Hostname: page-component-586b7cd67f-rcrh6 Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-11-25T05:47:08.935Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Is there an Explanation for the Current Inflation(*)

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  17 August 2016

Alfred Steinherr*
Affiliation:
Université Catholique de Louvain
Get access

Extract

For the last 25 years the industrial countries of the West have experienced continuous rises in price levels. However, as shown in Table 1, price indexes rose moderately until the end of the sixties but show a sharp acceleration from then onwards. In this paper attempts are made to identify and explain the main causes of that acceleration. It is, of course, obvious that in every country special factors and circumstances contributed to differences in national inflation rates. These factors we shall neglect.

In a similar effort Nordhaus (1972) emphasized that it is difficult to accept the large number of special factors and theories offered to explain the worldwide inflationary phenomenon. After testing, and rejecting as generally applicable, several hypotheses (the monetarist theory, the naive Phillips curve, the expectations Phillips curve, frustration theories, and the Scandinavian model) Nordhaus offers his own interpretation. In a world of interdependent economies a disturbance in one part of the world tends to be transmitted to other parts of the world through linkages in commodity trade and in financial markets. The particular disturbance identified by Nordhaus is the abrupt acceleration of the U.S. price level around 1968. While, as can again be seen from Table 1, U.S. prices were more stable than world market prices before 1968 this was no longer true after 1968.

Type
Research Article
Copyright
Copyright © Université catholique de Louvain, Institut de recherches économiques et sociales 1974 

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

Footnotes

(*)

The author has benefitted from discussions with A. Kervyn de Lettenhove, R. Schmalensee, and G. Vila. None of them is in any way responsible for opinions or errors in the paper.

References

Aukrust, O., «Prim I : A Model of the Price and Income Distribution Mechanism of an Open Economy», Review of Income and Wealth (March, 1970), 5178.Google Scholar
Branson, W.H., and Myhrman, J., «Inflation in Open Economies : Supply-Determined vs. Demand Determined Models», Seminar Paper no. 34, Institute for International Economic Studies, Stockholm.Google Scholar
Caves, R.E., et al., Britain's Economic Prospects (Washington: Brookings Institution, 1968).Google Scholar
Caves, R.E., Reuben, G.L., et al., Capital Transfers and Economic Policy: Canada, 1951-1962, Harvard Economic Studies, no. 135 (Cambridge: Harvard University Press, 1971).Google Scholar
Caves, R.E., and Jones, R.W., World Trade and Payments (Boston: Little, Brown, 1973).Google Scholar
Corden, W.M., Monetary Integration, Essays in International Finance, no. 93 (International Finance Section, Princeton University, 1972).Google Scholar
Dunn, R.M., «Flexible Exchange Rates and Oligopoly Pricing: A Study of Canadian Markets», Journal of Political Economy, 78 (January/February, 1970), 140151.10.1086/259613Google Scholar
Edgren, G., Faxen, K.-O., and Odhner, C.-E., «Wages, Growth and the Distribution of Income», Swedish Journal of Economics, 71 (September, 1969), 133160.10.2307/3439366Google Scholar
Ehrenberg, H., «Von Waffenmangel keine Rede», Die Zeit, no. 16, April 12, 1974.Google Scholar
Foster, E., «Costs and Benefits of Inflation», Research Department, Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis (March, 1972).Google Scholar
Friedman, M., in Newsweek (1973).Google Scholar
Goldstein, M., «The Trade-off Between Inflation and Unemployment: A Survey of the Econometric Evidence for Selected Countries», IMP Staff Papers, 19 (November, 1972), 647695.10.2307/3866420Google Scholar
Hankel, W., «Ist gegen die Inflation kein Kraut gewachsen ?», Die Zeit, no. 33, August 17, 1973.Google Scholar
Johnson, H.G., and Nobay, A.R., ed., The Current Inflation (London: Macmillan, 1971).10.1007/978-1-349-01284-8Google Scholar
Jones, A., The New Inflation (London: Penguin, 1973).Google Scholar
Mundell, R.A., «The Dollar and the Policy Mix: 1971», Essays in International Finance, no. 85 (May, 1971).Google Scholar
Mundell, R.A., Monetary Theory (Siena: Santa Colomba, 1971).Google Scholar
Nordhaus, W.D., «The Worldwide Wage Explosion», Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, 2: 1972, 431464.10.2307/2534184Google Scholar
Okun, A.M., The Political Economy of Prosperity (Brookings Institution, 1970).Google Scholar
Romanis, A., «Cost Inflation and Incomes Policy in Industrial Countries», IMP Staff Papers, 14 (March, 1967), 169206.10.2307/3866387Google Scholar
Samuelson, P.A., and Solow, R.M., «The Problem of Achieving and Maintaining a Stable Price Level: Analytical Aspects of Anti-Inflation Policy», American Economic Review, supplement, (May, 1960).Google Scholar
Spitäller, E., «Prices and Unemployment in Selected Industrial Countries», IMF Staff Papers, 18 (November, 1971), 528569.Google Scholar
Turnovsky, S.J., «Empirical Evidence on the Formation of Price Expectations», Journal of the American Statistical Association, no. 65 (December, 1970), 1441–54.Google Scholar
Winch, D.M., «Inflation and Resource Allocation», mimeo, Department of Economics, McMaster University (June, 1970).Google Scholar
Annual Report of the Banque Nationale de Belgique, Bruxelles.Google Scholar
Annual Report of the Deutsche Bundesbank, Frankfurt.Google Scholar
Annual Report of the Bank for International Settlements, Basle.Google Scholar
Bank of England, Quarterly Bulletin, vol. 14 (March, 1974).Google Scholar
Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development (OECD), Inflation: The Present Problem (Paris: 1970).Google Scholar
Weltkonjunkturdienst, HWWA-Institut für Wirtschaftsforschung, Hamburg.Google Scholar