Hostname: page-component-586b7cd67f-g8jcs Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-11-25T08:27:16.806Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Dynamic Advertising Effects in A Generalised Firm

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  17 August 2016

Get access

Extract

Optimal advertising expenditures in static models of the firm generally satisfy the well-known Dorfman-Steiner conditions (Dorfman and Steiner) under a variety of objective functions (see Peel), including that of the « Illyrian » labour-managed firm as perceived by Meade and Vanek, (see Ireland and Law). If advertising has dynamic effects then the generalisation of such results as that of Nerlove and Arrow to firms with objectives other than pure profit maximisation is considered doubtful by at least one writer (Peel). The purpose of the present note is to argue that there is unlikely to be any fundamental difference in advertising policy between a « generalised » firm such as a labour-managed firm and a traditional profit-maximising firrn after provision has been made to adjust for scale differences (factor input levels).

Peel contrasts Nerlove and Arrow’s result for the profit-maximising firm with the result for the same model but with an objective function of maximising the discounted stream of profits per worker or income per worker.

Type
Research Article
Copyright
Copyright © Université catholique de Louvain, Institut de recherches économiques et sociales 1979 

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

REFERENCES

[1] Cowling, K.G., (1972) « Optimality in Firms’ Advertising Policies : an Empirical Analysis » in Cowling, K.G. (ed.), Market Structure and Corporate Behaviour (Gray-Mills, 1972).Google Scholar
[2] Dorfman, R. and Steiner, P.O., (1954) « Optimal Advertising and Optimal Quality », American Economic Review, 44.Google Scholar
[3] Gould, J., (1970) « Diffusion Processes and Optimal Advertising Policy » in Phelps, E.S. (ed.) Microeconomic Foundations of Employment and Inflation Theory, (W. Norton).Google Scholar
[4] Ireland, N.J., (1973) « The Dorfman-Steiner Rule and Bandwagon Effects », Zeitschrift für Nationalökonomie, 33.Google Scholar
[5] Ireland, N.J. and Law, P.J., (1977) « Advertising and the Labour Managed Firm », Journal of Industrial Economics Vol. 25.10.2307/2098193Google Scholar
[6] Jacquemin, A.P., (1971) « Product Differentiation and Optimal Advertising Policy : A Dynamic Analysis », Working Paper No. 7107, Louvain : Institut des Sciences Economiques.Google Scholar
[7] Jacquemin, A.P. and Thisse, J., (1972) « Strategy of the Firm and Market Structure : An Application of Optimal Control Theory » in Cowling, K.G. (ed.) Market Structure and Corporate Behaviour, (Gray-Mills, 1972).Google Scholar
[8] Meade, J.E., (1972) « The Theory of Labour Managed Firms and of Profit-sharing », Economic Journal, 82 (suppl.).10.2307/2229945Google Scholar
[9] Nerlove, M. and Arrow, K., (1972) « Optimal Advertising Policy under Dynamic Conditions », Economica, 29.Google Scholar
[10] Peel, D.A., (1977) « The Non-uniqueness of the Dorfman-Steiner Condition : A note », Economica, 40.Google Scholar
[11] Peel, D.A., (1975) « Optimal Advertising Rules when Advertising acts as a Capital Good », Recherches Economiques de Louvain, Vol. 44 n° 2.Google Scholar
[12] Tsurumi, H. and Tsurumi, Y., (1971) « Simultaneous Determination of Market Share and Advertising Expenditure under Dynamic Conditions : The Case of a Firm within the Japanese Pharmaceutical Industry », Economic Studies Quarterly, 22.Google Scholar
[13] Vanek, J., (1970) « The General Theory of Labour-managed Market Economies », (Cornell University Press, Ithaca.Google Scholar