Hostname: page-component-586b7cd67f-rdxmf Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-11-25T05:14:21.601Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Consumer Behavior Versus Economie Theory(*)

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  17 August 2016

Richard Schmalensee*
Affiliation:
University of California, San Diego
Get access

Extract

The neoclassical model of consumer behavior, hereafter generally called utility theory, both serves as the basis for modern welfare theory and draws some of its support from the usefulness of that theory to the economics profession. Modern welfare theory, however, posits a direct correspondence between market behavior and individual welfare, a correspondence that does not exist in modern market economies. In such economies, where information is imperfect and learning is important, utility theory also fails to describe or to facilitate analysis of important aspects of consumers' behavior. Thus it provides neither a sound normative theory nor a generally useful positive theory of consumer' behavior. These assertions are amplified and defended in Sections I - III below.

Type
Research Article
Copyright
Copyright © Université catholique de Louvain, Institut de recherches économiques et sociales 1974 

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

Footnotes

(*)

This paper was written while I was Visiting Associate Professor of Economics. University of Louvain. I would like to thank A.P. Barten and D. Weiserbs for very helpful comments on an earlier version, without suggesting that they necessarily agree with anything that remains.

References

[1] Allison, R.I. and Uhl, K.P.. “Influence of Beer Brand Identification on Taste Perception”. Journal of Marketing Research, 1 (August, 1964), 3639.10.1177/002224376400100305Google Scholar
[2] Anderson, L.K., Taylor, J.R., and Holloway, R.J., “The Consumer and His Alternatives: An Experimental Approach”, Journal of Marketing Research. 3 (February, 1966), 6267.10.1177/002224376600300107Google Scholar
[3] Becker, G.S., “A Theory of the Allocation of Time”. Economic Journal, 75 (September, 1965), 493517.10.2307/2228949Google Scholar
[4] Comanor, W.S. and Wilson, T.A., “Advertising Market Structure and Performance”. Review of Economics and Statistics, 49 (November, 1967), 423440.10.2307/1928327Google Scholar
[5] Cox, D.F. and Rich, S., “Perceived Risk and Consumer Decision-Making – A Case of Telephone Shopping”, Journal of Marketing Research, 1 (November, 1964), 3239.Google Scholar
[6] Cross, J.G., “A Stochastic Learning Model of Economic Behavior”. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 87 (May, 1973). 239266.10.2307/1882186Google Scholar
[7] Cyert, R.M. and March, J.G., A Behavioral Theory of the Firm, Englewood Cliffs, N.J.: Prentice-Hall, 1963.Google Scholar
[8] Day, R.H., Morley, S., and Smith, K.R., “Myopic Optimizing and Rules of Thumb in a Micro-Model of Industrial Growth,” American Economic Review, 64 (March, 1974), 1123.Google Scholar
[9] Ehrlich, D., Guttman, I., Schönbach, P. and Mills, J., “Post Decision Exposure to Relevant Information”. Journal of Abnormal and Social Psychology, 54 (January, 1957), 98102.10.1037/h0042740Google Scholar
[10] Engel, J.F., “Are Automobile Purchasers Dissonant Consumers?Journal of Marketing, 27 (April, 1963), 5558.10.1177/002224296302700211Google Scholar
[11] Engel, J.F., Kollat, D.T. and Blackwell, R.D., Consumer Behavior. New York: Holt. Rinehartand Winston. 1968.Google Scholar
[12] Experimental Economics. Symposium on. Review of Economic Studies. 36 (October, 1969), 399502.Google Scholar
[13] Farley, J.U., “Why Does Brand Loyalty Vary over Products?Journal of Advertising Research. 1 (November, 1964). 914.Google Scholar
[14] Fisher, F.M., A Priori Information and Time Series Analysis. Amsterdam: North-Holland. 1962.Google Scholar
[15] Fisk, G.Media Influence Reconsidered”. Public Opinion Quarterly. 23 (1959), 8391.10.1086/266848Google Scholar
[16] Gabor, A. and Granger, C.W.J., “Price as an Indicator of Quality: Report on an Inquiry”. Economica. 33 (February, 1966). 4370.10.2307/2552272Google Scholar
[17] Gintis, H., “Welfare Economics and Individual Development”. Quarterly Journal of Economics. 86 (November, 1972). 632683.10.2307/1882043Google Scholar
[18] Hempel, D.J., “An Experimental Study of the Effects of Information on Consumer Product Evaluations”. in Haas, R.M., ed., Science, Technology and Marketing, Chicago: American Marketing Association. 1966, 413421.Google Scholar
[19] Kassarjian, H.H. and Robertson, T.S., Perspectives in Consumer Behavior. Glenview, Ill.: Scott. Foresman. 1968.Google Scholar
[20] Katona, G., “Rational Behavior and Economic Behavior”. Psychological Review, 60 (1953), 307318.10.1037/h0060640Google Scholar
[21] Katona, G., The Powerful Consumer, New York: McGraw-Hill. 1960.Google Scholar
[22] Katona, G. and Mueller, E., “A Study of Purchasing Decisions”. in Clark, L. H., ed., Consumer Behavior: The Dynamics of Consumer Reactions, New York: New York University Press, 1955, 3087.Google Scholar
[23] Kihlstrom, R.A General Theory of the Demand for Information about Product Quality”. University of Massachusetts. Amherst, mimeographed. 1973.Google Scholar
[24] Kuehn, A.A., “An Analysts of the Dynamics of Consumer Behavior and Its Implications for Marketing Management.” unpublished dissertation. Carnegie Institute of Technology. 1958.Google Scholar
[25] Lancaster, K., “A New Approach to Consumer Theory”. Journal of Political Economy, 74 (April, 1966). 132157.10.1086/259131Google Scholar
[26] Lanzetta, J.T. and Kanareff, V., “Information Cost. Amount of Payoff and Level of Aspiration as Determinants of Information Seeking in Decision-Making”. Behavioral Science, 7 (1962), 459473.10.1002/bs.3830070406Google Scholar
[27] Manove, M., “Consumer Behavior and Preference Formation “. CORE Discussion Paper 7343, 1973.Google Scholar
[28] Mishan, E.J., “Theories of Consumer Behavior: A Cynical View”. Economica. 28 (February, 1961), 111.10.2307/2550449Google Scholar
[29] Mueller, E., “The Desire for Innovations in Household Goods”. in Clark, L.H., ed.. Consumer Behavior: Research on Consumer Reactions, New York: Harper & Row, 1958, 1337.Google Scholar
[30] Phlips, L., Applied Consumption A nalvsis, Amsterdam: North-Holland. 1974 Google Scholar
[31] Rothenberg, J., “Welfare Comparisons and Changes in Tastes”. American Economic Review. 43 (December, 1953). 885890.Google Scholar
[32] Rothschild, M., “A Two-Armed Bandit Theory of Market Pricing”, Journal of Economic Theory, forthcoming.Google Scholar
[33] Schmalensee, R., The Economics of Advertising, Amsterdam: North-Holland. 1972.Google Scholar
[34] Schmalensee, R., “Brand Loyalty and Barriers to Entry.” Southern Economic Journal, 40 (April, 1974), 579588.10.2307/1056376Google Scholar
[35] Schmalensee, R., “Advertising and Economic Welfare.” in Divita, S.F.. ed., Adverlising and the Public Interest. Chicago: American Marketing Association, forthcoming.Google Scholar
[36] Schmalensee, R., “An Experimental Studv of Expectation FormationEconometrica forthcoming.Google Scholar
[37] Schmalensee, R., “Alternative Models of Bandit Selection.” unpublished. 1974.Google Scholar
[38] Sen, A., “Behavior and the Concept of Preference”. Economica. 40 (August, 1973), 241259 10.2307/2552796Google Scholar
[39] Sheth, J.N., “A Review of Buyer Behavior”. Management Science, 13 (August, 1967). B718B786.10.1287/mnsc.13.12.B718Google Scholar
[40] Simon, H.A., “Theories of Decision-Making in Economics and Behavioral ScienceAmerican Economic Review. 49 (June, 1959). 253283.Google Scholar
[41] Sonnenschein, H., “Market Excess Demand Functions”. Econometrica. 40 (May, 1972), 549564.10.2307/1913184Google Scholar
[42] Stafford, J.E. and Enis, B.M., “The Price-Quality Relationship: An Extention”. Journal of Marketing Research. 6 November, 1969). 456458.10.1177/002224376900600411Google Scholar
[43] Starr, R.M.. “Optimal Production and Allocation under Uncertainty”. Quarterly Journal of Economics. 37 (February, 1973). 8195.10.2307/1885225Google Scholar
[44] Stigler, G.J., “The Economics of Information”. Journal of Political Economy. 69 (June, 1961). 213225.10.1086/258464Google Scholar
[45] Tucker, W.T., “The Development of Brand Loyalty”. Journal of Marketing Research, 3 (August, 1964). 3235.10.1177/002224376400100304Google Scholar
[46] Turnovsky, S., “Empirical Evidence on the Formation of Price Expectations”. Journal of the American Statistical Association. 65 (December, 1970), 11411454.10.1080/01621459.1970.10481175Google Scholar
[47] Von Weizsäcker, C.C.Notes on Endogenous Changes in Tastes”. Journal of Economic Theory 3 (December, 1971). 345372.10.1016/0022-0531(71)90037-8Google Scholar