Hostname: page-component-78c5997874-fbnjt Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-11-06T06:54:16.209Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Conjuring the spirit of multilateralism: Histories of crisis management during the ‘great credit crash’

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  08 June 2015

Abstract

In recent years, critical scholars have emphasised how the recollection of past events as traumas can both constrain and widen the political possibilities of a present. This article builds on such research by suggesting that the management of contemporary financial crises is reliant on a ritual work of repetition, wherein prior ‘crisis’ episodes are called upon to identify and authorise specific sites and modes of crisis management. In order to develop this argument, I focus on how past crises figure within the public pronouncements of four key policymaking organisations during the financial instability of 2007–9. I find that while the Great Depression does enable these organisations to reaffirm old ways of managing crises, both it and the more recent Asian crisis are also made to disclose new truths about the evolution of multilateralism as a form of governance. In so doing, I argue, these historical narratives reveal how the management of global financial crisis depends upon a kind of ‘magic trick’. Rather than a strictly rational, historical process of problem solving, contemporary crises are instead negotiated through a contingent and self-referential conjuring of crisis-histories.

Type
Articles
Copyright
© 2015 British International Studies Association 

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

1 President of the European Central Bank (2003–11) quoted in Peel, Quentin, ‘Europe writes a history of crisis management’, The Financial Times (9 October 2008)Google Scholar.

2 Oatley, Thomas, A Political Economy of American Hegemony: Buildups, Booms, and Busts (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 2015)CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

3 Drezner, Daniel, The System Worked: How the World Stopped Another Great Depression (Oxford: Oxford University Press, 2014)Google Scholar.

4 See Minsky, Hyman P., Can ‘It’ Happen Again? Essays on Instability and Finance (New York, NY: M. E. Sharpe, 1982)Google Scholar; Delong, J. Bradford, ‘Financial crises in the 1890s and the 1990s: Must history repeat?’, Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, 1999:2 (1999), pp. 253–294CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Reinhart, Carmen M. and Rogoff, Kenneth S., This Time Is Different: Eight Centuries of Financial Folly (Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press, 2009)Google Scholar.

5 Duncan Bell provides an invaluable overview of this literature in his edited collection, Memory, Trauma and World Politics: Reflections on the Relationship Between Past and Present (Basingstoke: Palgrave Macmillan, 2006). See also Edkins, Jenny, Trauma and the Memory of Politics (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 2003)CrossRefGoogle Scholar; and Zehfuss, Maja, Wounds of Memory: The Politics of War in Germany (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 2007)CrossRefGoogle Scholar. In relation to global finance and financial crisis in particular see Brassett, James and Clarke, Chris, ‘Performing the sub-prime crisis: Trauma and the financial event’, International Political Sociology, 6:1 (2012), pp. 4–20CrossRefGoogle Scholar, and Brassett, James and Vaughan-Williams, Nick, ‘Crisis is governance: Sub-prime, the traumatic event, and bare life’, Global Society, 26:1 (2012), pp. 19–42CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

6 Eliade, Mircea, The Myth of the Eternal Return: Or, Cosmos and History, trans. Willard Trask (Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press, 1991 [orig. pub. 1954]), p. 149Google Scholar.

7 ‘Historiophany’ is a neologism intended to specify an epiphany brought on through the apparent manifestation of History to humankind. It is a play on ‘theophany’, where of course it is God that appears.

8 See Koselleck, Reinhart, ‘Crisis’, Journal of the History of Ideas, 67:2 (2006), pp. 357–400CrossRefGoogle Scholar (pp. 358–61, 368–97).

9 Marx’s writings on crisis are notoriously fragmented, spawning an entire cottage industry in critical exegesis. My comments here relate to his discussion of over-accumulation in Capital: Volume III (Moscow: Progress Publishers, 1977 [orig. pub. 1894]), pp. 247–59. For more on the role of ‘crisis’ in Marxian economics see Mattick, Paul, Economic Crisis and Crisis Theory (London: Merlin Press, 1981), pp. 43–77Google Scholar.

10 On history and the sublime see Hayden White’s 1982 article, ‘The politics of historical interpretation: Discipline and de-bublimation’, reprinted in The Content of the Form: Narrative Discourse and Historical Representation (Baltimore, MD: Johns Hopkins University Press, 1987), pp. 58–82 (p. 69ff). See also Nietzsche’s ‘On the uses and disadvantages of history for life’, in Daniel Breazeale (ed.), Friedrich Nietzsche: Untimely Meditations (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1997 [orig. pub. 1874]), pp. 57–124.

11 White, , Content of the Form, pp. 2325Google Scholar, 44–6, and 66–8; cf. Mink, Louis O., ‘Narrative form as cognitive instrument’, in Robert Canary and Henry Kozicki (eds), The Writing of History: Literary Form and Historical Understanding (Madison, WI: University of Wisconsin Press, 1978), pp. 129–149Google Scholar (pp. 143–4). Paul Ricoeur also appropriates and builds on Mink’s concept of configuration. For example, see his essay on ‘The narrative function’, in Thompson, John (ed.), Hermeneutics and the Human Sciences: Essays on Language, Action and Interpretation (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1981), pp. 274–296Google Scholar.

12 Kerwin Lee Klein, ‘On the emergence of memory in historical discourse’, Representations, 69:Winter (2000), pp. 127–50 (p. 128). With ‘counter-concept’ Klein means to highlight the ability of ‘memory’ to reorient the focus and conduct of historical studies. For Klein and others there are signs not only that this reorientation has taken place, but also that a reversal may be underway. See Rosenfeld, Gavriel, ‘A looming crash or a soft landing? Forecasting the future of the memory industry’, The Journal of Modern History, 81:1 (2009), pp. 122–158CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

13 Ricoeur, Paul, Memory, History, Forgetting, trans. Kathleen Blamey and David Pellauer (Chicago, IL: University of Chicago Press, 2004), pp. 5–55CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

14 Ibid., pp. 56–92, 234–92.

15 Michel de Certeau, The Writing of History, trans. Tom Conley (New York, NY: Columbia University Press, 1988 [orig. pub. 1975]), p. 94.

16 Brassett and Clarke, ‘Performing sub-prime’.

17 Ibid., p. 14. See also Brassett, James, Rethel, Lena, and Watson, Matthew, ‘The political economy of the subprime crisis: the economics, politics and ethics of response’, New Political Economy, 15:1 (2010), pp. 1–7CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

18 Brassett and Vaughan-Williams, ‘Crisis is governance’.

19 Ibid., p. 28.

20 See Brassett, and Clarke, , ‘Performing sub-prime’, p. 18Google Scholar.

21 In this context the Holocaust still serves as the paradigmatic case study, but trauma thinking has also proved influential in the study of other genocides, as well as plagues, wars, famines, terrorist attacks, and even financial crises. See, for example, Caruth, Cathy, Unclaimed Experience: Trauma, Narrative and History (Baltimore, MD: Johns Hopkins University Press, 1996)CrossRefGoogle Scholar; LaCapra, Dominick, History and Memory After Auschwitz (Ithaca, NY: Cornell University Press, 1998)CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Jenny Edkins, Trauma and the Memory of Politics; Maja Zehfuss, Wounds of Memory; and Paul Crosthwaite, ‘Is a financial crisis a trauma?’ Cultural Critique, 82:Fall (2012), pp. 34–67.

22 Radstone, Susannah, ‘Trauma theory: Contexts, politics, ethics’, Paragraph, 30:1 (2007), pp. 929CrossRefGoogle Scholar. In contrast, see Friedlander, Saul (ed.), Probing the Limits of Representation: Nazism and the ‘Final Solution’ (Cambridge: Harvard University Press, 1992)Google Scholar.

23 Bousquet, Antoine, ‘Time zero: Hiroshima, September 11 and apocalyptic revelations in historical consciousness’, Millennium: Journal of International Studies, 34:3 (2006), pp. 739–764Google Scholar (p. 739).

24 Lawless, Kate, ‘Unrecyclable times: the traumatic topographies of global capitalism in W. G. Sebald’s Austerlitz’, The Word Hoard, 1:2 (2013), pp. 94108Google Scholar (p. 94).

25 White, , ‘The historical event’, p. 29Google Scholar, emphasis in original.

26 Ibid., p. 30, emphasis added.

27 Eliade, , Eternal Return, p. 149Google Scholar.

28 Eliade’s terminology is unlikely to sit well with the contemporary reader, but what he means to designate with terms like ‘archaic’ are societies without historical discourse. In his study these ‘premodern or “traditional” societies include both the world usually known as “primitive”, and the ancient cultures of Asia, Europe, and America’ (in Eternal Return, p. 3). Moreover, for Eliade the ontologies of such societies need not give way to historicism. Indeed he anticipates the opposite: ‘as the terror of history grows worse … the positions of historicism will increasingly lose in prestige’ (ibid., p. 153).

29 Ibid., pp. 73–92, pp. 112–30.

30 Ibid., pp. 102–12.

31 Speaking of later Hebrew and Christian theodicies, Hayden White terms this the ‘figure-fulfillment model’ of trauma, thus highlighting the retroactive structure of revelation. See White, , ‘The historical event’, p. 28Google Scholar.

32 White, , Content of the Form, pp. 169184Google Scholar.

33 Berressem, Hanjo, ‘Crystal history: “You pick up the pieces. You connect the dots”’, in Bernd Herzogenrath (ed.), Time and History in Deleuze and Serres (London: Continuum, 2012), pp. 203–228Google Scholar (p. 215).

34 For example, compare Kindleberger, Charles, The World in Depression, 1929-1939 (London: Allen Lane, 1973)Google Scholar; Polanyi, Karl, The Great Transformation: The Political and Economic Origins of Our Time (Boston, MA: Beacon Press, 2001 [orig. pub. 1944])Google Scholar; Trachtenberg, Marc, ‘Keynes triumphant: a study in the social history of economic ideas’, Knowledge and Society, 4 (1983), pp. 1786Google Scholar; and Ruggie, John Gerard, ‘International regimes, transactions, and change: Embedded liberalism in the postwar economic order’, International Organization, 36:2 (1982), pp. 379415CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

35 Nsouli, Saleh, ‘Lessons from the Recent Financial Crisis and the Role of the Fund’, Paris (26 June 2008)Google Scholar, Section I, available at: {http://www.imf.org/external/np/speeches/2008/062608.htm} accessed 22 June 2009.

36 Mishkin, Frederic, ‘Global Financial Turmoil and the World Economy’, Eliat (2 July 2008)Google Scholar, Section I, available at: {http://www.federalreserve.gov/newsevents/speech/mishkin20080702a.htm} accessed 29 July 2009.

37 Stark, Jürgen, ‘EMU: Weathering the Perfect Storm’, London (25 June 2009)Google Scholar, Section I, available at: {http://www.ecb.int/press/key/date/2009/html/sp090625.en.html} accessed 30 June 2009. See also Barr, Michael, ‘Remarks on Regulatory Reform’, Washington DC (15 July 2009)Google Scholar, Section I, available at: {http://www.treasury.gov/press-center/press-releases/Pages/tg213.aspx} accessed 18 September 2013.

38 de Rato, Rodrigo, ‘Confronting the Future with Wisdom and Courage’, Washington DC (19 July 2007)Google Scholar, Point 7, available at: {http://www.imf.org/external/np/speeches/2007/071907.htm} accessed 28 May 2009.

39 McCormick, David, ‘Remarks at the Peter G. Peterson Institute for International Economics Conference on IMF Reform’, Washington DC (25 February 2008)Google Scholar, Section II, available at: {http://www.treasury.gov/press-center/press-releases/Pages/hp838.aspx} accessed 18 September 2013.

40 Smaghi, Lorenzo, ‘From Tuscany’s 19th Century Currency, the Fiorino, to the Euro’, Florence (15 May 2008)Google Scholar, paras 28–9, available at: {http://www.ecb.int/press/key/date/2008/html/sp080515_2.en.html} accessed 27 October 2009.

41 Strauss-Kahn, Dominique, ‘Remarks to the Board of Governors of the IMF’, Washington DC (13 October 2008)Google Scholar, para. 12, available at: {http://www.imf.org/external/np/speeches/2008/101308.htm} accessed 22 June 2009.

42 Sobel, Mark, ‘Remarks on the Global Financial Crisis and the IMF’s Response’ (2 December 2008)Google Scholar, Section I, available at: {http://www.treasury.gov/press-center/press-releases/Pages/hp1307.aspx} accessed 18 September 2013; Lorenzo Smaghi, ‘The Financial Crisis and Global Imbalances’, Beijing (9 December 2008), Section II, available at: {http://www.ecb.int/press/key/date/2008/html/sp081209.en.html} accessed 5 October 2009.

43 This, for example, is the narrative that underpins Kindleberger’s The World in Depression. Incidentally, Kindleberger’s narrative of the Great Depression was carried through into subsequent theories of hegemonic stability within international studies. On these theories and the debates they inspired see Grunberg, Isabelle, ‘Exploring the “myth” of hegemonic stability’, International Organization, 44:4 (1990), pp. 431–477CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

44 I discuss these and other narrated threats of recurrence at length in Samman, Amin, ‘The 1930s as black mirror: Visions of historical repetition in the global financial press, 2007–2009’, Journal of Cultural Economy, 5:2 (2012), pp. 213–229CrossRefGoogle Scholar. For a similar analysis that focuses specifically on trade discourse and policy, see Siles-Brügge, Gabriel, ‘Explaining the resilience of free trade: the “Smoot-Hawley” myth and the crisis’, Review of International Political Economy, 21:3 (2014), pp. 535–574CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

45 Smaghi, Lorenzo, ‘The Euro Area’s Exchange Rate Policy and the Experience with International Monetary Coordination During the Crisis’, Brussels (6 April 2009)Google Scholar, Section I, available at: {http://www.ecb.int/press/key/date/2009/html/sp090406.en.html} accessed 19 October 2009; Timothy Geithner, ‘The United States and China: Cooperating for Recovery and Growth’, Beijing (1 June 2009), Section II, available at: {http://www.treasury.gov/press-center/press-releases/Pages/tg152.aspx} accessed 18 September 2013.

46 Lipsky, John, ‘Crisis Lessons for the IMF’, New York (17 December 2008)Google Scholar, Section IV, available at: {http://www.imf.org/external/np/speeches/2008/121708.htm} accessed 28 May 2009.

47 Smaghi, ‘Financial Crisis and Global Imbalances’, Section II.

48 Strauss-Kahn, ‘Remarks to the Board of Governors’, Paras 3, 7, and 10.

49 Ibid., para. 19.

50 Lipsky, ‘Crisis Lessons for the IMF’, Section IV. See also Dominique Strauss-Kahn, ‘Speech delivered at the 44th SEACEN Governors’ Conference’, Kuala Lumpur (7 February 2009), Section I, available at: {http://www.imf.org/external/np/speeches/2009/020709.htm} accessed 22 June 2009.

51 See McCormick, ‘Remarks on IMF Reform’, Section II; and Sobel, ‘Global Financial Crisis and the IMF’, Section I.

52 Strauss-Kahn, Dominique, ‘Multilateralism and the Role of the International Monetary Fund in the Global Financial Crisis’, Washington DC (23 April 2009)Google Scholar, Section I, emphasis added. Available at: {http://www.imf.org/external/np/speeches/2009/042309.htm} accessed 28 May 2009.

53 Strauss-Kahn, Dominique, ‘Economic Stability, Economic Cooperation, and Peace’, Oslo (23 October 2009)Google Scholar, Section II, available at: {http://www.imf.org/external/np/speeches/2009/102309.htm} accessed 23 October 2009.

54 An early and influential version of this critical response is outlined in Robert Wade and Frank Veneroso’s article, ‘The Asian crisis: the high-debt model vs. the Wall Street-Treasury-IMF complex’, New Left Review, March–April (1998), pp. 3–23.

55 See, for example, Haggard, Stephan and MacIntyre, Andrew, ‘The political economy of the Asian economic crisis’, Review of International Political Economy, 5:3 (1998), pp. 381–392CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

56 On this compare Gore, Charles, ‘The rise and the fall of the Washington consensus as a paradigm for developing countries’, World Development, 28:5 (2000), pp. 789–804CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Hayami, Yujiro, ‘From the Washington consensus to the post-Washington consensus: Retrospect and prospect’, Asian Development Review, 20:2 (2003), pp. 47–54CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Sheppard, Eric and Leitner, Helga, ‘Quo Vadis Neoliberalism? The remaking of global capitalist governance after the Washington consensus’, Geoforum, 41:2 (2010), pp. 185–194CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

57 Kang, Laura Hyun Yi, ‘The uses of Asianization: Figuring crises, 1997–98 and 2007-?’, American Quarterly, 64:3 (2012), pp. 411436CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

58 Warsh, Kevin, ‘Market Liquidity: Definitions and Implications’, Washington DC (5 March 2007)Google Scholar, Section II, available at: {http://www.federalreserve.gov/newsevents/speech/warsh20070305a.htm} accessed 6 October 2009.

59 Burton, David, ‘Asia: Ten Years On’, Singapore (5 June 2007)Google Scholar, Section I, available at: {http://www.imf.org/external/np/speeches/2007/060507.htm} accessed 28 May 2009; Randall Kroszner, ‘Analyzing and Assessing Banking Crises’, San Francisco (6 September 2007), Section II, available at: {http://www.federalreserve.gov/newsevents/speech/kroszner20070906a.htm} accessed 6 October 2009.

60 The then Chairman of the Federal Reserve Ben Bernanke first articulates this crisis history in a speech entitled ‘Global Imbalances: Recent Developments and Prospects’, Berlin (11 September 2007). available at: {http://www.federalreserve.gov/newsevents/speech/bernanke20070911a.htm} accessed 6 October 2009.

61 On the global narration of state failure in South Korea after its crisis, see Hall, Rodney Bruce, ‘The discursive demolition of the Asian development model’, International Studies Quarterly, 47:1 (2003), pp. 71–99CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

62 Rodrigo de Rato, ‘Ten years after the Asian currency crisis’, Tokyo (22 January 2007a), Point, available at: {http://www.imf.org/external/np/speeches/2007/012207.htm} accessed 28 May 2009.

63 In late 2007, the IMF faced considerable budgetary pressures, prompting it to layoff 15 per cent of its staff in order to reduce operating expenses. See Broome, André, ‘The International Monetary Fund, crisis management and the credit crunch’, Australian Journal of International Affairs, 64:1 (2010), pp. 37–54CrossRefGoogle Scholar (pp. 45–6).

64 Frederic Mishkin, ‘Systemic risk and the international lender of last resort’, Chicago (28 September 2007), Section III, available at: {http://www.federalreserve.gov/newsevents/speech/mishkin20070928a.htm} accessed 12 October 2009.

65 Jean-Claude Trichet, ‘Reflections on the international financial architecture’, Salzburg (29 September 2007), Section III, available at: {http://www.ecb.int/press/key/date/2007/html/sp070929.en.html} accessed 23 June 2009.

66 Ibid., Section I. Paradoxically, in this schema the task of ‘crisis prevention’ is at once both never and always the same – never, because each new solution always has its particulars, and always, because these solutions never actually solve the problem which prompts them (namely, the emergent properties of globalisation itself).

67 Ibid., Section I.

68 Ibid., Section I.

69 For an indication of this shift from optimism to disappointment, compare Noble, Gregory and Ravenhill, John (eds), The Asian Financial Crisis and the Architecture of Global Finance (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 2000)CrossRefGoogle Scholar; and Best, Jacqueline, ‘The limits of financial risk management: Or what we didn’t learn from the Asian crisis’, New Political Economy, 15:1 (2010), pp. 29–49CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

70 See Trichet, ‘International financial architecture’, Section III; and ‘Reflections on the global financial system’, Washington DC (20 October 2007), Section II, available at: {http://www.ecb.int/press/key/date/2007/html/sp071020.en.html} accessed 23 June 2009.

71 Jean-Claude Trichet, ‘Remarks on the Recent Turbulences in Global Financial Markets’, New York (14 April 2008), Section III, available at: {http://www.ecb.int/press/key/date/2008/html/sp080414_1.en.html} accessed 23 June 2009.

72 Clay Lowery, ‘Remarks at the Annual Conference of the Institute of International Bankers’, New York (3 March 2008), Section IV, available at: {http://www.treasury.gov/press-center/press-releases/Pages/hp855.aspx} accessed 18 September 2013; David McCormick, ‘The International Response to Financial Market Turmoil’, Chicago (16 April 2008), Section III, available at: {http://www.treasury.gov/press-center/press-releases/Pages/hp931.aspx} accessed 18 September 2013.

73 Trichet, ‘Turbulences in Global Financial Markets’, Section III; Sobel, ‘Global Financial Crisis and the IMF’, Section III.

74 Daniel Tarullo, ‘International Cooperation to Modernize Financial Regulation’, Washington DC (30 September 2009), Section I; available at: {http://www.federalreserve.gov/newsevents/testimony/tarullo20090930a.htm}, accessed 15 October 2009. For a discussion of this transformation and its potential signifiance, see Helleiner, Eric, ‘What role for the new financial stability board? The politics of international standards after the crisis’, Global Policy, 1:3 (2010), pp. 282–290CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

75 Trichet, ‘International Financial Architecture’, Section III.

76 Jean-Claude Trichet, ‘Lessons from the Financial Crisis’, Frankfurt (15 October 2009), Section III, available at: {http://www.ecb.int/press/key/date/2009/html/sp091015.en.html} accessed 23 October 2009.

77 Krugman, Paul, The Return of Depression Economics (New York, NY: W. W. Norton, 1999)CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

78 Krugman, Paul, The Return of Depression Economics and the Crisis of 2008 (New York, NY: W. W. Norton, 2009)Google Scholar.

79 Brassett and Clarke, ‘Performing sub-prime’; Brassett and Vaughan-Williams, ‘Crisis is governance’.

80 Brassett and Clarke, ‘Performing sub-prime’, p. 18.

81 Roitman, Janet, Anti-Crisis (Durham, NC: Duke University Press, 2014), p. 90Google Scholar.