Published online by Cambridge University Press: 31 October 2008
When writing his final report in 1823 on the current state of affairs in the county of Kopparberg in Sweden, its governor, Hans Järta, made a short digression to ponder upon the differences between England and Sweden. According to Järta, England had been unfortunate in that it had deprived a large proportion of its rural population of the land on which they could otherwise have supported themselves. They had now, Järta remarked, no other choice but to work in the factories, and were the first to suffer when these had to close down. In some parts of Sweden, efforts were at this time being made to organise agricultural production in accordance with similar ideas, that is, through the use of wage labour. Järta was deeply sceptical about these experiments however, claiming that they led to nothing but poverty and social problems.
2. What Järta had in mind was probably the so-called statarsystem. See Eriksson, I. and Rogers, J., Rural Labor and Population Change. Social and Demographic Developments in East-Central Sweden during the Nineteenth Century (Uppsala, 1978).Google Scholar
3. Järta, H., Underdånig Berättelse om Stora Kopparbergs län [A Humble Report concerning the County of Stora Kopparberg] (Falun, 1823) p. 19.Google Scholar
4. Thirsk, J., ‘Industries in the Countryside’ in Essays in the Economic and Social History of Tudor and Stuart England in Honour of Professor R.H. Tawney (Cambridge, 1961)Google Scholar; see also the criticism of Berg, M. in The Age of Manufactures 1700–1820 (London, 1985) pp. 103ff.Google Scholar In the case of Kopparberg, it should be pointed out that partible inheritance does not seem to have been common in its southwestern part, but in spite of this proto-industry (peasant iron production) flourished. See e.g. ongoing research by M. Sjöberg, Stockholm (to be published in autumn 1993).
5. Marx, K., Capital, Book I chapter 24 (1867; Swedish translation Lund, 1981).Google Scholar
6. For an overview see e.g. Charlesworth, A., An Atlas of Rural Protest in Britain 1548–1900 (London, 1983) pp. 8–28.Google Scholar
7. Clay, C. G. A., Economic Expansion and Social Change: England 1500–1700, vol. 1 (Cambridge, 1984) p. 72.Google Scholar
8. The general importance of indebtedness is underlined already by Dobb, M. in Studies in the Development of Capitalism (London, 1946), chapters 5:1, 6:1.Google Scholar
9. See e.g. Neeson, J. M., ‘Parliamentary Enclosure and the Disappearance of the English Peasantry, Revisited’ in Agararian Organization in the Century of Industrialization: Europe, Russia and North America (Greenwich, 1989)Google Scholar; Searle, C. E., ‘Custom, Class Conflict and Agrarian Capitalism: the Cumbrian Customary Economy in the Eighteenth Century’ in: Past and Present, 1986:110.Google Scholar
10. Almqvist, J. E., ‘Till frågan om skattebondens jordäganderätt under perioden 1719–1789 [Regarding the property rights of the skattebonde in the period 1719–1789] in Minnesskrift ägnad 1734 års lag (Stockholm, 1934).Google Scholar
11. Carlsson, S., Svensk historia [Swedish History] (Stockholm, 1961, 1980) p. 64.Google Scholar
12. See e.g. Rydeberg, G., Skatteköen i Öebro lan 1701–1809 [The Sales of Crown Lands in the Province of Örebro, Sweden 1701–1809] (Uppsala, 1985).Google Scholar
13. The selling out of Crown land thus proved a much greater success in Sweden than it did in England in the early seventeenth century; cf Hoyle, R., ‘“Vain projects”: the Crown and its copyholders in the reign of James I’ in English Rural Society 1500–1800. Essays in Honour of Joan Thirsk, ed. Chartres, J. & Hey, D. (Cambridge, 1990).Google Scholar
14. Winberg, C., Folkökning och proletarisering. Kring den sociala strukturomvandlingen på Sveriges landsbygd under den agrara revolutionen [Population Growth and Proletarianization. The Transformation of Social Structures in Rural Sweden during the Agrarian Revolution] (Göteborg, 1975).Google Scholar This dissertation is presented and discussed at length by Tilly, C. in Proletarianization and family history ed. Levine, D. (Orlando, 1984).Google Scholar
15. Some parts of Sweden, most notably the northern ones, obviously did not have the same experience. See Ågren, M., Jord och gäld. Social skiktning och rättslig konflikt i södra Dalarna ca 1650–1850 [Land and Debt. Social differentiation and legal conflict in southern Dalecarlia c. 1650–1850] (Uppsala, 1992) p. 34ff.Google Scholar
16. C. Winberg, op. cit. pp. 208ff; Söderberg, J., Agrar fattigdom i Sydsverige under 1800-talet [Agrarian Poverty in Southern Sweden during the Nineteenth Century] (Stockholm, 1978) pp. 126ff.Google Scholar
17. Cf. Hannerberg, D., Svenskt agrarsamhälle under 1200 år [Swedish rural society during 1200 years] (Stockholm, Oslo, Köpenhamn, 1971)Google Scholar; C. Winberg, op. cit.; Isacson, M., Ekonomisk tillväxt och social differentiering 1680–1860. Bondeklassen i By socken, Kopparbergs län [Economic Development and Social Differentiation 1680–1860: A Peasant Class in a Parish in Dalecarlia] (Uppsala, 1979).Google Scholar
18. Emphasis should be put upon the distinction between proletarianization, in the sense of losing the productive resources with which to support oneself, and proletarianization, in the sense of becoming a proletarian worker. Obviously, these two meanings of the word are both frequent but it is not always clear which one a writer has in mind. The problem of pauperism can often be observed in societies where proletarianization in the first sense has proceeded quite far, whereas the labour market is still undeveloped, i.e. few people have been proletarianized in the second sense. See M. Ågren, op. cit. pp. 30ff.
19. Wrightson, K., English Society 1580–1680 (London, 1982) pp. 130ffGoogle Scholar; C. G. A. Clay, op. cit. pp. 67ff.
20. This period in Swedish history is presented in English by several historians in Sweden's Age of Greatness 1632–1718, ed. Roberts, M. (London, Basingstoke, 1973)Google Scholar and by Nilsson, S. A. in The Age of New Sweden (Stockholm, 1988).Google Scholar
21. Cf. Dahlgren, S., ‘Karl XI’ in Kungar och krigare [Kings and Warriors] (Stockholm, 1992).Google Scholar
22. On the taxation system and its effects see e.g. S. Dahlgren, ‘Skatterna och jordbruket under 1700- och 1800-talen’ [Taxes and agriculture during the 18th and 19th centuries] in Statens jordbrukspolitik under 200 år (1991).
23. Österberg, E., Gränsbygd under krig. Ekonomiska, demografiska och administrativa förhållanden i sydvästra Sverige under och efter nordiska sjuårskriget [Borderdistrict at war. The economic, demographic and administrative situation of southwestern Sweden during and after the war 1563–1570] (Lund, 1971)Google Scholar passim; Kolonisation och kriser. Bebyggelse, skattetryck, odling och aararstruktur i västra Värmland ca 1300–1600 [Colonisation and Crisis. Settlement, taxation, cultivation and agrarian structure in western Värmland ca 1300–1600] (Lund, 1977) pp. 254ffGoogle Scholar; M. Isacson, op. cit. p 174; Lindegren, J., Utskrivning och utsugning. Produktion och reproduktion i Bygdeå 1620–1640 [Conscription and Exploitation. Production and Reproduction in the Parish of Bygdeå 1620–1640] (Uppsala, 1980) pp. 19, 26, 38, 198, 259.Google Scholar Cf. also Myrdal, J. and Söderberg, J., Kontinuitetens dynamik. Agrar ekonomi i 1500-talets Sverige [Dynamics of continuity: The Agrarian Economy of Sixteenth-Century Sweden] (Stockholm, 1991) pp. 508ffGoogle Scholar, who maintain that there are very few signs of differentiation in sixteenth-century Sweden.
24. On the creation of a free market for land transactions see e.g. Winberg, C., Grenverket. Studier rörande jord, släktskapssystem och ståndsprivilegier [Ramifications. Studies on land, kinship systems and privileges] (Stockholm, 1985)Google Scholar; Österberg, E., ‘Land Transactions. Symptoms of Crisis or the Emergence of Capitalism in Swedish Peasant Society?’ in Plov og Pen. Festskrift til Svend Gissel (Københarn, 1991)Google Scholar; Backlund, J., Rusthållarna i Fellingsbro 1684–1748. Indelningsverket och den sociala differentieringen av det svenska agrarsamhället [Peasants and Arms — Fellingsbro Equips the Cavalry 1684–1748: The military allotment system and social differentiation in Swedish agrarian society] (Uppsala, 1993).Google Scholar
25. Letter from Charles XI, 15 October 1684; quoted and translated from M. Ågren, op. cit., p 45.
26. M. Ågren, op. cit., p 59ff.
27. This process is analysed in detail by Herlitz, L. in Jordegendom och ränta. Omfördelningen av jordbrukets merprodukt i Skaraborgs län under frihetstiden [Land ownership and rent. The redistribution of the surplus of agriculture in the province of Skaraborg during the Freedom Time [sic]] (Göteborg, 1974) pp. 282, 347, 349, 361.Google Scholar
28. Cf. the perspective of Spufford, M. in ‘Peasant inheritance customs and land distribution in Cambridgeshire from the sixteenth to the eighteenth centuries’ in Family and Inheritance: Rural Society in Western Europe 1200–1800, ed. Goody, J., Thirsk, J. and Thompson, E. P. (Cambridge, 1976)Google Scholar and of Winberg, C. in ‘Familj och jord i tre västgötasocknar. Generationsskiften bland självägande bönder ca 1810–1870’ [Family and inheritance in three parishes of southwestern Sweden about 1810–1870] in Svensk Historisk Tidskrift 1981: 3.Google Scholar
29. Florén, A., Disciplinering och konflikt. Den sociala organiseringen av arbetet. Jäders bruk 1640–1750 [Discipline and Conflict. The Social Organization of Work: The Example of Jäder Ironworks] (Uppsala, 1987).Google Scholar
30. Anderson, P., Lineages of the Absolutist State (London, 1974).Google Scholar
31. When not indicated otherwise, the whole section is built upon results presented and discussed in my thesis (M. Ågren, op. cit.).
32. Cf. e.g. J. Söderberg, op. cit., on the importance of poor relief in nineteenth-century local selfgovernment see e.g. Tiscornia, A., Statens, godsens eller böndernas socknar? Den sockenkommunala självstyrelsens utveckling i Västerfärnebo, Stora Malm och Jäder 1800–1880 [State, manorial or peasants' parishes? Swedish Local Self-government in Transition, c. 1800–1880] (Uppsala, 1992).Google Scholar
33. C. G. A. Clay, op. cit. pp. 99ff.
34. 10 skeppund = c. 1.5 tons.
35. When discussing eighteenth-century criminal statistics, Douglas Hay has argued that the figures pertaining to theft cannot reasonably be influenced by any enforcement waves, since such crimes were not prosecuted by state representatives. He thus seems to define an enforcement wave as something which results solely from the controlling and enforcing activities of the state. It seems to me that this is making the concept unduly narrow. (Hay, D., ‘War, Dearth and Theft in the Eighteenth Century: The Record of the English Courts’ in Past and Present 1982:95Google Scholar).
36. 1 tunnland = c. 5,000 m2
37. Ågren, M., ‘Att lösa ekonomiska tvister — domstolarnas främsta sysselsättning på 1700-talet?’ [Settling disputes — the Principal Occupation of the Courts in the Eighteenth Century?] in Svensk Historisk Tidskrift, 1988:4.Google Scholar
38. Cf. Sjöberg, M. Taussi, ‘Tinget sam social arena’ [The court as social arena] in Historia Nu ed. Brändström, A. et al. , (Umeå, 1988)Google Scholar; Sundin, J., För Gud, staten och folket [Crime and Local Justice in Pre-Industrial Sweden] (Stockholm, 1992).Google Scholar
39. Contrary to what happened in other Swedish counties, the reform was not proposed by the local population but by the governor. Because of its alleged poverty, the peasantry was given ample state funding to cover the expenses related to the reform (M. Ågren, op. cit., pp. 177f).
40. It should be noticed that the Swedish word for ‘enclosure’ — skifte — means exchange, which is not incidental. A presentation of the Swedish ‘enclosure movement’ is given by S. Helmfrid in ‘The Storskifte, Enskifte and Laga Skifte in Sweden. General Features’ in Geografiska Annaler, 1960.
41. M. Ågren, op. cit., pp. 212ff.
42. M. Isacson, op. cit., pp. 82, 180.
43. Cf. note 17.
44. S. Carlsson, op. cit., pp. 64f.
45. Hobsbawm, E., The Age of Revolution: Europe 1789–1848 (London, 1962) p. 149.Google Scholar
46. C. G. A. Clay, op. cit., pp. 68, 71, 75.
47. Ibid. pp. 85ff.
48. J. M. Neeson, op. cit.
49. Cf. Winberg, C., ‘Another route to modern society: The advancement of the Swedish peasantry’ in Agrarian Society in History: Essays in Honour of Magnus Mörner, ed. Lundahl, M. and Svensson, T. (London, New York, 1990).Google Scholar