Hostname: page-component-586b7cd67f-dlnhk Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-11-26T01:03:02.410Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Brain Drain, R&D-Cost Differentials and the Innovation Gap*

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  17 August 2016

Fabio Mariani*
Affiliation:
Paris School of Economics, Universite Paris 1 Pantheon-Sorbonne and IZA, Bonn.
Get access

Summary

This paper aims at explaining why countries with comparable levels of education still experience notable differences in terms of R&D and innovation. High-skilled migration, ultimately linked to differences in R&D costs, might be responsible for the persistence of such a gap. In fact, in a model where human capital accumulation and innovation are strategic complements, we show that allowing labor outflows may strengthen educational incentives in the lagging economy if migration is probabilistic in nature, but at the same time reduces the share of innovative production. Income (growth) might be consequently affected, and a positive migration chance is very unlikely to act as a substitute for educational subsidies.

Résumé

Résumé

Ce papier se propose d'expliquer pourquoi certains pays, caractérisés par un system éducatif de niveau comparable, diffèrent de façon importante en termes d'innovation et d'R&D. La migration des travailleurs qualifiées, liée aux différents coûts de R&D, pourrait être responsable de cet écart. Dans un cadre théorique avec complémentarité stratégique entre accumulation de capital humain et innovation, on montrera que la possibilité d'émigrer augmente les incitations à s'éduquer dans le pays relativement moins développé. Au même temps, cette « fuite des cerveaux » nuit à l'innovation technologique. Par conséquent, la croissance pourrait en être affectée (négativement) et, contrairement à certains résultats établis par la littérature existante, la migration ne serait pas susceptible de remplacer les subsides à l'éducation.

Type
Research Article
Copyright
Copyright © Université catholique de Louvain, Institut de recherches économiques et sociales 2008 

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

Footnotes

CES - Centre d'Economie de la Sorbonne; 106-112, bd. de I'Hôpital, F-75013 Paris (France). Ph.: +33 (0)1 44078350; fax: +33 (0)1 44078231. E-mail: [email protected].

*

I want to thank David de la Croix for his guidance and for many useful comments on earlier drafts. I am also grateful to Antonio Minniti and Luca Panaccione for insightful discussions. Finally, several comments and suggestions provided by two anonymous referees proved extremely useful to improve the paper. All remaining errors are, of course, under my own responsibility. Financial support from the Belgian French-Speaking Community in the framework of the ARC Project “New Macroeconomic Perspectives on Development” (Grant ARC 03/08-302) is very gratefully acknowledged.

References

Acemoglu, D. (1994). “Search in the labour market, incomplete contracts and growth”, CEPR Discussion Paper no. 1026.Google Scholar
Barro, R.J. and Lee, J.-W. (2000). “International data on educational attainment: updates and implications”, CID Working Paper no. 42. [Data set available at: http://www.cid.harvard.edu/ciddata/ciddata.html/]Google Scholar
Beine, M., Docquier, F. and Rapoport, H. (2001). “Brain drain and economic growth: theory and evidence”, Journal of Development Economics 64, 275289.Google Scholar
Cooper, R., and John, A. (1988). “Coordinating coordination failures in Keynesian models”, Quarterly Journal of Economics 103 (3), 441463.Google Scholar
Cozzi, G. (2003). “The self-fulfilling international allocation of innovation, inequality, and education”, mimeo.Google Scholar
Docquier, F. and Marfouk, A. (2006). “International migration by education attainment, 1990-2000”; in Ozden, C., and Schifi, M. (eds.): International Migration, Remittances & the Brain Drain, World Bank and Palgrave Macmillan.Google Scholar
Docquier, F., Faye, O. and Pestieau, P. (2008). “Is migration a good substitute for education subsidies?”, Journal of Development Economics 86, 263276.Google Scholar
European Commission (2003, 2005). European Innovation Scoreboard, Cordis, Luxembourg. [Available on-line at: http://trendchart.cordis.lu/]Google Scholar
Furman, J.L., Porter, M.E. and Stern, S. (2002). “The determinants of national innovative capacity”, Research Policy 31, 899933.Google Scholar
Janeba, E. (1998). “Tax competition in imperfectly competitive markets”, Journal of International Economics 44, 135153.Google Scholar
Kahn, B.Z. and Sokoloff, K.L. (2004). “Institutions and technological innovation during early economic growth: evidence from the great inventors of the United States, 1790-1930”, NBER Working Paper no. 10966.Google Scholar
Mountford, A. (1997). “Can a brain drain be good for growth in the source economy?”, Journal of Development Economics 53, 287303.Google Scholar
Mulkay, B., Hall, B.H. and Mairesse, J. (2000). “Firm level investment and R&D in France and the United States: a comparison”, NBER Working Paper 8038.Google Scholar
Redding, S. (1996). “The low-skill, low-quality trap: strategic complementarities between human capital and R&D”, Economic Journal 106 (435), 458470.Google Scholar
Stark, O. and Wang, Y. (2002). “Inducing human capital formation: migration as a substitute for subsidies”, Journal of Public Economics 86, 2946.Google Scholar
Wilson, J.D. and Wildasin, D.E. (2004). “Capital tax competition: bane or boon”, Journal of Public Economics 88, 10651091.Google Scholar