Hostname: page-component-586b7cd67f-2brh9 Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-11-25T08:57:59.382Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

The Fiscal Component of Revolution: An Essay in Fiscal Sociology

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  05 August 2009

Extract

Throughout history, the control of public funds has been considered a cornerstone of political power. If it is true that all societies, from die dawn of civilizations to the present, have been divided into two classes, one that rules and the other that is ruled, it may be expected that the methods of raising and spending government money have been determined by one social group, generally a minority, to the complete or almost complete exclusion of the rest of the population. Such control would be intended to kill two birds with one stone, serving the direct purpose of administering the state and the indirect purpose of strengthening the privileged position of the governing group and thus prolonging their predominance. Yet studies in fiscal sociology are still in tlieir infancy. Because of their casual and hapo hazard character, they are not as yet a match for political sociology. Only during recent decades has a broader and more systematic approach been attempted.

Type
Research Article
Copyright
Copyright © University of Notre Dame 1947

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

1 This analysis is designed to supplement several of my former studies in this field, particularly: Finanzsoziologie. Grundsätzliche Bemerkungen.” Kölner Vierleljahrshefte fur Soziologie, vol. XII (1933), pp. 120;Google ScholarBeiträge zur Steuersoziologie,” Finanzarchiv, Neue Folge, vol. II (1934), pp. 281314;Google ScholarZur Soziologie der finanzpolitischen Entscheidung,” SchmolUrs Jahrhuch, vol. LVII (1933), pp. 705730;Google ScholarAlbert Schäffle als Wirtschaftsund Finanzsoziologe,” Gründer der Soziologie (vol. IVGoogle Scholar of my series Soziawissenschaftliche Bausteine), Jena 1932, pp. 1178;Google ScholarThe Sociology of Taxation,” The Review Of Politics, vol. V (1943), pp. 225235.Google Scholar See also my book Steuerpolitische Ideale. Vergleichende Studien zur Geschichte der politischen und ökonomischien Ideen und ihres Wirkens in der öffentlichen Meinung 1600–1935 (Jena 1935) (vol. V of my series Finanzwissenschlaftlicher Forschungen).Google Scholar

2 Loth, David, Public Plunder: A History of Crafl in America (New York, 1938), p. 404.Google Scholar

3 See Fortune, May, 1940, pp. 4849.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

4 See, for instance, Mosca, G., The Ruling Class (Elemenii di Scienza Politico) ed. by Livingston, Arthur (New York, 1939), p. 368.Google Scholar

5 Wicksell, Knut, Finanzlheoretische Untersuchungen (Jena 1896), pp. 110124;Google ScholarLindahl, Eric, Die Cerechligkeil der Besieuerung. Eine Analyse der Steuerprinzipien auf Grundlage der Crenznuizentheorie (Lund, 1919), pp. 144154.Google Scholar

6 Petty, William, “A Treatise of Taxes and Contributions,” London 1662:Google Scholar in The Economic Writings of Sir William Ptliy, edited by Hull, Ch. H. (Cambridge, 1899), p. 32.Google Scholar

7 Goldscheid, Rudolf, Staatssozialismus oder Staatskapitalismus? Ein finanzsoziologischer Beitrag zur Lösung des Staatsschulden-Problems (2d and 3rd ed.Vienna-Leip-Google Scholar

8 Goldscheid, Rudolf, “Staat, Öffentlicher Haushalt and Gesellschaft,” in Handbuch der Finanzmssemchaft, edited by Gerloff, W. and Meisel, F., vol. I (Tubingen, 1926). p. 148.Google Scholar

9 Sorokin, Pitirim A., The Sociology of Revolution (Philadelphia and London, 1925). p. 367.Google Scholar

10 I would thus quality Merriman's, R. B. interpretation, which lists the government's financial exactions as one of the two chief original causes of the revolt (Six Contemporaneous Revolutions (Glasgow, 1937), p. 13.Google Scholar

11 Taine, H., Les Origines de la France Contemporaine, vol. III,Google ScholarL' Ancien Régime, vol. II (Paris, 1899), p. 233.Google Scholar

12 Marion, Marcel, Histoire Financière de la France depuis 1715 (Paris, 1919), Introduction, page v.Google Scholar

13 Mathiez, Albert, La Question Sociale pendant la Révolution Française (Paris. 1905), p. 4.Google Scholar

14 de Tocqueville, Alexis, L'Ançien Régime el la Révolution (2d ed., Paris, 1856), pp. 283, 285286.Google Scholar

15 Ibid., pp. 286–287.

16 Wahl, Adalbert, Vorgeschichte der französischen Revolution, vol. I (Tübingen, 1905), p. 348.Google Scholar

17 LeFebvre, Georges in: La Révolution Française by LeFebvre, G., Guyot, R. and Sagnac, Ph. (Paris, 1930), p. 7.Google Scholar

18 Brinton, Crane, The Anatomy of Revolution (New York, 1938), p. 42.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

19 See Stein, L. V., Geschichte der sozialen Bemegung in Frankreich von 1789 bis auf unsere Tage, I. Bd., Der Begriff der Gesellschaft und die soziale Geschichte der französischen Revolution his zum Jahre 1830 (Munich, 1921), pp. 9798.Google Scholar

20 Quoted from Alfred Meusel's article Revolution and Counterrevolution,” Encyclopedia of the Social Sciences, vol. XIII, p. 368.Google Scholar

21 Ortega, Jose y Gasset, , Der Aufstand der Massen (Stuttgart-Berlin, 1933), p. 130.Google Scholar

22 Hyslop, Beatrice Fry, French Nationalism in 1789 according lo the General Cahiers (New York, 1934), pp. 8486.Google Scholar

23 Idem., p. 86.

24 Trevelyan, George M., The English Revolution 1668–1689 (London, 1939), pp. 4493.Google Scholar

25 Macaulay, Thomas B., The History of England from the Accession of James II. vol. I (New York, 1856), pp. 482483.Google Scholar

26 Sorokin, Pitirim A., op. cit., p. 374.Google Scholar

27 Van Tyne, Claude H., The Causes of the War of Independence (Boston and New York, 1922), p. 171.Google Scholar

28 See Dewey, Davis R., Financial History of the United States, 11th ed. (New York, 1931), pp. 3132;Google ScholarFaulkner, Harold Underwood, American Economic History (5th ed., New York, 1943), p. 128.Google Scholar

29 Hacker, Louis M., The Triumph of American Capitalism (New York, 1940), p. 160.Google Scholar

30 Faulkner, Harold U., American Economic History (5th ed., New York, 1943), p. 130.Google Scholar

31 Brinton, Crane, The Anatomy of Revolution (New York, 1938), p. 42.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

32 Hacker, Louis M., The Triumph of American Capitalism (New York, 1940), p. 161.Google Scholar

33 Beard, Charles A. and Beard, Mary R., The Rise of American Civilization (New York, 1930), pp. 201203.Google Scholar

34 Also Wright, Chester W., who considers the economic conditions as subordinate causes compared with the political ideals of liberty and self-government, admits that, proximately, the struggle originated in the sphere of tangible material interests, “in the problems of the economic and political organization of the expanding British Empire” (Economic History of the United States (New York, 1941), pp. 204205).Google Scholar

35 Van Tyne, Claude H., p. 184.Google Scholar

36 Brinton, Crane, p. 40.Google Scholar

37 Merriman, R. B., Six Contemporaneous Revolutions (Glasgow, 1937), p. 10.Google Scholar

38 Idem., p. 11.

39 In comparing the six seventeenth-century upheavals in England, France, the Netherlands, Spain, Portugal, and Naples, Professor R. B. Merriman contends: “In the first place, we find that the most immediate, though not always the most fundamental cause of every one of them was finance; in every case it was arbitrary taxation in one form or another, and the complaints that it evoked, that brought matters to a head.” (op. cit., pp. 1516.)Google Scholar

40 See Kemmerer, Edwin Walter, Inflation and Revolution. Mexico's Experience, 1912–1917 (Princeton. 1940).Google Scholar

41 Compare Stolper, Gustav, German Economy, 1870–1940, Issues and Trends (New York, 1940), pp. 125130.Google Scholar

42 Quoted from Andreades, A. M., A History of Creefc Public Finance, vol. I (Cambridge, 1933). pp. 222223.Google Scholar

43 Compare Rostovtzeff, M., A History of the Ancient World, vol. I (Oxford, 1926). pp. 316317,Google ScholarAndreades, A. M., pp. 130131.Google Scholar

44 Compare Meyer, Eduard, Geschichte des Alterthums, vol. 4 (Stuttgart and Berlin, 1901), pp. 560601.Google Scholar

45 Peisker, J., Die serbische Zadruga, Zeitschrift für Sozial and Wirlschaftsgeschichte, vol. VII (1900), pp. 211326.Google Scholar

46 See Simkhowitch, Wladimir Gr., Die Feldgemeinschaft in Russland (Jena, 1898);Google ScholarTschuprow, Alexander A., Die Feldgemeinschaft. Eine morphologische Untersuchung (Strassburg, 1902);Google ScholarRachfahl, Felix, “Zur Geschichte des Grundeigentums,” Jahrbücher für National-ökonomie, vol. 74 (1900), p. 9;Google ScholarBelow, Georg V., “Das kurze Leben einer viel genannten Theorie” in: Probleme der Wirischaftsgeschichte (Tübingen, 1920), pp. 1314.Google Scholar

47 Caesar, , De Bello Callico, Liber VI, ch. 13.Google Scholar