Hostname: page-component-586b7cd67f-dsjbd Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-11-26T04:08:55.773Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Conflict and cooperation in paranoia: a large-scale behavioural experiment

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  17 October 2017

N. J. Raihani
Affiliation:
Department of Experimental Psychology, University College London, London, UK
V. Bell*
Affiliation:
Division of Psychiatry, University College London, London, UK South London and Maudsley NHS Foundation Trust, London, UK
*
Author for correspondence: V. Bell, E-mail: [email protected]
Rights & Permissions [Opens in a new window]

Abstract

Background

Paranoia involves thoughts and beliefs about the harmful intent of others but the social consequences have been much less studied. We investigated whether paranoia predicts maladaptive social behaviour in terms of cooperative and punitive behaviour using experimental game theory paradigms, and examined whether reduced cooperation is best explained in terms of distrust as previous studies have claimed.

Methods

We recruited a large population sample (N = 2132) online. All participants completed the Green et al. Paranoid Thoughts Scale and (i) a Dictator Game and (ii) an Ultimatum Game, the former with an option for costly punishment. Following distrust-based accounts, we predicted highly paranoid people would make higher offers when the outcome depended on receiving a positive response from their partner (Ultimatum Game) but no difference when the partner's response was irrelevant (Dictator Game). We also predicted paranoia would increase punitive responses. Predictions were pre-registered in advance of data collection. Data and materials are open access.

Results

Highly paranoid participants actually made lower offers than non-paranoid participants both in the Dictator Game and in the Ultimatum Game. Paranoia positively predicted punitive responses.

Conclusions

These findings suggest that distrust is not the best explanation for reduced cooperation in paranoia and alternative explanations, such as increased self-interest, may apply. However, the tendency to attribute harmful intent to partners was important in motivating punitive responses. These results highlight differing motivations underlying adverse social behaviour in paranoia and suggest that accounts based solely on the presenting features of paranoia may need to be rethought.

Type
Original Articles
Creative Commons
Creative Common License - CCCreative Common License - BY
This is an Open Access article, distributed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution licence (http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/), which permits unrestricted re-use, distribution, and reproduction in any medium, provided the original work is properly cited.
Copyright
Copyright © Cambridge University Press 2017

Introduction

Paranoia lies on a continuum, ranging from low-level paranoid thoughts to frank paranoid delusions that centre on concerns about others’ harmful intent (Freeman & Garety, Reference Freeman and Garety2000). Paranoia has typically been investigated using psychometric measures or tests that measure cognitive biases, reflecting the common focus on individualistic processes involved in evaluating personal threat (Freeman & Garety, Reference Freeman and Garety2014). However, relatively little research has explored social interaction despite adverse social behaviour being a common characteristic of paranoia (Freeman, Reference Freeman2016).

Paranoia strongly relates to processes involved in social decision-making and cooperation (Boyer et al. Reference Boyer, Firat and van Leeuwen2015; Patrzyk & Takáč, Reference Patrzyk and Takáč2017) and there is now a nascent literature investigating paranoia using game theoretic paradigms. These paradigms involve social interactions where cooperative or non-cooperative decisions determine each participant's economic payoff (Camerer, Reference Camerer2003). These tasks are particularly relevant to paranoid concerns because they allow for cooperation and mutual benefit but also allow for harm, in the form of economic costs, and cheating, by gaining resources at the expense of the partner. These approaches therefore have the potential to reveal how paranoia affects social behaviour, and – because they are designed to selectively isolate specific social motivations – can help test and develop psychological theories.

Paranoia and cooperative behaviour

Previous game theory studies report that paranoia predicts reduced cooperation in the Prisoner's Dilemma Game (Ellett et al. Reference Ellett2013) and reduced investments in the Trust Game (Fett et al. Reference Fett2012, Reference Fett2016; Gromann et al. Reference Gromann2013). These findings were interpreted as due to increased levels of ‘distrust’ in paranoia. Nevertheless, alternative explanations for reduced cooperation are possible. Reduced cooperation could reflect doubts about the partner's competence rather than fears about their intentions. Alternatively, it might stem from players’ increased desire to maximise their own payoffs (hereafter ‘self-interest’, used in the non-pejorative economic sense) since, in both the one shot Prisoner's Dilemma and Trust Games the individually payoff-maximising option is to defect (choose the non-cooperative option), regardless of how the partner behaves. To disentangle these motives, a comparison with a situation where the personal incentive to defect is still the same but where the partner's response is irrelevant in deciding payoffs is needed. In these so-called ‘non-strategic’ scenarios, where the partner's response is not a concern, self-interest rather than distrust is a more parsimonious explanation for reduced cooperation.

To test whether paranoia predicts reduced cooperative behaviour in the presence and absence of strategic concerns, we recruited participants to play the Dictator Game (Kahneman et al. Reference Kahneman, Knetsch and Thaler1986) and the Ultimatum Game (Güth et al. Reference Güth, Schmittberger and Schwarze1982). The Dictator Game is a non-strategic game where the ‘dictator’ decides how to split a pot of money with their partner (the ‘receiver’) who must accept any donation. Dictator donations therefore represent a relatively unbiased estimate of cooperative tendency in the absence of strategic concerns. In contrast, the Ultimatum Game is a strategic scenario where the responder decides whether to accept the proposer's offer – in which case both players are paid according to the proposed split, or can reject the offer – meaning neither player receives any money. To ensure a payoff, the proposer needs to judge what is likely to be an acceptable offer to the responder. These games provide a helpful contrast, allowing a test of how social decision-making differs in paranoia between two similar scenarios that vary only in whether one player needs to take into account the other's intentions when making a decision.

The Ultimatum Game also offers another method to disambiguate whether reduced cooperation stems from self-interest or distrust in a manner that is not possible in the Prisoner's Dilemma Game (where defecting could reflect either motive). Ultimatum Game rejections to unfair offers impose greater costs on the proposer than the responder, and leave open the possibility that the responder could be motivated by intent to harm the proposer. Indeed, previous research has shown that a perception that the responder will reject offers leads to more generous proposals (Slembeck, Reference Slembeck1999). If reduced cooperation in paranoia stems from over-attributing harmful intentions (thereby reducing trust), we would expect paranoid participants to make more generous offers as proposers in the Ultimatum Game in order to counter what they perceive as higher levels of harmful intent in the responders. By contrast, if Ultimatum Game offers only reflect self-interest (i.e. where participants offer the lowest amount they expect the partner to accept), then we would not expect Ultimatum Game offers to vary with paranoia.

Paranoia and punitive behaviour

Paranoid attributions of harmful intent should not only manifest in reduced cooperation but also increased punitive behaviour. Punishment occurs when one individual pays a cost to impose a reciprocal cost on a cheating partner (Raihani et al. Reference Raihani, Thornton and Bshary2012). Previous research has established that decisions to take punitive action involve a judgement of the severity of harm as well as a judgment of whether the harm was intended (Carlsmith et al. Reference Carlsmith, Darley and Robinson2002; Cushman et al. Reference Cushman2009). A recent study confirmed that paranoia leads to increased levels of harmful intent attribution to partners in the Dictator Game where the actual motivation underlying dictator decisions is ambiguous (Raihani & Bell, Reference Raihani and Bell2017a). Therefore in this study, we expected these paranoid attributions to manifest behaviourally – by predicting an increased willingness to punish. We tested this prediction using two behavioural measures. In the Dictator Game, we introduced an unannounced opportunity for receivers to pay a small amount to impose a larger fine on the dictator after the dictator's decision. In the Ultimatum Game, rejecting offers can be interpreted as costly punishment since it involves incurring a cost to impose a larger cost on an unfair partner (Slembeck, Reference Slembeck1999; but see Yamagishi et al. Reference Yamagishi2009). As such, we predicted paranoia would also predict increased rejection of Ultimatum Game offers.

Study aims summary

We predicted highly paranoid people would make higher offers when the final outcome depended on a positive response from their partner (in the Ultimatum Game) but no difference when they believed that the partner's response was irrelevant (in the Dictator Game). We also predicted paranoia would increase punitive responses in the Dictator Game and rejections in the Ultimatum Game.

In contrast to studies which have recruited clinical participants with psychiatric diagnoses but have relatively low statistical power, we recruited a large sample that naturally includes people in the clinical range (Shapiro et al. Reference Shapiro, Chandler and Mueller2013) and tested these predictions using analyses, which we pre-registered prior to collecting data.

Methods

Participants

This project was approved by the UCL Ethics Board (project 3720/001). Participation was voluntary and informed consent was obtained from all participants prior to taking part.

We recruited 3217 US-based participants to complete the Green et al. Paranoid Thoughts Scale (GPTS; Green et al. Reference Green2008) via the online crowdsourcing platform Amazon Mechanical Turk (MTurk, http://www.mturk.com). GPTS responses were collected in November–December 2016. Participants played two Dictator Games without punishment (Raihani & Bell, Reference Raihani and Bell2017a) in December 2016. These data were published in Raihani & Bell (Reference Raihani and Bell2017a) and are not presented here. We successfully recalled 2132 (979 males; 1153 females) of the original 3217 participants in January–February 2017 to take part in the present study. Participants ranged in age from 18 to 80 years old (mean: 38.0 ± 0.26). Paranoia scores were unavailable for 11 participants, because the worker ID entered did not match any of the worker IDs in our existing database. Of the 2120 participants for whom we had paranoia scores, the mean score was 50.7 ± 0.49 (range: 32–160), compared with a mean of 48.8 ± 1.00 from the non-clinical sample in the original Green et al. (Reference Green2008) study. The mean GPTS score for clinical patients with paranoid delusions in original study was 101.9; in our sample 108 participants (5%) scored above the Green et al. clinical mean (compared with 3% of non-clinical participants in the original Green et al. study).

Data were collected in two waves with a 15-day interval to reduce interference between tasks. In each wave, participants played both the Dictator Game and the Ultimatum Game (game order presentation was counter-balanced via random assignment across participants). In one wave, participants played as both the Dictator Game dictator and the Ultimatum Game proposer, while in the other wave they played as the Dictator Game receiver and the Ultimatum Game responder (see description below). The order in which participants were recruited to waves of the study was also counter-balanced. In each wave, participants received a payment of $0.20 for taking part, plus up to $1.10 depending on the outcome of the games. In total 1187 of the recalled participants took part in just one wave of the study, while 945 were successfully recruited to both waves.

The experiment

In each wave, participants were truthfully informed that they would be assigned two different partners for each task, to reduce the potential for reciprocity or retaliation across the tasks. Most participants reported being confident or highly confident that they were interacting with a real partner (see online Supplementary Information). Participants made their decisions in isolation and partners were subsequently assigned via ex-post matching (c.f. Raihani et al. Reference Raihani, Mace and Lamba2013). Using this method, decisions are stored and retrieved when the matched partner participates, and so although they involve genuine interaction, they do not occur in real time. Participants were required to correctly answer multiple-choice comprehension questions to ensure that they understood the contingencies of the different tasks (see online Supplementary Information for game instructions). Participants that failed a multiple-choice comprehension question were given a second attempt to answer correctly (using a free-form answer so that they could not select the correct option via trial and error). Participants who still answered incorrectly (46/1522, 3.0%, in the Dictator Game and 88/1544, 5.7%, in the Ultimatum Game answered at least one question incorrectly) could participate but we include incomprehension as a variable in analyses.

In the Dictator Game, participants were cast as either the dictator (in one wave) or the receiver (in the other wave). Note that loaded terms such as dictator and receiver were not used in the instructions seen by participants. Dictators were given $0.55 and informed that the receiver had been given $0.05. Dictators could then choose to send any division (from $0.00 to $0.55, in $0.05 increments) to the receiver. Importantly, dictators were not aware of the possibility that they could be punished until after they had made their donation. This was essential because we wished to collect a measure of generosity that was unbiased by strategic considerations. Receivers were informed of the starting bonuses of both players and the fact that the dictator could choose how much of a $0.55 starting bonus to send to them. Receivers could sacrifice $0.05 of their bonus to punish the dictator, by subtracting $0.15 from the dictator's bonus. Using the strategy method, receivers stated what donations from the dictator (from $0.00 to $0.55) they would punish – and were told that their decision would be executed based on the actual donation decision of the dictator. Previous studies have shown that this method is a reliable technique for eliciting behavioural responses in similar tasks (Brandts & Charness, Reference Brandts and Charness2011; Fischbacher et al. Reference Fischbacher, Gächter and Quercia2012), although it might yield conservative estimates of punitive tendency (Brandts & Charness, Reference Brandts and Charness2011).

In the Ultimatum Game, participants played as proposers in one wave and in responders in the other wave. Proposers were given $0.50 and instructed to offer any share of this endowment (from $0.00 to $0.50, in $0.05 increments) to the responder. Proposers were also informed that the responder had veto power over the division, such that if the responder rejected the offer then both players would get nothing. Responders were instructed to indicate which offers they would accept and which they would reject, using the strategy method as above. In doing so, we determined the responder's minimum acceptable offer (MAO). Responders were informed that their decision to accept or reject the proposer's offer would be implemented based on their MAO.

Predictions

We specified eight a priori predictions, which were pre-registered before data collection on AsPredicted.org – https://aspredicted.org/mc5vz.pdf – and are included in the online Supplementary Information. We report one deviation for all analyses from the pre-registered analysis and two deviations related to data coding. The overall deviation was to include ‘failed comprehension’ as an explanatory variable in all models. Originally, we intended to exclude participants who failed comprehension checks but, to reduce the possibility of systematic bias from excluding participants, we used responses from all participants and controlled for the effect of failing at least one comprehension question in the analyses. All models were checked for robustness when failed comprehenders were excluded and discrepancies between the two approaches are reported.

Data coding deviations relate to the analyses for predictions 6 and 7 below and were due to non-monotonic strategies in the reported MAOs and punishment thresholds for some participants (N = 72/1551 in Ultimatum Game and 104/1551 in Dictator Game). Participants could display a non-monotonic strategy by, for example, stating that they would accept a proposer's offer of $0.20 but reject an offer of $0.50. Similarly, a non-monotonic punishment strategy would be implied if participants said they would punish a dictator donation of $0.20 but not $0.15. Non-monotonic MAOs in the Ultimatum Game can reflect advantageous inequity aversion (Brosnan & de Waal, Reference Brosnan and de Waal2014), though other explanations are also possible (e.g. Hennig-Schmidt et al. Reference Hennig-Schmidt, Li and Yang2008). Since we did not anticipate non-monotonic strategies, we decided that a more conservative approach for P6 and P7 would be to assess whether participants rejected any non-zero proposer offer or punished any dictator donation (rather than analysing responses to all offers as originally envisaged).

P1: Dictator Game donations will be lower than Ultimatum Game offers

To check the pattern of results in the whole sample matched established findings (Camerer, Reference Camerer2003), we ran a paired, two-tailed Wilcoxon signed rank test comparing Dictator Game donations with Ultimatum Game offers. N = 1529 participants.

P2 & P3: Dictator donations will not vary with paranoia but Ultimatum Game offers will increase with paranoia

We ran two models, one with Dictator Game donation as the response term and one with Ultimatum Game offer as the response term. These response terms were each parameterised as a 7-level ordered categorical response term in two cumulative link models (CLM, package: ordinal; Christensen, Reference Christensen2015), with the terms ‘Age’, ‘Paranoia’, ‘Order’ (0 = played as DG dictator first; 1 = played as UG proposer first), ‘Failed Comprehension’ (0 = no comprehension questions wrong; 1 = at least 1 comprehension question wrong), ‘Gender’ (0 = female; 1 = male) and ‘Wave’ (1/2) set as potential explanatory terms. These response terms were included in all statistical models. Data were missing for seven participants, so both models are based on N = 1522.

P4: Paranoia will be inversely associated with Dictator Game punishment threshold

Punishment threshold was defined as the highest dictator donation that the participant said they would punish. We had responses from 1544 participants. Of these, 859 participants who did not punish any donation were excluded, leaving 685 responses for analysis. As above, punishment threshold was a 7-level ordered categorical variable, with higher values indicating increased punitive tendency (i.e. a lower punishment threshold). We used a CLM to investigate the factors explaining the punishment threshold.

P5: Paranoia will be associated with higher MAO in the Ultimatum Game

The MAO was specified as the minimum offer that a responder said they would accept in the Ultimatum Game. MAO was a 7-level ordered categorical variable and was set as the response term in a CLM. N = 1544 responses.

P6: Paranoia will be positively associated with willingness to punish at least one dictator donation

Willingness to punish was a dummy variable where 0 = would not punish any dictator donation and 1 = would punish at least one dictator donation. This dummy variable was set as the response term in a Generalised Linear Model (GLM) with binomial error structure. N = 1544 responses.

P7: Paranoia will be positively associated with tendency to reject at least one Ultimatum Game offer

We specified whether participants accepted all offers (=0) or rejected at least one offer in the Ultimatum Game (=1) and set this dummy variable as the response term in a GLM with binomial error structure. N = 1544 responses.

P8: We do not know whether participants will be more willing to reject Ultimatum Game offers than they are to punish Dictator Game donations

To test whether the Ultimatum Game rejection threshold (defined as MAO – $0.05) was significantly different to the Dictator Game punishment threshold, we first converted these threshold amounts into proportions of the total stake, to account for the different stake sizes across the tasks ($0.55 and $0.50 in the Dictator and Ultimatum Game, respectively). We then ran a paired Wilcoxon signed rank test to see whether participants showed different thresholds for rejecting (Ultimatum Game) or punishing (Dictator Game) offers, respectively. This test is based on all 638 cases for participants who indicated that they would punish a Dictator Game donation and reject an Ultimatum Game offer.

Statistical approach

We used multi-model selection with model averaging (Burnham & Anderson, Reference Burnham and Anderson2002; Grueber et al. Reference Grueber2011) to compare the explanatory power of different input variables. Continuous input variables were standardised (Gelman, Reference Gelman2008) and binary input variables were centred, so estimates can be considered on the same scale. Under this approach, we first specify a global model, containing all fixed effects and interactions that were specified in the pre-registered predictions. All possible models deriving from this global model are compared, resulting in a top model set, which contains all the models that are within 2 AICc units of the ‘best’ model (that with the lowest AICc value). Parameter estimates are obtained by averaging across this top model set. This approach therefore incorporates the uncertainty over the true parameter estimate when many models have similar levels of support. All estimates reported here are full model averages, which provide conservative estimates for terms that are not included in all the top models. All data and code are available at Raihani & Bell (Reference Raihani and Bell2017b) https://figshare.com/s/c5bbc8330551b14bc91e.

Unplanned analysis

We report one unplanned analysis, motivated by comments from an anonymous reviewer, to establish whether the effect of paranoia on punishment decision in the Dictator Game was mediated by the participant's tendency to attribute harmful intentions. This was achieved by identifying participants who had participated in a previous Dictator Game reported in Raihani & Bell (Reference Raihani and Bell2017a) where harmful intent attributions were recorded. See online Supplementary Information for full details.

Results

Supported predictions

P1: Dictator Game donations will be lower than Ultimatum Game offers

The mean dictator donation was $0.13 ± 0.00, compared with a mean Ultimatum Game offer of $0.21 ± 0.00. Thus, dictator donations were significantly lower than Ultimatum Game offers, as predicted (Wilcoxon signed rank test, V = 353 700, p < 0.001; Fig. 1a).

Fig. 1. Effect of paranoia on (a) DG and UG offers made and (b) amount offered that the subject rejected (UG) or punished (DG). DG donations are shown in black and UG offers are shown in red. Data are raw means and standard errors and do not control for other terms included in the statistical models. Where no standard error bars are shown, this is because the standard error of the mean was 0.00 when rounded. For visualisation (and to calculate the raw means) paranoia was converted to a 5-level categorical variable, where 1 ⩽ 35, 35 < 2 ⩽ 60, 60 < 3⩽85, 85 < 4 ⩽ 110, and 110 < 5 ⩽ 160.

P4: Paranoia will be inversely associated with Dictator Game punishment threshold

A total of 685/1544 (44.4%) receivers chose to punish at least one dictator donation. The mean threshold below which dictator donations were punished was $0.18 ± 0.01 (i.e. ~33% of the stake). As predicted, paranoia resulted in lower punishment thresholds [estimate: −0.86, confidence interval (CI) −1.16 to −0.57; Table 1; Fig. 1b]. Women also had lower punishment thresholds than men and threshold decreased with age (Table 1). There were no meaningful effects of game order or wave on punishment thresholds, although we did find that failing comprehension checks was associated with a lowered punishment threshold (Table 1). Excluding failed comprehenders (n = 66; 9.6%) does not qualitatively change the results.

Table 1. Factors affecting punishment threshold

Punishment threshold was parameterised as a 7-level ordinal categorical variable, where lower levels indicate increased willingness to punish higher DG offers. For binary input variables, the reference category is given in parentheses. All continuous input variables were standardized and binary input variables were centred. Thus, estimates can be interpreted as being on the same scale. Importance is the probability that the term in question is a component of the true best model.

P5: Paranoia will be associated with higher MAO in the Ultimatum Game

The mean MAO was $0.12 ± 0.00 (i.e. 24% of stake). Paranoia was associated with marginally higher MAO (estimate: 0.15; Fig. 1b), though the CIs associated with this estimate include zero (CI −0.07 to 0.37). Men demanded higher shares of the stake than women, as did participants that played the Ultimatum Game before the Dictator Game (Table 2). There were no meaningful effects of age or wave on MAO. Finally, failed comprehenders (n = 88, 5.7%) had lower MAOs than those who passed all comprehension checks. When failed comprehenders are excluded, then we detect a robust positive effect of paranoia on MAO (estimate: 0.22; CI 0.04–0.41).

Table 2. Factors affecting minimal acceptable offer (MAO) in the Ultimatum Game

MAO was parameterised as a 7-level ordinal categorical variable, where higher levels indicate increased willingness to reject UG offers. For binary input variables, the reference category is given in parentheses. All continuous input variables were standardized and binary input variables were centred. Thus, estimates can be interpreted as being on the same scale. Importance is the probability that the term in question is a component of the true best model.

P6: Paranoia will be positively associated with willingness to punish at least one Dictator Game donation

Paranoia was positively associated with willingness to punish at least one dictator donation (estimate: 0.48, CI 0.27–0.70; online Supplementary Table S1). Furthermore, punishment was more common among males (estimate: 0.38; CI 0.16–0.59), among participants who failed comprehension check(s) (estimate: 1.38, CI 0.87–1.90), and among participants who played in the role of Ultimatum Game responder before they made their punishment decision in the Dictator Game (estimate: 0.62, CI 0.41–0.83). We detected no meaningful effects of age or wave on the willingness to punish (online Supplementary Table S1). Excluding participants who failed comprehension checks does not qualitatively change these results.

Unsupported predictions

P2: Dictator Game donations will not vary with paranoia

Paranoia had a negative effect on dictator donations (estimate: −0.29, CI −0.49 to −0.10; Fig. 1a). In addition, male dictators made lower donations than females (estimate: −0.37, CI −0.56 to −0.18; Table 3). Older participants and those that played the Dictator Game before the Ultimatum Game made higher donations (Table 3). In a separate, unregistered analysis, we found a positive effect of paranoia on the tendency to fail at least one comprehension check (GLM, estimate = 0.02, CI 0.00–0.03). Thus, the negative effect of paranoia on dictator donations emerges even though failed comprehenders were more – not less – generous in the task. Excluding failed comprehenders from analyses does not change these results qualitatively.

Table 3. Factors affecting Dictator Game offer

DG offer was parameterised as a 7-level ordinal categorical variable. For binary input variables, the reference category is given in parentheses. All continuous input variables were standardized and binary input variables were centred. Thus, estimates can be interpreted as being on the same scale. Importance is the probability that the term in question is a component of the true best model.

P3: Ultimatum Game offers will increase with paranoia

Paranoid participants made lower Ultimatum Game offers (estimate: −0.32, CI −0.53 to −0.11; Table 4; Fig. 1a). As with dictator donations, older participants made higher Ultimatum Game offers (estimate: 0.34, CI 0.11–0.56) but we detected no meaningful effects of gender or game order on offer (Table 4). There was no effect of failing a comprehension check on Ultimatum Game offers so we did not conduct further analyses where failed comprehenders were excluded.

Table 4. Factors affecting Ultimatum Game offer

UG offer was parameterised as a 7-level ordinal categorical variable. For binary input variables, the reference category is given in parentheses. All continuous input variables were standardised and binary input variables were centred. Thus, estimates can be interpreted as being on the same scale. Importance is the probability that the term in question is a component of the true best model.

P7: Paranoia will be positively associated with tendency to reject at least one Ultimatum Game offer

There was no meaningful effect of paranoia on tendency to reject at least one offer in the Ultimatum Game (estimate: 0.01, CI −0.13 to 0.15; online Supplementary Table S2). Men (estimate: 0.35, CI 0.08–0.62), and participants that played the Ultimatum Game first (online Supplementary Table S2), were more likely to reject at least one offer. By contrast, older participants and failed comprehenders were less likely to reject at least one offer (online Supplementary Table S2). Excluding failed comprehenders from this model does not qualitatively affect the results.

Exploratory analysis results

P8: We do not know whether participants will be more willing to reject Ultimatum Game offers than they are to punish Dictator Game donations

Participants were more willing to punish dictator donations than they were to reject Ultimatum Game offers of the same proportional value (Wilcoxon signed rank test, V = 100 950, p = 0.03). Specifically, the average maximum dictator donation that was punished was $0.16 (30 ± 1% of the stake), whereas the mean maximum Ultimatum Game rejection was $0.13 (25 ± 1% of the stake).

Unplanned analysis results

Punishment decisions were significantly mediated by a tendency to make harmful intent attributions although there was also a direct effect of paranoia. See online Supplementary Information for all details.

Discussion

We used a large, non-clinical sample to explore the association between paranoia and (i) cooperation and (ii) willingness to punish in social interactions.

Paranoia and cooperative behaviour

Previous work has suggested that reduced cooperation in paranoia could be explained by distrust (Fett et al. Reference Fett2012; Ellett et al. Reference Ellett2013; Gromann et al. Reference Gromann2013; although see Fett et al. Reference Fett2016). Our findings suggest that distrust might not be the sole explanation, as we found that paranoia predicted lower generosity in the Dictator Game, where trust is not a strategic consideration. Moreover, in the Ultimatum Game – where distrust should predict higher offers – we found that paranoia was unexpectedly associated with lower offers. Our results suggest that reduced cooperation in paranoia reflects increased self-interest. Importantly, self-interest here is used in the economic sense of maximising individual payoffs (rather than the everyday sense suggesting ‘selfishness’).

Paranoia and punitive behaviour

We expected that paranoia would positively predict punitive tendency. Our data mostly support our predictions: paranoia positively predicted the tendency to punish at all in the Dictator Game, and to punish more generous donations. Moreover, in an unplanned mediation analysis, the effect of paranoia on willingness to punish dictator donations was mediated by a tendency to attribute harmful intentions, along with a direct effect of paranoia.

In the Ultimatum Game, paranoia only reliably predicted punitive tendency when participants that failed at least one comprehension check were excluded from the analyses. Furthermore, unlike the Dictator Game, the tendency to reject at least one offer in the Ultimatum Game was not predicted by paranoia. This discrepancy in the results might stem from the fact that rejecting any offer over $0.05 in the Ultimatum Game was costlier than punishing in the Dictator Game (which cost $0.05 regardless of the dictator's donation). Moreover, the fee to fine ratio of punishment was always 1:3 in the Dictator Game but was variable in the Ultimatum Game from 1:9 (in the case where responders rejected an offer of $0.05) to 1:1 (in the case where responders rejected an offer of $0.25). These differences in the cost of punishing and the potential efficacy of punishment across the two games might help explain the finding that players were more willing to punish dictator donations than to reject Ultimatum Game offers, and might also have reduced the size of any effect of paranoia on Ultimatum Game rejections.

Implications for theories of paranoia

Our results suggest that the pattern of reduced cooperation in paranoia better reflects self-interest rather than distrust. Importantly, self-interest is a proximal motivation and various other processes may underlie it. For example, maximising immediate payoffs can manifest as being less willing to invest in social interactions (Stevens & Hauser, Reference Stevens and Hauser2004) and may be an adaptive strategy when living in environments where resource availability is scarce and/or unpredictable (Frankenhuis et al. Reference Frankenhuis, Panchanathan and Nettle2016). The fact that paranoia is associated with a history of serious adverse life events (Cristóbal-Narváez et al. Reference Cristóbal-Narváez2016) would support this explanation. Alternatively, Andreoni (Reference Andreoni1990) and Gromann et al. (Reference Gromann2013) have suggested that reduced cooperation in paranoia may result from reduced subjective rewards from social interactions. These explanations are not mutually exclusive. Previous research has suggested that adverse life events raise the risk of reward system dysregulation later in life (review in Howes & Murray, Reference Howes and Murray2014) suggesting a potential proximal mechanism for the impact of distal developmental experiences. On the basis of non-clinical studies, Fehr & Schmidt (Reference Fehr and Schmidt1999) have argued that altered fairness preferences can be drivers of reduced cooperation and this is a plausible but yet unexplored approach to paranoia.

The mediation analysis showed that the tendency to attribute harmful intent to partners, as measured on a previous task, was a factor motivating punishment decisions, alongside a direct effect of paranoia. It is possible that punitive behaviour in this study reflected increased levels of hostility (Coid et al. Reference Coid2016). However, it is important to note that punishment as conceptualised here does not necessarily imply anti-social or aggressive tendencies. Indeed, willingness to invest in punishment can provide benefits in the form of increased within-group cooperation (Yamagishi, Reference Yamagishi1986) and we note that the factors that encourage punitive behaviour are likely to vary across different scenarios (see Raihani & McAuliffe, Reference Raihani and McAuliffe2012; Bone & Raihani, Reference Bone and Raihani2015; Raihani & Bshary, Reference Raihani and Bshary2015; Krasnow et al. Reference Krasnow2016).

Freeman & Garety (Reference Freeman and Garety2014) conceptualise paranoia as being maintained by a feedback loop of behaviour, interpretation and emotion, suggesting a dynamic system in which different motivations may apply depending on the incentive structure of specific situations. We found reduced cooperation and increased punitive behaviour in paranoia but suggest that the motivations are likely to be different in each case. We suggest here that models of paranoia need to include not only common factors but also the dynamics and contextual modifiers of social situations to fully understand how paranoia manifests in social behaviour. Considering that negative social interactions are themselves likely to act as maintaining factors for paranoia, identifying these cycles of maintenance may be important for identifying points of intervention.

Limitations

The GPTS asks about paranoid ideation over the prior month and participants completed the experimental tasks in the subsequent weeks. It is possible that levels of paranoid thinking may have altered during this time, although given the good test-retest reliability of the measure (Green et al. Reference Green2008), we presume this effect would be small. Additionally, we recruited our sample from an online platform. Previous research has shown that online participants do not produce systematically different responses to other participants (Horton et al. Reference Horton, Rand and Zeckhauser2011; Paolacci & Chandler, Reference Paolacci and Chandler2014; Hauser & Schwarz, Reference Hauser and Schwarz2016; Arechar et al. Reference Arechar, Gächter and Molleman2017). The current study supports this position. The mean and distribution of GPTS scores closely reflect findings from the original Green et al. (Reference Green2008) validation study. Dictator Game donations were 23.6% of the stake compared with the mean of 28% reported in the Engel (Reference Engel2011) meta-analysis, and mean Ultimatum Game offers were 42%, compared with previously reported values of 30–40% (Camerer, Reference Camerer2003). Although stake sizes on MTurk are often smaller than those used in the laboratory, they are designed to reflect similar hourly rates of pay. Moreover, stake size has been found not to significantly affect behaviour in the Dictator Game or the Ultimatum Game (Camerer, Reference Camerer2003; Raihani et al. Reference Raihani, Mace and Lamba2013). Although participants recruited online tend to be more representative than student samples or community samples from college towns (Buhrmester et al. Reference Buhrmester, Kwang and Gosling2011), online samples also tend to be younger, less-likely to report full-time employment, and more likely to experience social anxiety than the general population (Chandler & Shapiro, Reference Chandler and Shapiro2016) and this needs to be borne in mind when interpreting these results.

Supplementary material

The supplementary material for this article can be found at https://doi.org/10.1017/S0033291717003075

Acknowledgements

We thank Sarah-Jayne Blakemore for useful discussion during the preparation of this manuscript.This work was support by a Royal Society University Research Fellowship (NR) and by a Wellcome Trust Seed Award in Science (VB; grant number: 200589/Z/16/Z)

Declaration of Interest

None.

Ethical Standards

The authors assert that all procedures contributing to this work comply with the ethical standards of the relevant national and institutional committees on human experimentation and with the Helsinki Declaration of 1975, as revised in 2008. The behavioural experiments were approved by the UCL Ethics Board under project number 3720/001.

References

Andreoni, J (1990) Impure altruism and donations to public goods: a theory of warm-glow giving. The Economic Journal 100, 464477.Google Scholar
Arechar, AA and Gächter, S, Molleman, L (2017) Conducting interactive experiments online. Experimental Economics 133.Google Scholar
Bone, JE and Raihani, NJ (2015) Human punishment is motivated by both a desire for revenge and a desire for equality. Evolution and Human Behavior 36, 323330.Google Scholar
Boyer, P, Firat, R and van Leeuwen, F (2015) Safety, threat, and stress in intergroup relations: a coalitional index model. Perspectives on Psychological Science 10, 434450.Google Scholar
Brandts, J and Charness, G (2011) The strategy versus the direct-response method: a first survey of experimental comparisons. Experimental Economics 14, 375398.Google Scholar
Brosnan, SF and de Waal, FB (2014) Evolution of responses to (un)fairness. Science 346, 1251776.Google Scholar
Buhrmester, M, Kwang, T and Gosling, SD (2011) Amazon's Mechanical Turk a new source of inexpensive, yet high-quality, data? Perspectives on Psychological Science 6, 35.Google Scholar
Burnham, KP and Anderson, DR (2002) Model Selection and Multimodel Inference: A Practical Information-Theoretic Approach. Springer Verlag: New York.Google Scholar
Camerer, CF (2003) Behavioral Game Theory. Experiments in Strategic Interaction. Princeton University Press: Princeton, NJ.Google Scholar
Carlsmith, KM, Darley, JM and Robinson, PH (2002) Why do we punish? Deterrence and just desserts as motives for punishment. Journal of Personality and Social Psychology 83, 284299.Google Scholar
Chandler, J and Shapiro, D (2016) Conducting clinical research using crowdsourced convenience samples. Annual Review of Clinical Psychology 12, 5381.Google Scholar
Christensen, RHB (2015) ordinal – Regression Models for Ordinal Data. R package version 2015.6-28 (http://www.cran.r-project.org/package=ordinal/).Google Scholar
Coid, JW et al. (2016) Paranoid ideation and violence: meta-analysis of individual subject data of 7 population surveys. Schizophrenia Bulletin 42, 907915.Google Scholar
Cristóbal-Narváez, P et al. (2016) Impact of adverse childhood experiences on psychotic-like symptoms and stress reactivity in daily life in nonclinical young adults. PLOS ONE 11, e0153557.Google Scholar
Cushman, F et al. (2009) Accidental outcomes guide punishment in a ‘trembling hand’ game. PLOS ONE 4, e6699.Google Scholar
Ellett, L et al. (2013) A paradigm for the study of paranoia in the general population: the Prisoner's Dilemma Game. Cognition and Emotion 27, 5362.Google Scholar
Engel, C (2011) Dictator games: a meta study. Experimental Economics 14, 583610.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fehr, E and Schmidt, KM (1999) A theory of fairness, competition, and cooperation. The Quarterly Journal of Economics 114, 817868.Google Scholar
Fett, AK et al. (2012) To trust or not to trust: the dynamics of social interaction in psychosis. Brain 135, 976984.Google Scholar
Fett, AK et al. (2016) Learning to trust: trust and attachment in early psychosis. Psychological Medicine 46, 14371447.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Fischbacher, U, Gächter, S and Quercia, S (2012) The behavioral validity of the strategy method in public good experiments. Journal of Economic Psychology 33, 897913.Google Scholar
Frankenhuis, WE, Panchanathan, K and Nettle, D (2016) Cognition in harsh and unpredictable environments. Current Opinion in Psychology 7, 7680.Google Scholar
Freeman, D (2016) Persecutory delusions: a cognitive perspective on understanding and treatment. The Lancet Psychiatry 3, 685692.Google Scholar
Freeman, D and Garety, PA (2000) Comments on the content of persecutory delusions: does the definition need clarification? British Journal of Clinical Psychology 39, 407414.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Freeman, D and Garety, P (2014) Advances in understanding and treating persecutory delusions: a review. Social Psychiatry and Psychiatriatric Epidemiology 49, 11791189.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Gelman, A (2008) Scaling regression inputs by dividing by two standard deviations. Statistics in Medicine 27, 28652873.Google Scholar
Green, CE et al. (2008) Measuring ideas of persecution and social reference: the Green et al. Paranoid Thought Scales (GPTS). Psychological Medicine 38, 101111.Google Scholar
Gromann, PM et al. (2013) Trust versus paranoia: abnormal response to social reward in psychotic illness. Brain 136, 19681975.Google Scholar
Grueber, CE et al. (2011) Multimodel inference in ecology and evolution: challenges and solutions. Journal of Evolutionary Biology 24, 699711.Google Scholar
Güth, W, Schmittberger, R and Schwarze, B (1982) An experimental analysis of ultimatum bargaining. Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization 3, 367388.Google Scholar
Hauser, DJ and Schwarz, N (2016) Attentive Turkers: MTurk participants perform better on online attention checks than do subject pool participants. Behavioral Research 48, 400407.Google Scholar
Hennig-Schmidt, H, Li, ZY and Yang, C (2008) Why people reject advantageous offers – non-monotonic strategies in ultimatum bargaining: evaluating a video experiment run in PR China. Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization 65, 373384.Google Scholar
Horton, JJ, Rand, DG and Zeckhauser, RJ (2011) The online laboratory: conducting experiments in a real labor market. Experimental Economics 14, 399425.Google Scholar
Howes, OD and Murray, RM (2014) Schizophrenia: an integrated sociodevelopmental-cognitive model. Lancet 383, 16771687.Google Scholar
Kahneman, D, Knetsch, JL and Thaler, R (1986) Fairness as a constraint on profit seeking: entitlements in the market. The American Economic Review 76, 728741.Google Scholar
Krasnow, MM et al. (2016) Looking under the hood of third-party punishment reveals design for personal benefit. Psychological Science 27, 405418.Google Scholar
Paolacci, G and Chandler, J (2014) Inside the Turk: understanding mechanical Turk as a participant pool. Current Directions in Psychological Science 23, 184188.Google Scholar
Patrzyk, PM and Takáč, M (2017) Cognitive adaptations to criminal justice lead to ‘paranoid’ norm obedience. Adaptive Behavior 25, 8395.Google Scholar
Raihani, NJ and Bell, V (2017a) Paranoia and the social representation of others: a large-scale game theory approach. Scientific Reports 7, 4544.Google Scholar
Raihani, NJ and Bell, V (2017b) Data and R code to reproduce analyses from Conflict and Cooperation in Paranoia: A Large-Scale Behavioural Experiment. Figshare. Doi: 10.6084/m9.figshare.4769752.Google Scholar
Raihani, NJ and Bshary, R (2015) The reputation of punishers. Trends in Ecology & Evolution 30, 98103.Google Scholar
Raihani, NJ, Mace, R and Lamba, S (2013) The effect of $1, $5 and $10 stakes in an online dictator game. PLOS ONE 8, e73131.Google Scholar
Raihani, NJ and McAuliffe, K (2012) Human punishment is motivated by inequity aversion, not a desire for reciprocity. Biology Letters 8, 802804.Google Scholar
Raihani, NJ, Thornton, A and Bshary, R (2012) Punishment and cooperation in nature. Trends in Ecology & Evolution 27, 288295.Google Scholar
Shapiro, DN, Chandler, J and Mueller, PA (2013) Using mechanical Turk to study clinical populations. Clinical Psychological Science 1, 213220.Google Scholar
Slembeck, T (1999) Reputations and Fairness in Bargaining-Experimental Evidence from a Repeated Ultimatum Game with Fixed Opponents. Discussion Paper, University of St Gallen.Google Scholar
Stevens, JR and Hauser, MD (2004) Why be nice? Psychological constraints on the evolution of cooperation. Trends in Cognitive Sciences 8, 6065.Google Scholar
Yamagishi, T (1986) The provision of a sanctioning system as a public good. Journal of Personality and Social Psychology 51, 110116.Google Scholar
Yamagishi, T et al. (2009) The private rejection of unfair offers and emotional commitment. Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences USA 106, 11520–3.Google Scholar
Figure 0

Fig. 1. Effect of paranoia on (a) DG and UG offers made and (b) amount offered that the subject rejected (UG) or punished (DG). DG donations are shown in black and UG offers are shown in red. Data are raw means and standard errors and do not control for other terms included in the statistical models. Where no standard error bars are shown, this is because the standard error of the mean was 0.00 when rounded. For visualisation (and to calculate the raw means) paranoia was converted to a 5-level categorical variable, where 1 ⩽ 35, 35 < 2 ⩽ 60, 60 < 3⩽85, 85 < 4 ⩽ 110, and 110 < 5 ⩽ 160.

Figure 1

Table 1. Factors affecting punishment threshold

Figure 2

Table 2. Factors affecting minimal acceptable offer (MAO) in the Ultimatum Game

Figure 3

Table 3. Factors affecting Dictator Game offer

Figure 4

Table 4. Factors affecting Ultimatum Game offer

Supplementary material: PDF

Raihani and Bell supplementary material

Raihani and Bell supplementary material 1

Download Raihani and Bell supplementary material(PDF)
PDF 128.1 KB
Supplementary material: File

Raihani and Bell supplementary material

Raihani and Bell supplementary material 2

Download Raihani and Bell supplementary material(File)
File 53.4 KB