitalism, Socialism, and Democracy. 3rd ed. New York: Harper and Row.Google Scholar
Sewell, William H. Jr. (1980) Work and Revolution: The Language of Labor from the Old Regime to the Revolution of 1848. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Sewell, William H. Jr. (1994) A Rhetoric of Bourgeois Revolution: The Abbé Sieyes and “What Is the Third Estate?” Durham, NC: Duke University Press.Google Scholar
Sewell, William H. Jr. (2005) Logics of History: Social Theory and Social Transformation. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
Sewell, William H. Jr. (2008) “The temporalities of capitalism.” Socio-Economic Review 6 (3): 517–37.Google Scholar
Sewell, William H. Jr. (2010) “The rise of capitalism and the empire of fashion in eighteenth-century France.” Past and Present 206 (1): 81120.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sewell, William H. Jr. (2012) “Economic crises and the shape of modern history.” Public Culture 24 (2): 303–27.Google Scholar
Wallerstein, Immanuel (1974) The Modern World-System. Vol. 1, Capitalist Agriculture and the Origins of the European World-Economy in the Sixteenth Century. New York: Academic Press.Google Scholar
Weber, Max (1976) The Protestant Ethic and the Spirit of Capitalism, trans. Talcott Parsons. Introduction by Anthony Giddens. New York: Charles Scribner's Sons.Google Scholar
Wilson, Arthur M. (1972) Diderot. New York: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar