Hostname: page-component-cd9895bd7-p9bg8 Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-12-27T02:33:55.800Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Valuing vulnerable Asian options with liquidity risk under Lévy processes

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  07 February 2022

Chengyou Cai
Affiliation:
School of International Trade and Economics, University of International Business and Economics, Beijing 100029, China. E-mails: [email protected], [email protected]
Xingchun Wang
Affiliation:
School of International Trade and Economics, University of International Business and Economics, Beijing 100029, China. E-mails: [email protected], [email protected]
Rights & Permissions [Opens in a new window]

Abstract

In this paper, we study the pricing of vulnerable Asian options with liquidity risk. We employ general Lévy processes to capture the changes in the liquidity discount factors and the information processes of all assets. In the proposed pricing model, we obtain the closed-form pricing formula of vulnerable Asian options using the Fourier transform methods. Finally, the derived pricing formula is used to illustrate the effects of asymmetric jump risk, and the effects are relatively stable on (vulnerable) Asian options with different moneynesses.

Type
Research Article
Copyright
© The Author(s), 2022. Published by Cambridge University Press

1. Introduction

In this paper, we study the pricing problems of vulnerable Asian options with liquidity risk. In the option pricing literature, liquidity risk has been considered using different approaches. For example, Liu and Yong [Reference Liu and Yong27] study European contingent claims by assuming that the stock price is directly affected by the trading of option traders. Cruz and Ševčovič [Reference Cruz and Ševčovič10] investigate the price of European options by taking into account of feedback effects of a large trader on the underlying asset. Another strand of the literature is based on theory of conic finance (see, e.g., [Reference Madan and Cherny28,Reference Madan and Schoutens29]). Leippold and Schärer [Reference Leippold and Schärer21] develop a stochastic liquidity model to generate term and skew structures of bid-ask spreads. There are also some other studies on options with liquidity risk, where the price of the illiquid stock is determined by equaling the demand and the supply of the stock, originating from Brunetti and Caldarera [Reference Brunetti and Caldarera4]. Li et al. [Reference Li, Zhang and Liu22] work in the model of Brunetti and Caldarera [Reference Brunetti and Caldarera4] and study the pricing problems of Asian options. Li et al. [Reference Li, Zhang, Liu and Zhang23] extend the framework in Brunetti and Caldarera [Reference Brunetti and Caldarera4] by adding jumps in the information process and investigate the price of discrete barrier options. Wang [Reference Wang40] investigates European options with default risk in a model with both liquidity risk and jump risk. Different from these studies, we work in a more general pricing model including Brunetti and Caldarera [Reference Brunetti and Caldarera4], Li et al. [Reference Li, Zhang, Liu and Zhang23] and Wang [Reference Wang40] as special cases, and focus on the pricing of Asian options with default risk.

Actually, Asian options with default risk have also been studied in the literature.Footnote 1 Tsao and Liu [Reference Tsao and Liu36] derive the approximation formula for the arithmetic Asian options with default risk in the Black–Scholes model. Jeon et al. [Reference Jeon, Yoon and Kang16] employ the pricing formula of vulnerable European options with time-dependent coefficients to derive a closed-form formula of vulnerable geometric Asian options. Wang [Reference Wang38] obtains an explicit pricing formula of Asian options with default risk under a stochastic volatility model and illustrates the effects of systematic risk on Asian option prices. Wang [Reference Wang39] employs GARCH models to describe the dynamics of the underlying assets and obtains the closed form of the prices of vulnerable Asian options, where the reduced-form model is employed to capture default risk. All these studies are based on the assumption that the underlying asset is completely liquid. The aim of the current paper is to relax this assumption and we work under the assumption that the underlying asset is an illiquid stock. In this sense, this paper contributes to the literature on Asian options with default risk and to the literature on default-free Asian options as well.Footnote 2

In this paper, we study the pricing of vulnerable Asian options with liquidity risk, by relaxing the assumptions in the literature on vulnerable Asian options that the underlying stock is perfectly liquid. We follow Li et al. [Reference Li, Zhang and Liu22] and Wang [Reference Wang40], and determine the price of the illiquid stock by the market clearing condition. We use structural approaches to describe default risk and model the dynamics of option issuer's assets similarly. In addition, Lévy processes are used to capture jump changes in the liquidity discount factors and the information processes of all assets. In this pricing model, we study the pricing problems of Asian options with default risk, which are more complex than European options with default risk considered in Wang [Reference Wang40]. Because of the generality of Lévy processes, we use the Fourier transform methods to get closed forms of option prices. Moreover, we mainly focus on the impact of asymmetric jump risk on option prices. For example, when negative news comes, the decline of underlying stock prices is greater than the rise when positive news comes. Many studies provide evidence for the presence of asymmetric jump risk (see, e.g., Carr et al. [Reference Carr, Geman, Madan and Yor8], Cont and Tankov [Reference Cont and Tankov9] and Frame and Ramezani [Reference Frame and Ramezani13]). For instance, Frame and Ramezani [Reference Frame and Ramezani13] calibrate the asymmetric affine jump-diffusion models using the time series data of market index and individual stocks. They find that the arrival frequency and jump amplitude of positive news are not equal to those of negative news. In order to characterize this asymmetric jump risk, in the numerical section, we use CGMY processes to show the difference of the asymmetry on option prices by changing different parameter values.

Comparing with the existing literature, this paper has several instructive characteristics. As mentioned above, the pricing model in this paper is constructed using similar methods as in Brunetti and Caldarera [Reference Brunetti and Caldarera4], Li et al. [Reference Li, Zhang, Liu and Zhang23] and Wang [Reference Wang40], and includes them as special cases. Second, we take into account of default risk, while Brunetti and Caldarera [Reference Brunetti and Caldarera4] and Li et al. [Reference Li, Zhang, Liu and Zhang23] work in a default-free model. Third, the pricing model in this paper uses more general Lévy processes, while Wang [Reference Wang40] employs compound Poisson processes to describe jumps. Fourth, we derive the pricing formula using Fourier transform methods, which are different from Wang [Reference Wang40]. Because compound Poisson processes are used in Wang [Reference Wang40], the pricing formula can be derived conditional on the exact numbers of Poisson jumps. However, this method is not applicable in general Lévy processes. Moreover, in this paper, we mainly focus on asymmetric jump risk, and the closed-form pricing formula is still available. Note that Wang [Reference Wang40] also illustrates asymmetric jumps on vulnerable European options using numerical methods (see footnote 3 therein), since the explicit pricing formula is not available there. Fifth, we consider vulnerable Asian options, while Wang [Reference Wang40] investigates vulnerable European options, and Li et al. [Reference Li, Zhang and Liu22] work in a default-free model. Lastly, the proposed pricing model can be extended to price vulnerable power exchange options (see, e.g., [Reference Pasricha and Goel33,Reference Xu, Shao and Wang42]).

The structure of this paper is as follows. In Section 2, we describe the model and get the closed-form pricing formula of vulnerable Asian options. In Section 3, we carry out numerical analysis. Section 4 concludes the paper. The detailed proof is given in the Appendix.

2. Vulnerable Asian options with liquidity risk

In this section, we consider vulnerable Asian options with liquidity risk. We first describe the pricing model, where both the underlying asset and option issuer's assets are exposed to liquidity risk and correlated in a general sense. More specifically, a common Lévy process is adopted to drive the information processes of all assets and the liquidity discount factors. In this proposed framework, we obtain the closed form of vulnerable Asian options with liquidity risk using Fourier transform methods.

2.1. The model

Let $P$ be a real-world probability measure. We consider an illiquid stock and use $S(t)$ to express its price at time $t$. Briefly speaking, market clearing gives the illiquid stock price, which means that the demand for the stock and the supply are equal. Following Brunetti and Caldarera [Reference Brunetti and Caldarera4], Li et al. [Reference Li, Zhang, Liu and Zhang23] and Wang [Reference Wang40], we work with a fixed supply ($\bar {S}$), and assume that the demand for the illiquid stock has the following specific form,

(2.1)\begin{equation} D_1(S(t), I_1(t), L_1(t)):=g_1\left(\frac{I_1(t)^{\vartheta_1}}{L_1(t)S(t)}\right), \end{equation}

where $g_{1}(\cdot )$ is a smooth and strictly increasing function, and $\vartheta _1$ is a constant. In addition, $I_{1}(t)$ represents the information process and $L_{1}(t)$ denotes the liquidity discount factor. Furthermore, the information process $I_{1}(t)$ is driven by the following process,

$$I_1(t)=I_1(0)\exp\{(\mu_1-\tfrac{1}{2}\sigma_1^{2} -k_{1})t +\sigma_{1} B_{1}(t)+\delta_{1}X(t)+Y_{1}(t)\},$$

where $\mu _1$ and $\sigma _1$ are constants, and $B_{1}(t)$ is a standard Brownian motion. The last two terms, $X(t)$ and $Y_{1}(t)$, are two independent pure jump Lévy processes, which describe the common and idiosyncratic jumps, respectively. Note that the above form of $I_{1}(t)$ contains the ones in Brunetti and Caldarera [Reference Brunetti and Caldarera4], Li et al. [Reference Li, Zhang, Liu and Zhang23] and Wang [Reference Wang40] as special cases. We suppose the liquidity discount factor $L_{1}(t)$ has the following specific form,

$$L_1(t)=L_1(0)\exp\left\{ -\beta_1 \left(\int_0^{t} a(s)\, {{\mathrm{d}}}s + \int_0^{t} a(s)\, {{\mathrm{d}}}W(s)+\theta X(t) \right)\right\},$$

where $a(s)$ is a deterministic function of time, $\beta _1$ and $\theta$ are nonnegative constants, and $W(t)$ is a standard Brownian motion, independent of $B_{1}(t)$. It should also be noted that the above liquidity discount factor includes those in Brunetti and Caldarera [Reference Brunetti and Caldarera4], Li et al. [Reference Li, Zhang, Liu and Zhang23] and Wang [Reference Wang40].

Based on the assumptions on the supply and the demand, the market clearing condition is as follows:

$$D_1(S(t), I_1(t), L_1(t))=\bar{S},$$

which in turn implies that,

$$S(t)=S(0)\frac{(I_1(t)/I_1(0))^{\vartheta_1}}{L_1(t)/L_1(0)}.$$

Lastly, by substituting $I_{1}(t)$ and $L_{1}(t)$, we can get the following form:

(2.2)\begin{align} S(t)& =S(0)\exp\left\{\vartheta_1(\mu_1-\frac{1}{2}\sigma_1^{2} -k_{1})t +\vartheta_1\sigma_{1} B_{1}(t) + (\vartheta_{1}\delta_{1}+\beta_{1}\theta)X(t)+\vartheta_{1}Y_{1}(t)\right.\nonumber\\ & \quad \left.+ \beta_1 \left(\int_0^{t} a(s)\, {{\mathrm{d}}}s + \int_0^{t} a(s)\, {{\mathrm{d}}}W(s) \right)\right\}. \end{align}

It is clear that the stock price is driven by the common jumps, idiosyncratic jumps and liquidity risk as well.

Now, we turn to default risk. Here, we follow Klein [Reference Klein17] and Wang [Reference Wang37], and adopt structural approaches. Let $V(t)$ be the value of option issuer's assets and we assume that it has a similar form to the stock, that is,

(2.3)\begin{align} V(t)& =V(0)\exp\left\{\vartheta_2(\mu_2-\frac{1}{2}\sigma_2^{2} -k_{2})t +\vartheta_2\sigma_{2} B_{2}(t) + (\vartheta_{2}\delta_{2}+\beta_{2}\theta)X(t)+\vartheta_{2}Y_{2}(t)\right.\nonumber\\ & \quad \left. + \beta_2 \left(\int_0^{t} a(s)\, {{\mathrm{d}}}s + \int_0^{t} a(s)\, {{\mathrm{d}}}W(s) \right)\right\}, \end{align}

where $B_{2}(t)$ is a standard Brownian motion independent of $W(t)$ and $Y_{2}(t)$ is a pure jump Lévy process, independent of $X(t)$ and $Y_{1}(t)$. Recall that $B_{1}(t)$ is a standard Brownian motion, driving the information process of the illiquid stock. Similarly, $B_{2}(t)$ drives the information process of option issuer's assets. To work in a more general pricing model, here we assume that $B_{1}(t)$ and $B_{2}(t)$ are correlated and have a correlation coefficient $\rho$. Moreover, both the stock and option issuer's assets are affected by liquidity risk and common jumps.

In the pricing model described above, we will value vulnerable Asian options with liquidity risk in the coming subsection. As mentioned before, different from Wang [Reference Wang40], we will derive the pricing formula using Fourier transform methods, since the method in Wang [Reference Wang40] is not applicable in general Lévy processes. Moreover, in this paper, we mainly focus on asymmetric jump risk. In order to capture asymmetric jump risk, in the numerical section, we will employ CGMY processes, albeit the pricing formula is available in general Lévy processes. CGMY processes are proposed by Carr et al. [Reference Carr, Geman, Madan and Yor8] to capture jump changes of assets, including both finite or infinite activities and finite or infinite variation. There are four parameters $C$, $G$, $M$ and $Y$, which characterize different properties of the process. We refer interested readers to Carr et al. [Reference Carr, Geman, Madan and Yor8] for more details. In this paper, because we are mainly interested in asymmetric jump risk, we pay more attention to the parameters $G$ and $M$, which characterize the exponential decay rate on the left and right of the Lévy density. Specially, when $G=M$, the density function is symmetric. In addition, the CGMY process has been used commonly in the option pricing literature (see, e.g., Madan and Yor [Reference Madan and Yor30], Ballotta and Kyriakou [Reference Ballotta and Kyriakou2], Figueroa-López et al. [Reference Figueroa-López, Gong and Houdré12] and references therein) and its characteristic function is given as follows:

(2.4)\begin{equation} \phi_{{\rm CGMY}}(u,t;C,G,M,Y)=\exp\{tC\Gamma({-}Y)[(M-iu)^{Y}-M^{Y}+(G+iu)^{Y}-G^{Y}]\}, \end{equation}

where $C\gt0,\ G\geqslant 0,\ M\geqslant 0$, $Y\lt2$, and $\Gamma (\cdot )$ is the gamma function.

2.2. The pricing formula

In this subsection, we use Fourier transform methods to derive the pricing formula of vulnerable Asian options with liquidity risk. Let $G(T)$ denote discrete geometric average price of the illiquid stock $S(t)$, and it has the following form:

(2.5)\begin{equation} G(T)=\left[\prod_{j=1}^{n}S(t_{j})\right]^{{1}/{n}}, \end{equation}

with $0\lt t_1\lt\cdots \lt t_n=T$ and $t_j=jT/n$. The payoff of Asian options with fixed strike prices is therefore given by,

$$\max\{G(T)-K,0\},$$

where $K$ is the fixed strike price. When $n=1$, the above payoff equals the standard European call options. Recall that we use structural approaches to capture default risk. Assuming that the value of option issuer's debt is $D$ and the recovery rate is $\alpha$, we then have the payoff of Asian options with default risk as follows:

$$\max\{G(T)-K,0\}\left(\textbf{1}(V(T)\geqslant D)+\frac{\alpha V(T)}{D}\textbf{1}(V(T)\lt D)\right).$$

According to the risk-neutral pricing theory, we have the following price of Asian options with default risk,

(2.6)\begin{equation} C_{0}=e^{{-}rT}{\rm E}^{Q}\left[\max\{G(T)-K,0\}\left(\textbf{1}(V(T)\geqslant D)+\frac{\alpha V(T)}{D}\textbf{1}(V(T)\lt D)\right)\right], \end{equation}

where $Q$ is a risk-neutral probability measure. Based on the above price of vulnerable Asian options, we can obtain the difference between vanilla Asian options and vulnerable Asian options, that is,

$$e^{{-}rT}{\rm E}^{Q}\left[\max\{G(T)-K,0\}(1-\frac{\alpha V(T)}{D})\textbf{1}(V(T)\lt D)\right].$$

This difference is the credit value adjustment (CVA) of Asian options (see, e.g., [Reference Antonelli, Ramponi and Scarlatti1]) and is an adjustment to the risk-free value in order to include default risk. In addition, investment banks have built trading desks and complex models around managing CVA (see, e.g., [Reference Brigo, Morini and Pallavicini3]).

In order to obtain the closed form of $C_{0}$ listed above, we need to work under a risk-neutral probability measure, which could be found based on the Esscher transform (see, e.g., [Reference Elliott, Chan and Siu11]). Here, we give the dynamics of the illiquid stock and the issuer's assets under $Q$ directly,

(2.7)\begin{align} S(t) & =S(0)\exp\left\{ r t +\vartheta_1\sigma_{1} \tilde{B}_{1}(t)-\frac{1}{2}\vartheta_1^{2}\sigma_1^{2}t +\beta_1 \int_0^{t} a(s) \,{{\mathrm{d}}} \tilde{W}(s)- \frac{1}{2}\beta_1^{2}\int_0^{t} a(s)^{2}\,{{\mathrm{d}}}s\right.\nonumber\\ & \quad \left.\vphantom{\frac{1}{2}\int_0^{t}} + (\vartheta_{1}\delta_{1}+\beta_{1}\theta)\tilde{X}(t)+\vartheta_{1}\tilde{Y}_{1}(t) - \bar{k}_{1} t\right\}, \end{align}

and

(2.8)\begin{align} V(t)& =V(0)\exp\left\{ r t +\vartheta_2\sigma_{2} \tilde{B}_{2}(t)-\frac{1}{2}\vartheta_2^{2}\sigma_2^{2}t +\beta_2 \int_0^{t} a(s)\, {{\mathrm{d}}} \tilde{W}(s)- \frac{1}{2}\beta_2^{2}\int_0^{t} a(s)^{2}\,{{\mathrm{d}}}s\right.\nonumber\\ & \quad \left.\vphantom{\frac{1}{2}\int_0^{t}}+ (\vartheta_{2}\delta_{2}+\beta_{2}\theta)\tilde{X}(t)+\vartheta_{2}\tilde{Y}_{2}(t) - \bar{k}_{2} t\right\}, \end{align}

where $r$ is risk-free interest rate, $\bar {k}_{1}=\ln ({\rm E}^{Q}[e^{(\vartheta _{1}\delta _{1}+\beta _{1}\theta )X(1)+\vartheta _{1}Y_{1}(1)}])$ and $\bar {k}_{2}=\ln ({\rm E}^{Q}[e^{(\vartheta _{2}\delta _{2}+\beta _{2}\theta )X(1)+\vartheta _{2}Y_{2}(1)}])$. We can easily verify that the discounted prices of two assets are martingales under $Q$.

In what follows, we use Fourier transform methods to derive the pricing formula. To this end, we rewrite $C_0$ in (2.6) as follows,

$$C_0=C_1(k,h)+C_2(k,\tilde{h}),$$

where

\begin{align*} C_1(k,h)& =e^{{-}rT}\,{\rm E}^{Q}\left[\max\{G(T)-K,0\}(\textbf{1}(V(T)\geqslant D))\right] \\ & =e^{{-}rT}\,{\rm E}^{Q}\left[\max\{e^{Y(T)}-e^{k},0\}(\textbf{1}(e^{H(T)}\geqslant e^{h}))\right], \\ C_2(k,\tilde{h})& =e^{{-}rT}\,{\rm E}^{Q}\left[\max\{G(T)-K,0\}\left(\frac{\alpha V(T)}{D}\textbf{1}(V(T)\lt D)\right)\right]\\ & =e^{{-}rT}\,{\rm E}^{Q}\left[\max\{e^{Y(T)}-e^{k},0\}\left(\frac{\alpha e^{H(T)}}{e^{-\tilde{h}}}\textbf{1}(e^{H(T)}\lt e^{-\tilde{h}})\right)\right], \end{align*}

where $Y(T)=\ln G(T)$, $H(T)=\ln V(T)$, $k=\ln K$, $h=\ln D$ and $\tilde {h}=-\ln D$.

Additionally, we can obtain the respective Fourier transforms of $C_1(k,h)$ and $C_2(k,\tilde {h})$ shown below,

(2.9)\begin{align} \mathscr{F}[C_{1}](u,v)& =\int_{-\infty }^{+\infty }\int_{-\infty }^{+\infty }e^{\varrho_{1}k+\varrho_{2}h}C_1(k,h)\,e^{2\pi i(uk+vh)}\,{{\mathrm{d}}}k{{\mathrm{d}}}h, \end{align}
(2.10)\begin{align} \mathscr{F}[C_{2}](u,v)& =\int_{-\infty }^{+\infty }\int_{-\infty }^{+\infty }e^{\varrho_{1}k}C_{2}(k,\tilde{h})\,e^{2\pi i(uk+v\tilde{h})}\,{{\mathrm{d}}}k{{\mathrm{d}}} \tilde{h}, \end{align}

where $\varrho _{1}$ and $\varrho _{2}$ are positive constants. It should be noted that $\varrho _{1}$ and $\varrho _{2}$ are the damping factors, which are introduced in order to ensure the existence of the integrals (see, e.g., [Reference Carr and Madan7]).

Substituting the concrete forms of $C_1(k,h)$ and $C_2(k,\tilde {h})$ into the above expression, we get the following results:

\begin{align*} \mathscr{F}[C_{1}](u,v) & =\frac{e^{{-}rT}}{(2\pi iu+\varrho_{1})(2\pi iu+\varrho_{1}+1)(2\pi iv+\varrho_{2})}{\rm E}^{Q}[e^{(2\pi iu+\varrho_{1}+1)Y(T)}\,e^{(2\pi iv+\varrho_{2})H(T)}]\\ & =\frac{e^{{-}rT}}{(2\pi iu+\varrho_{1})(2\pi iu+\varrho_{1}+1)(2\pi iv+\varrho_{2})}\zeta(2\pi iu+\varrho_{1}+1,2\pi iv+\varrho_{2}),\\ \mathscr{F}[C_{2}](u,v) & =\frac{\alpha \,e^{{-}rT}}{(2\pi iu+\varrho_{1})(2\pi iu+\varrho_{1}+1)(2\pi iv+1)}{\rm E}^{Q}[e^{(2\pi iu+\varrho_{1}+1)Y(T)}\,e^{-(2\pi iv)H(T)}]\\ & =\frac{\alpha\, e^{{-}rT}}{(2\pi iu+\varrho_{1})(2\pi iu+\varrho_{1}+1)(2\pi iv+1)}\zeta(2\pi iu+\varrho_{1}+1, -2\pi iv). \end{align*}

The detailed calculations are shown in the Appendix and $\zeta (\cdot,\cdot )$ is given in Proposition 2.1. Finally, $C_1(k,h)$ and $C_2(k,\tilde {h})$ are expressed by the inverse Fourier transforms,

\begin{align*} C_{1}(k,h)& =e^{-\varrho_{1}k-\varrho_{2}h}\int_{-\infty }^{+\infty }\int_{-\infty }^{+\infty }\mathscr{F}[C_{1}](u,v)\,e^{{-}i2\pi(uk+vh)}\,{{\mathrm{d}}}u{{\mathrm{d}}}v, \\ C_{2}(k,\tilde{h})& =e^{-\varrho_{1}k}\int_{-\infty }^{+\infty }\int_{-\infty }^{+\infty }\mathscr{F}[C_{2}](u,v)\,e^{{-}i2\pi(uk+v\tilde{h})}\,{{\mathrm{d}}}u\,{{\mathrm{d}}}v. \end{align*}

Therefore, we obtain the pricing formula of vulnerable Asian options with liquidity risk, that is, $C_0=C_1(k,h)+C_2(k,\tilde {h})$. Note that we have obtained the pricing formula expressed by the inverse Fourier transforms. In Section 3, we will set the lower and upper limits for the infinite integrals to $-$10,000 and 10,000 in order to obtain the prices of (vulnerable) Asian options. Additionally, we use the functions ‘$quad(\cdot )$’ and ‘$dblquad(\cdot )$’ in Matlab to evaluate Asian options and vulnerable Asian options, respectively.

We end this subsection by giving the explicit expression of $\zeta (\cdot,\cdot )$ defined below,

$$\zeta(p,q)={\rm E}^{Q}[{e^{p Y(T)+q H(T)}}],$$

where $p$ and $q$ are complex numbers, $Y(T)=\ln G(T)$ and $H(T)=\ln V(T)$. From the dynamics of the illiquid stock and the issuer's assets under $Q$, one gets that

(2.11)\begin{align} Y(T)& =\ln(G(T))\\ & =\frac{1}{n}\sum_{j=1}^{n}\ln(S(t_{j})) \nonumber\\ & =\frac{1}{n}\sum_{j=1}^{n}\left[\ln(S(0))+(r-\frac{1}{2}\vartheta_{1}^{2}\sigma_{1}^{2}-\bar{k}_{1})t_{j} -\frac{1}{2}\beta_{1}^{2}\int_{0}^{t_{j}}a(s)^{2}\,{{\mathrm{d}}}s+\vartheta_{1}\sigma_{1}\tilde{B}_{1}(t_{j})\right. \nonumber\\ & \quad \left. + \beta_{1}\int_{0}^{t_{j}}a(s)\, {{\mathrm{d}}} \tilde{W}(s)+(\vartheta_{1}\delta_{1}+\beta_{1}\theta)\tilde{X}(t_{j}) +\vartheta_{1}\tilde{Y}_{1}(t_{j})\right]\nonumber\\ & =\ln(S(0))+\left(r-\frac{1}{2}\vartheta_{1}^{2}\sigma_{1}^{2}-\bar{k}_{1}\right)\frac{n+1}{2n}T- \frac{\beta_{1}^{2}}{2n}\sum_{j=1}^{n}\int_{0}^{t_{j}}a(s)^{2}\,{{\mathrm{d}}}s+\frac{\vartheta_{1}\sigma_{1}}{n}\sum_{j=1}^{n}\tilde{B}_{1}(t_{j}) \nonumber\\\notag \end{align}
(2.12)\begin{align} & \quad +\frac{\beta_{1}}{n}\sum_{j=1}^{n}\int_{0}^{t_{j}}a(s)\, {{\mathrm{d}}} \tilde{W}(s)+\frac{\vartheta_{1}\delta_{1}+\beta_{1}\theta}{n}\sum_{j=1}^{n}\tilde{X}(t_{j}) +\frac{\vartheta_{1}}{n}\sum_{j=1}^{n}\tilde{Y}_{1}(t_{j}), \end{align}

and

(2.13)\begin{align} H(T)& =\ln(V(T))\nonumber\\ & =\ln(V(0))+\left(r-\frac{1}{2}\vartheta_{2}^{2}\sigma_{2}^{2}-\bar{k}_{2}\right)T -\frac{1}{2}\beta_{2}^{2}\int_{0}^{T}a(s)^{2}\,{{\mathrm{d}}}s+\vartheta_{2}\sigma_{2}\tilde{B}_{2}(T)+\beta_{2}\int_{0}^{T}a(s)\, {{\mathrm{d}}} \tilde{W}(s)\nonumber\\ & \quad +(\vartheta_{2}\delta_{2}+\beta_{2}\theta)\tilde{X}(T)+\vartheta_{2}\tilde{Y}_{2}(T), \end{align}

where $0\lt t_1\lt\cdots \lt t_n=T$ and $t_j=jT/n$. In order to give the explicit expression of $\zeta (\cdot,\cdot )$, we introduce the following notations,

\begin{align*} \Delta \tilde{X}_{j}& =\tilde{X}(t_{j})-\tilde{X}(t_{j-1}),\\ {\rm E}^{Q}[e^{iw\Delta \tilde{X}_1}]& =\psi_{\Delta \tilde{X}}(w),\\ {\rm E}^{Q}[e^{iw\Delta \tilde{Y}_{1}}]& =\psi_{\Delta \tilde{Y}_{1}}(w),\\ {\rm E}^{Q}[e^{iw\tilde{Y}_{2}}]& =\psi_{\tilde{Y}_{2}}(w). \end{align*}

Proposition 2.1. In the proposed pricing model, we have the closed form of $\zeta (\cdot,\cdot )$ as follows:

$$\zeta(p,q)=A_{1}(p,q)\cdot A_{2}(p,q)\cdot A_{3}(p,q)\cdot A_{4}(p,q)\cdot A_{5}(p,q)\cdot A_{6}(p,q),$$

where

\begin{align*} A_{1}(p,q)& =e^{p(\ln(S(0))+(r-\frac{1}{2}\vartheta_{1}^{2}\sigma_{1}^{2}-\bar{k}_{1})\frac{n+1}{2n}T-\frac{\beta_{1}^{2}}{2n}\sum_{j=1}^{n}\int_{0}^{t_{j}}a(s)^{2}\,{{\mathrm{d}}}s)+q(\ln(V(0))+(r-\frac{1}{2}\vartheta_{2}^{2}\sigma_{2}^{2}-\bar{k}_{2})T-\frac{1}{2}\beta_{2}^{2}\int_{0}^{T}a(s)^{2}\,{{\mathrm{d}}}s)}, \\ A_{2}(p,q)& =\exp\left\{\frac{1}{2}\sum_{j=1}^{n}\left[p\frac{\vartheta_{1}\sigma_{1}}{n}(n+1-j) +q\vartheta_{2}\sigma_{2}\rho\right]^{2}\frac{T}{n}+\frac{1}{2}q^{2}\vartheta_{2}^{2} \sigma_{2}^{2}(1-\rho^{2})T\right\},\\ A_{3}(p,q)& =\exp\left\{\frac{1}{2}\sum_{j=1}^{n}\left[p\frac{\beta_{1}}{n}(n+1-j)+q\beta_{2}\right]^{2} \int_{t_{j-1}}^{t_{j}}a(s)^{2}\,{{\mathrm{d}}}s\right\}, \\ A_{4}(p,q)& =\prod_{j=1}^{n}\psi _{\Delta X}\left({-}ip(\vartheta_{1}\delta_{1}+\beta_{1}\theta)\frac{n+1-j}{n}-iq(\vartheta_{2}\delta_{2}+\beta_{2}\theta)\right),\\ A_{5}(p,q)& =\prod_{j=1}^{n}\psi _{\Delta Y}\left({-}ip\frac{\vartheta_{1}}{n}(n+1-j)\right), \\ A_{6}(p,q)& =\psi_{Y_{2}}({-}iq\vartheta_{2}). \end{align*}

Proof. See the Appendix.

By far, we have obtained the closed-form pricing formula of vulnerable Asian options in the proposed pricing model. In the coming section, we will illustrate vulnerable Asian option prices and focus on the difference of the asymmetric jump risk.

3. Numerical results

In this section, we use the derived pricing formula to focus on the effects of asymmetric jump risk on the prices of (vulnerable) Asian options. In Subsection 3.1, we report Asian option values in the proposed pricing model, and the corresponding pricing formula can be obtained by discarding default risk. In Subsection 3.2, the prices of vulnerable Asian options are illustrated. As mentioned before, here we choose a particular Lévy process, that is, the CGMY process, to describe common jumps $X(t)$ and investigate the impact of asymmetric jumps on option prices. In order to directly observe this impact, here we assume away idiosyncratic jumps of both assets. In this way, the asymmetric effects are only caused by common jumps, rather than the combination of common and idiosyncratic jumps. Additionally, the effects of idiosyncratic jumps are quite intuitive (see, e.g., [Reference Wang40]).

In order to obtain option prices, we need to set the parameter values. As we know, there are four parameters in the CGMY process (see Subsection 2.1 for a brief introduction or refer to Carr et al. [Reference Carr, Geman, Madan and Yor8] for more details). We set four parameters to be $C_0=6.51,\ G_0=18.75,\ M_0 =32.95$ and $Y_0=0.5757$ as a base case. These parameter values are from Carr et al. [Reference Carr, Geman, Madan and Yor8]. The other parameter values are borrowed from Wang [Reference Wang40] and take the following values: $r=0.02,\ \vartheta _1=1.0,\ \sigma _1=0.25,\ \beta _1=0.75,\ \delta _1=0.80,\ \theta =0.80$ and $a(t)=0.50$. In addition, we assume that the option is at the money ($S(0)=K=10$) and has a maturity of $2.0$ years, and three observations are made during the whole period, which means that $n=3$. Finally, we set the damping factors $\varrho _{1}=\varrho _{2}=1.10$. We also calculate option prices with other values and the results are the same.

Before illustrating the effects of asymmetric jump risk on the prices of (vulnerable) Asian options, here we compare option prices in the proposed framework with those derived in pricing models without default risk or liquidity risk. The results are shown in Table 1, and option prices are close to those in previous literature (see, e.g., [Reference Li, Zhang and Liu22]). It should be remarked that option prices in our models are higher than those in Li et al. [Reference Li, Zhang and Liu22], because there are jumps in our models. The effects of the parameters $G$ and $M$ can also be observed from Table 1. It can be seen that option prices decrease when the value of the parameter $G$ or $M$ increases, which is consistent with Merton [Reference Merton31], Kou and Wang [Reference Kou and Wang20] and Tian et al. [Reference Tian, Wang, Wang and Wang35]. Furthermore, these effects are the focus of this paper and will be investigated in great detail in the following subsections.

Table 1. Asian option prices in three models. Model $1$ is the one proposed in this paper, which reduces to Model $2$ by discarding default risk and further to Model $3$ by assuming liquidity risk away.

Recall that the parameters $G$ and $M$ characterize the exponential decay rate on the left and right of the Lévy density. To illustrate the effects of asymmetric jump risk, in what follows, we will show (vulnerable) Asian option prices in the following cases: fixed $M$, $G=0.5G_0$; fixed $M$, $G=2G_0$; fixed $G$, $M=0.5M_0$; fixed $G$, $M=2M_0$. In this way, we can observe the difference in (vulnerable) Asian option prices caused by asymmetric jump risk.

3.1. Asian options

In this subsection, the prices of Asian options in the proposed pricing model are illustrated, and the results are shown in Figures 15. Figure 1 shows the prices of Asian options with different maturities. First, in all cases, Asian option prices rise with an increase of time to maturity. Next, we focus on the effects of the parameter $M$. Note that the parameter $M$ characterizes the exponential decay rate on the right of the Lévy density. The solid line corresponds to the base case, that is, $G=G_0,\ M=M_0$. The dotted line and the dot-dashed line illustrate Asian option prices with ($G=G_0,\ M=0.5M_0$) and ($G=G_0,\ M=2M_0$), respectively. Intuitively, a lower value of the parameter $M$ corresponds to a slower rate of exponential decay on the right of the Lévy density, and hence a higher Asian option price. Moreover, the differences between the base case and the case with ($G=G_0,\ M=0.5M_0$) are larger than those between the base case and the case with ($G=G_0,\ M=2M_0$).

FIGURE 1. Prices of Asian call options against time to maturities. The solid, dashed, dot-solid, dotted and dot-dashed lines correspond to prices of Asian options with ($G=G_0,\ M=M_0$), prices of Asian options with ($G=0.5G_0,\ M=M_0$), prices of Asian options with ($G=2G_0,\ M=M_0$), prices of Asian options with ($G=G_0,\ M=0.5M_0$) and prices of Asian options with ($G=G_0,\ M=2M_0$), respectively.

In what follows, we focus on the effect of the parameter $G$. Once again, note that the parameter $G$ characterizes the exponential decay rate on the left of the Lévy density. When the value of the parameter $G$ decreases, the Lévy density on the left decays more slowly, meaning that negative jumps occur more likely. Option prices should fall when the value of the parameter $G$ drops. However, an interesting finding in Figure 1 is that option prices increase when the value of the parameter $G$ decreases. These results are a little counterintuitive. The reason is that the parameter $G$ also affects the risk compensation term $\bar {k}_{1}$ under the risk neutral probability measure. It can be seen clearly from Figure 2 that when the parameter $G$ decreases, $\bar {k}_{1}$ decreases rapidly, resulting in the rise of underlying asset prices and option prices as well. The similar conclusions can be found in Merton [Reference Merton31], Kou and Wang [Reference Kou and Wang20] and Tian et al. [Reference Tian, Wang, Wang and Wang35]. In Figure 1, it can also be seen that option prices increase more when we reduce the value of the parameter $G$ by half than when we reduce the value of the parameter $M$ by half. Similarly, when we double the values of $G$ and $M$, negative jumps have a more pronounced effect.

FIGURE 2. Risk compensation $\bar {k}_{1}$ against the parameter $G$ in the CGMY process with $C=C_0, M=M_0,\ Y=Y_0$.

Figure 3 depicts option prices with alternative strike prices. Intuitively, option prices drop with an increase of strike prices, and the prices of Asian options with ($G=0.5G_0,\ M=M_0$) are largest. By comparing the solid line and the dotted line (the dashed line), we see that the distance between the two lines almost keeps unchanged when strike price changes. This result tells us that the effects of these two parameters are relatively stable for alternative moneynesses.

FIGURE 3. Prices of Asian call options against strike prices. The solid, dashed, dot-solid, dotted and dot-dashed lines correspond to prices of Asian options with ($G=G_0,\ M=M_0$), prices of Asian options with ($G=0.5G_0,\ M=M_0$), prices of Asian options with ($G=2G_0,\ M=M_0$), prices of Asian options with ($G=G_0,\ M=0.5M_0$) and prices of Asian options with ($G=G_0,\ M=2M_0$), respectively.

Figure 4 shows the influence of the change of $\theta$ in the liquidity discount factor on option prices. Note that $\theta$ captures the impact of jumps in the liquidity discount factor. With a larger value of $\theta$, we have a lower level of the liquidity discount factor and hence a higher underlying asset price, resulting in a higher option price. This is consistent with the intuition. In addition, with an increase of $\theta$, the gaps between the five lines are growing, indicating that the impact of asymmetric jump risk becomes greater.

FIGURE 4. Prices of Asian call options against the values of $\theta$. The solid, dashed, dot-solid, dotted and dot-dashed lines correspond to prices of Asian options with ($G=G_0,\ M=M_0$), prices of Asian options with ($G=0.5G_0,\ M=M_0$), prices of Asian options with ($G=2G_0,\ M=M_0$), prices of Asian options with ($G=G_0,\ M=0.5M_0$) and prices of Asian options with ($G=G_0,\ M=2M_0$), respectively.

Figure 5 illustrates the effect of the parameter $Y$ in the CGMY process on Asian option prices. The parameter $Y$ controls the fine structure of the stochastic process (see, e.g., [Reference Carr, Geman, Madan and Yor8]). From Figure 5, we can observe that option prices rise with an increase of $Y$, but the difference between the five situations does not change significantly.

FIGURE 5. Prices of Asian call options against the values of the parameter $Y$ in the CGMY process. The solid, dashed, dot-solid, dotted and dot-dashed lines correspond to prices of Asian options with ($G=G_0,\ M=M_0$), prices of Asian options with ($G=0.5G_0,\ M=M_0$), prices of Asian options with ($G=2G_0,\ M=M_0$), prices of Asian options with ($G=G_0,\ M=0.5M_0$) and prices of Asian options with ($G=G_0,\ M=2M_0$), respectively.

3.2. Vulnerable Asian options

In this subsection, we report the values of vulnerable Asian options in the proposed pricing model. To obtain the prices of the options with default risk, we need the parameter values in the dynamics of option issuer's assets. For simplicity, here we set them the same as those in the dynamics of the illiquid stock and the correlation coefficient is assumed to be $\rho =-0.50$. Moreover, the initial value of issuer's assets is $V(0)=100$, the value of the debt is $D=80$ and the recovery rate is $\alpha =0.40$. The results are shown in Figures 613.

FIGURE 6. Prices of vulnerable Asian call options against maturities. The solid, dashed, dot-solid, dotted and dot-dashed lines correspond to prices of Asian options with ($G=G_0,\ M=M_0$), prices of Asian options with ($G=0.5G_0,\ M=M_0$), prices of Asian options with ($G=2G_0,\ M=M_0$), prices of Asian options with ($G=G_0,\ M=0.5M_0$) and prices of Asian options with ($G=G_0,\ M=2M_0$), respectively.

Figures 6 and 7 illustrate the values of vulnerable Asian options with alternative maturities and different strike prices, respectively. These patterns are similar to the ones we observed in the last subsection and could be understood in a similar way. In addition, the price difference between Figure 1 (Figure 3) and Figure 6 (Figure 7) shows the effects of default risk. Due to the existence of default risk, vulnerable Asian option prices are lower. For example, in the base case, the prices of Asian options and vulnerable Asian options are $2.3315$ and $2.1494$, respectively.

FIGURE 7. Prices of vulnerable Asian call options against strike prices. The solid, dashed, dot-solid, dotted and dot-dashed lines correspond to prices of Asian options with ($G=G_0,\ M=M_0$), prices of Asian options with ($G=0.5G_0,\ M=M_0$), prices of Asian options with ($G=2G_0,\ M=M_0$), prices of Asian options with ($G=G_0,\ M=0.5M_0$) and prices of Asian options with ($G=G_0,\ M=2M_0$), respectively.

Figures 8 and 9 show vulnerable Asian option prices against different values of $\theta$ and the parameter $Y$ in the CGMY process, respectively. Once again, these patterns are similar to the ones we observed in the last subsection. However, it should be noted that the values of $\theta$ and the parameter $Y$ also affect issuer's assets (default risk). We take the change of $\theta$ as example. When the values of $\theta$ increase, we have a lower level of the liquidity discount factor. Therefore, we have a higher underlying asset price, and a higher value of issuer's assets, implying that vulnerable Asian options increase faster than those of Asian options without default risk. Indeed, from Figure 10, we can see that the price differences between Asian options and vulnerable Asian options narrow, as the value of $\theta$ rises.

FIGURE 8. Prices of vulnerable Asian call options against the values of $\theta$. The solid, dashed, dot-solid, dotted and dot-dashed lines correspond to prices of Asian options with ($G=G_0,\ M=M_0$), prices of Asian options with ($G=0.5G_0,\ M=M_0$), prices of Asian options with ($G=2G_0,\ M=M_0$), prices of Asian options with ($G=G_0,\ M=0.5M_0$) and prices of Asian options with ($G=G_0,\ M=2M_0$), respectively.

FIGURE 9. Prices of vulnerable Asian call options against the parameter $Y$ in the CGMY process. The solid, dashed, dot-solid, dotted and dot-dashed lines correspond to prices of Asian options with ($G=G_0,\ M=M_0$), prices of Asian options with ($G=0.5G_0,\ M=M_0$), prices of Asian options with ($G=2G_0,\ M=M_0$), prices of Asian options with ($G=G_0,\ M=0.5M_0$) and prices of Asian options with ($G=G_0,\ M=2M_0$), respectively.

FIGURE 10. Price differences between Asian call options and vulnerable Asian call options against against the values of $\theta$. The solid, dashed, dot-solid, dotted and dot-dashed lines correspond to ($G=G_0,\ M=M_0$), ($G=0.5G_0,\ M=M_0$), ($G=2G_0,\ M=M_0$), ($G=G_0,\ M=0.5M_0$) and ($G=G_0,\ M=2M_0$), respectively.

Figure 11 illustrates the effect of the recovery rate $\alpha$ on the price of vulnerable Asian options. The recovery rate $\alpha$ means that when the issuers default, option holders can get a certain proportion of compensation. In the pricing formula, the effect of recovery rates on vulnerable Asian option prices is linear, which is also reflected in Figure 11. Figures 12 and 13 show the impact of initial values of issuer's assets $V(0)$ and the default barrier $D$, respectively. Both of them are related to the probability of default. The larger the $V(0)$ or the smaller the $D$, the less likely the issuers are to default, and the higher vulnerable Asian option prices. These effects are not linear, and the effects of asymmetric jump risk keep relatively stable.

FIGURE 11. Prices of vulnerable Asian call options against the recover rate $\alpha$. The solid, dashed, dot-solid, dotted and dot-dashed lines correspond to prices of Asian options with ($G=G_0,\ M=M_0$), prices of Asian options with ($G=0.5G_0,\ M=M_0$), prices of Asian options with ($G=2G_0,\ M=M_0$), prices of Asian options with ($G=G_0,\ M=0.5M_0$) and prices of Asian options with ($G=G_0,\ M=2M_0$), respectively.

FIGURE 12. Prices of vulnerable Asian call options against initial values of issuer's assets $V(0)$. The solid, dashed, dot-solid, dotted and dot-dashed lines correspond to prices of Asian options with ($G=G_0,\ M=M_0$), prices of Asian options with ($G=0.5G_0,\ M=M_0$), prices of Asian options with ($G=2G_0,\ M=M_0$), prices of Asian options with ($G=G_0,\ M=0.5M_0$) and prices of Asian options with ($G=G_0,\ M=2M_0$), respectively.

FIGURE 13. Prices of vulnerable Asian call options against the default barrier $D$. The solid, dashed, dot-solid, dotted and dot-dashed lines correspond to prices of Asian options with ($G=G_0,\ M=M_0$), prices of Asian options with ($G=0.5G_0,\ M=M_0$), prices of Asian options with ($G=2G_0,\ M=M_0$), prices of Asian options with ($G=G_0,\ M=0.5M_0$) and prices of Asian options with ($G=G_0,\ M=2M_0$), respectively.

4. Conclusion

This paper studies the pricing of vulnerable Asian options in a pricing model with liquidity risk, where general Lévy processes are used to describe jumps in the information processes of both assets and the liquidity discount factors. The proposed pricing model includes some existing ones such as Brunetti and Caldarera [Reference Brunetti and Caldarera4], Li et al. [Reference Li, Zhang, Liu and Zhang23] and Wang [Reference Wang40]. Employing the Fourier transform methods, we obtain the closed-form pricing formula of vulnerable Asian options. Finally, we illustrate the effects of asymmetric jump risk using CGMY processes to describe the jumps. More specifically, we investigate the effects of the parameters $G$ and $M$ in the CGMY process, which characterize the exponential decay rate on the left and right of the Lévy density. The numerical results show that option prices increase when the value of the parameter $G$ or $M$ decreases.

Acknowledgements

The authors would like to thank the anonymous referee and the editor for their helpful comments and valuable suggestions that led to several important improvements. All errors are our own responsibility.

Funding statement

This study was supported by the National Natural Science Foundation of China (No. 11701084).

Compliance with ethical standards

The authors declare that they have no conflict of interests.

Appendix. Derivations of Fourier transforms of $C_1(k,h)$ and $C_2(k,\tilde {h})$

Here, we show the detailed calculations of Fourier transforms of $C_1(k,h)$ and $C_2(k,\tilde {h})$. In order to guarantee the existence of the integrals, we employ the method in Carr and Madan [Reference Carr and Madan7] and introduce the damping factors $\varrho _{1}$ and $\varrho _{2}$. We have the Fourier transform of $C_1(k,h)$ as follows:

\begin{align*} \mathscr{F}[C_1](u,v)& =\int_{-\infty }^{+\infty }\int_{-\infty }^{+\infty }\,e^{\varrho_{1}k+\varrho_{2}h}C_1(k,h)\,e^{2\pi i(uk+vh)}\,{{\mathrm{d}}}k{{\mathrm{d}}}h \\ & =\int_{-\infty }^{+\infty }\int_{-\infty }^{+\infty }e^{\varrho_{1}k+\varrho_{2}h}\, e^{{-}rT}{\rm E}^{Q}[\max\{e^{Y(T)}-e^{k},0\}(\textbf{1}(e^{H(T)}\geqslant e^{h}))]\cdot e^{i\cdot 2\pi(uk+vh)}\,{{\mathrm{d}}}k{{\mathrm{d}}}h \\ & =e^{{-}rT}{\rm E}^{Q}\left[\int_{-\infty }^{+\infty }e^{(2\pi iv+\varrho_{2})h}\textbf{1}(H(T)\geqslant h)\int_{-\infty }^{Y(T) }e^{(2\pi iu+\varrho_{1})k}(e^{Y(T)}-e^{k})\, {{\mathrm{d}}}k{{\mathrm{d}}}h\right] \\ & =e^{{-}rT}{\rm E}^{Q}\left[\int_{-\infty }^{+\infty }e^{(2\pi iv+\varrho_{2})h}\textbf{1}(H(T)\geqslant h)\left(\left.\frac{e^{(2\pi iu+\varrho_{1})k+Y(T)}}{2\pi iu+\varrho_{1}}\right\vert^{Y(T)}_{-\infty}-\left.\frac{e^{(2\pi iu+\varrho_{1}+1)k}}{2\pi iu+\varrho_{1}+1}\right\vert^{Y(T)}_{-\infty}\right) {{\mathrm{d}}}h\right] \\ & =e^{{-}rT}{\rm E}^{Q}\left[\int_{-\infty }^{+\infty }e^{(2\pi iv+\varrho_{2})h}\textbf{1}(H(T)\geqslant h)\left(\frac{e^{(2\pi iu+\varrho_{1}+1)Y(T)}}{2\pi iu+\varrho_{1}}-\frac{e^{(2\pi iu+\varrho_{1}+1)Y(T)}}{2\pi iu+\varrho_{1}+1}\right) {{\mathrm{d}}}h\right]\\ & =e^{{-}rT}{\rm E}^{Q}\left[\frac{e^{(2\pi iu+\varrho_{1}+1)Y(T)}}{(2\pi iu+\varrho_{1})(2\pi iu+\varrho_{1}+1)}\int_{-\infty }^{+\infty }e^{(2\pi iv+\varrho_{2})h}\textbf{1}(H(T)\geqslant h)\, {{\mathrm{d}}}h\right] \\ & =e^{{-}rT}{\rm E}^{Q}\left[\left(\frac{e^{(2\pi iu+\varrho_{1}+1)Y(T)}}{(2\pi iu+\varrho_{1})(2\pi iu+\varrho_{1}+1)}\right)\left(\left.\frac{e^{(2\pi iv+\varrho_{2})h}}{2\pi iv+\varrho_{2}}\right\vert_{-\infty }^{H(T) }\right)\right] \\ & =e^{{-}rT}{\rm E}^{Q}\left[\frac{e^{(2\pi iu+\varrho_{1}+1)Y(T)}}{(2\pi iu+\varrho_{1})(2\pi iu+\varrho_{1}+1)}\times\frac{e^{(2\pi iv+\varrho_{2})H(T)}}{2\pi iv+\varrho_{2}}\right]. \end{align*}

Note that we have used that $\varrho _{1}$ and $\varrho _{2}$ are positive.

As for the Fourier transform of $C_2(k,\tilde {h})$, we only need to introduce one damping factor $\varrho _{1}$, because there is a real part in front of $\tilde {h}$ which ensures that the integral exists at infinity. The detailed calculations of $\mathscr {F}[C_2](u,v)$ are shown below:

\begin{align*} & \int_{-\infty }^{+\infty }\int_{-\infty }^{+\infty }e^{\varrho_{1}k}C_2(k,\tilde{h})\,e^{2\pi i(uk+v\tilde{h})}\,{{\mathrm{d}}}k{{\mathrm{d}}} \tilde{h} \\ & \quad =\int_{-\infty }^{+\infty }\int_{-\infty }^{+\infty }e^{\varrho_{1}k}\,e^{{-}rT}\,{\rm E}^{Q}\left[\max\{e^{Y(T)}-e^{k},0\}\left(\frac{\alpha e^{H(T)}}{e^{-\tilde{h}}}\textbf{1}(e^{H(T)}\lt e^{-\tilde{h}})\right)\right]\cdot e^{i\cdot 2\pi(uk+v\tilde{h})}\,{{\mathrm{d}}}k{{\mathrm{d}}} \tilde{h} \\ & \quad =\alpha e^{{-}rT}\,{\rm E}^{Q}\left[\int_{-\infty }^{+\infty }e^{(2\pi iv+1)\tilde{h}}e^{H(T)}\textbf{1}(H(T)\lt{-}\tilde{h})\int_{-\infty }^{+\infty }e^{(2\pi iu+\varrho_{1})k}\max\{e^{Y(T)}-e^{k},0\}\,{{\mathrm{d}}}k{{\mathrm{d}}} \tilde{h}\right] \\ & \quad =\alpha e^{{-}rT}\,{\rm E}^{Q}\left[\int_{-\infty }^{+\infty }e^{(2\pi iv+1)\tilde{h}}e^{H(T)}\textbf{1}(\tilde{h}\lt{-}H(T))\int_{-\infty }^{Y(T)}e^{(2\pi iu+\varrho_{1})k}(e^{Y(T)}-e^{k})\, {{\mathrm{d}}}k{{\mathrm{d}}} \tilde{h}\right] \\ & \quad =\alpha e^{{-}rT}\,{\rm E}^{Q}\left[\int_{-\infty }^{+\infty }e^{(2\pi iv+1)\tilde{h}}e^{H(T)}\textbf{1}(\tilde{h}\lt{-}H(T))\left(\left.\frac{e^{(2\pi iu+\varrho_{1})k+Y(T)}}{2\pi iu+\varrho_{1}}\right\vert^{Y(T)}_{-\infty}-\left.\frac{e^{(2\pi iu+\varrho_{1}+1)k}}{2\pi iu+\varrho_{1}+1}\right\vert^{Y(T)}_{-\infty}\right) {{\mathrm{d}}} \tilde{h}\right] \\ & \quad =\alpha e^{{-}rT}\,{\rm E}^{Q}\left[\int_{-\infty }^{+\infty }e^{(2\pi iv+1)\tilde{h}}e^{H(T)}\textbf{1}(\tilde{h}\lt{-}H(T))\left(\frac{e^{(2\pi iu+\varrho_{1}+1)Y(T)}}{2\pi iu+\varrho_{1}}-\frac{e^{(2\pi iu+\varrho_{1}+1)Y(T)}}{2\pi iu+\varrho_{1}+1}\right) {{\mathrm{d}}} \tilde{h}\right] \\ & \quad =\alpha e^{{-}rT}\,{\rm E}^{Q}\left[\frac{e^{(2\pi iu+\varrho_{1}+1)Y(T)}}{(2\pi iu+\varrho_{1})(2\pi iu+\varrho_{1}+1)}\int_{-\infty}^{{-}H(T) }e^{(2\pi iv+1)\tilde{h}}\,e^{H(T)}\,{{\mathrm{d}}} \tilde{h}\right] \\ & \quad =\alpha e^{{-}rT}\,{\rm E}^{Q}\left[\frac{e^{(2\pi iu+\varrho_{1}+1)Y(T)}}{(2\pi iu+\varrho_{1})(2\pi iu+\varrho_{1}+1)}\left(\left.\frac{e^{(2\pi iv+1)\tilde{h}+H(T)}}{2\pi iv+1}\right\vert_{-\infty}^{{-}H(T) }\right)\right] \\ & \quad =\alpha e^{{-}rT}\,{\rm E}^{Q}\left[\frac{e^{(2\pi iu+\varrho_{1}+1)Y(T)}}{(2\pi iu+\varrho_{1})(2\pi iu+\varrho_{1}+1)}\times\frac{e^{-(2\pi iv)H(T)}}{2\pi iv+1}\right]. \end{align*}

We can find that $\mathscr {F}[C_1](u,v)$ and $\mathscr {F}[C_2](u,v)$ have similar structures.

Proof of Proposition 2.1. Recall the forms of $Y(T)$ and $H(T)$,

\begin{align*} Y(T)& =\ln(S(0))+\left(r-\frac{1}{2}\vartheta_{1}^{2}\sigma_{1}^{2}-\bar{k}_{1}\right) \frac{n+1}{2n}T-\frac{\beta_{1}^{2}}{2n}\sum_{j=1}^{n}\int_{0}^{t_{j}}a(s)^{2}\,{{\mathrm{d}}}s+\frac{\vartheta_{1}\sigma_{1}}{n}\sum_{j=1}^{n}\tilde{B}_{1}(t_{j})\nonumber \\ & \quad +\frac{\beta_{1}}{n}\sum_{j=1}^{n}\int_{0}^{t_{j}}a(s)\, {{\mathrm{d}}} \tilde{W}(s)+\frac{\vartheta_{1}\delta_{1}+\beta_{1}\theta}{n}\sum_{j=1}^{n}\tilde{X}(t_{j}) +\frac{\vartheta_{1}}{n}\sum_{j=1}^{n}\tilde{Y}_{1}(t_{j}), \end{align*}

and

\begin{align*} H(T)& =\ln(V(0))+(r-\frac{1}{2}\vartheta_{2}^{2}\sigma_{2}^{2}-\bar{k}_{2})T-\frac{1}{2}\beta_{2}^{2}\int_{0}^{T}a(s)^{2}\,{{\mathrm{d}}}s+\vartheta_{2}\sigma_{2}\tilde{B}_{2}(T)+\beta_{2}\int_{0}^{T}a(s)\, {{\mathrm{d}}} \tilde{W}(s)\nonumber\\ & \quad +(\vartheta_{2}\delta_{2}+\beta_{2}\theta)\tilde{X}(T)+\vartheta_{2}\tilde{Y}_{2}(T), \end{align*}

where $0\lt t_1\lt\cdots \lt t_n=T$ and $t_j=jT/n$. Substituting the above forms of $Y(T)$ and $H(T)$, we separate the items according to their relevance,

$${\rm E}[e^{p Y(T)+q H(T)}]=A_{1}(p,q)\cdot A_{2}(p,q)\cdot A_{3}(p,q)\cdot A_{4}(p,q)\cdot A_{5}(p,q)\cdot A_{6}(p,q).$$

We put all deterministic items in $A_{1}(p,q)$, that is,

$$A_{1}(p,q)=e^{p(\ln(S(0))+(r-\frac{1}{2}\vartheta_{1}^{2}\sigma_{1}^{2}-\bar{k}_{1})\frac{n+1}{2n}T-\frac{\beta_{1}^{2}}{2n}\sum_{j=1}^{n}\int_{0}^{t_{j}}a(s)^{2}\,{{\mathrm{d}}}s)+q(\ln(V(0))+(r-\frac{1}{2}\vartheta_{2}^{2}\sigma_{2}^{2}-\bar{k}_{2})T-\frac{1}{2}\beta_{2}^{2}\int_{0}^{T}a(s)^{2}\,{{\mathrm{d}}}s)},$$

and the other terms are listed below,

\begin{align*} A_{2}(p,q)& ={\rm E}^{Q}[e^{p\frac{\vartheta_{1}\sigma_{1}}{n}\sum_{j=1}^{n}\tilde{B}_{1}(t_{j})+q\vartheta_{2}\sigma_{2}\tilde{B}_{2}(T)}],\\ A_{3}(p,q)& ={\rm E}^{Q}[e^{p\frac{\beta_{1}}{n}\sum_{j=1}^{n}\int_{0}^{t_{j}}a(s)\, {{\mathrm{d}}} \tilde{W}(s)+q\beta_{2}\int_{0}^{T}a(s)\, {{\mathrm{d}}} \tilde{W}(s)}], \\ A_{4}(p,q)& ={\rm E}^{Q}[e^{p(\vartheta_{1}\delta_{1}+\beta_{1}\theta)\frac{1}{n}\sum_{j=1}^{n}\tilde{X}(t_{j})+q(\vartheta_{2}\delta_{2}+\beta_{2}\theta)\tilde{X}(T)}],\\ A_{5}(p,q)& ={\rm E}^{Q}[e^{p\vartheta_{1}\frac{1}{n}\sum_{j=1}^{n}\tilde{Y}_{1}(t_{j})}], \\ A_{6}(p,q)& ={\rm E}^{Q}[e^{q\vartheta_{2}\tilde{Y}_{2}(T)}]. \end{align*}

In the following, we deal with $A_{2}(p,q)$-$A_{6}(p,q)$ in turn. In $A_{2}(p,q)$, there are two correlated Brownian motions $\tilde {B}_{1}(t)$ and $\tilde {B}_{2}(t)$ with correlation coefficient $\rho$. We write $\tilde {B}_{2}(t)$ by introducing another standard Brownian motion $\tilde {B}_{3}(t)$, independent of $\tilde {B}_{1}(t)$. Based on the form of $\tilde {B}_{2}(t)= \rho \tilde {B}_{1}(t)+\sqrt {1-\rho ^{2}} \tilde {B}_{3}(t)$, one gets that

\begin{align*} A_{2}(p,q)& ={\rm E}^{Q}[e^{p\frac{\vartheta_{1}\sigma_{1}}{n}\sum_{j=1}^{n}\tilde{B}_{1}(t_{j})+q\vartheta_{2}\sigma_{2}\tilde{B}_{2}(T)}]\\ & ={\rm E}^{Q}[e^{p\frac{\vartheta_{1}\sigma_{1}}{n}\sum_{j=1}^{n}(n+1-j) \Delta \tilde{B}_{1}(t_{j})+q\vartheta_{2}\sigma_{2}\sum_{j=1}^{n}(\rho \Delta \tilde{B}_{1}(t_{j})+\sqrt{1-\rho^{2}}\Delta \tilde{B}_{3}(t_{j}))}] \\ & ={\rm E}^{Q}[e^{\sum_{j=1}^{n}[p\frac{\vartheta_{1}\sigma_{1}}{n}(n+1-j)+q\vartheta_{2}\sigma_{2}\rho]\Delta \tilde{B}_{1}(t_{j})+\sum_{j=1}^{n}q\vartheta_{2}\sigma_{2}\sqrt{1-\rho^{2}} \Delta \tilde{B}_{3}(t_{j})}] \\ & =\prod_{j=1}^{n}{\rm E}^{Q}[e^{[p\frac{\vartheta_{1}\sigma_{1}}{n}(n+1-j)+q\vartheta_{2}\sigma_{2}\rho]\Delta \tilde{B}_{1}(t_{j})}]\cdot{\rm E}^{Q}[e^{q\vartheta_{2}\sigma_{2}\sqrt{1-\rho^{2}}\tilde{B}_{3}(T)}] \\ & =\prod_{j=1}^{n}e^{\frac{1}{2}[p\frac{\vartheta_{1}\sigma_{1}}{n}(n+1-j)+q\vartheta_{2}\sigma_{2}\rho]^{2} \frac{T}{n}}\cdot e^{\frac{1}{2}q^{2}\vartheta_{2}^{2}\sigma_{2}^{2}(1-\rho^{2})T} \\ & =e^{\frac{1}{2}\sum_{j=1}^{n}[p\frac{\vartheta_{1}\sigma_{1}}{n}(n+1-j)+q\vartheta_{2}\sigma_{2}\rho]^{2} \frac{T}{n}+\frac{1}{2}q^{2}\vartheta_{2}^{2}\sigma_{2}^{2}(1-\rho^{2})T}. \end{align*}

In $A_{3}(p,q)$, the term $\int _{0}^{T}a(s)\, {{\mathrm {d}}} \tilde {W}(s)$ is normally distributed in nature, and hence, its expectation and variance are zero and $\int _{0}^{T}a(s)^{2}\,{{\mathrm {d}}}s$, respectively. Therefore, it is easy to obtain the following result:

\begin{align*} A_{3}(p,q)& ={\rm E}^{Q}[e^{p\frac{\beta_{1}}{n}\sum_{j=1}^{n}\int_{0}^{t_{j}}a(s) {{\mathrm{d}}} \tilde{W}(s)+q\beta_{2}\int_{0}^{T}a(s)\, {{\mathrm{d}}} \tilde{W}(s)}] \\ & ={\rm E}^{Q}[e^{\sum_{j=1}^{n}p\frac{\beta_{1}}{n}(n+1-j)\int_{t_{j-1}}^{t_{j}}a(s) {{\mathrm{d}}} \tilde{W}(s)+\sum_{j=1}^{n}q\beta_{2}\int_{t_{j-1}}^{t_{j}}a(s)\, {{\mathrm{d}}} \tilde{W}(s)}] \\ & =\prod_{j=1}^{n}{\rm E}^{Q}[e^{[p\frac{\beta_{1}}{n}(n+1-j)+q\beta_{2}]\int_{t_{j-1}}^{t_{j}}a(s)\, {{\mathrm{d}}} \tilde{W}(s)}] \\ & =e^{\frac{1}{2}\sum_{j=1}^{n}[p\frac{\beta_{1}}{n}(n+1-j)+q\beta_{2}]^{2} \int_{t_{j-1}}^{t_{j}}a(s)^{2}\,{{\mathrm{d}}}s}. \end{align*}

In $A_{4}(p,q)$ and $A_{5}(p,q)$, we meet the similar forms. Write $e^{\sum _{j=1}^{n}\tilde {X}(t_{j})}$ in the form of $e^{\sum _{j=1}^{n}(n+1-j) \Delta \tilde {X}_{j}}$, and through the property of stationary and independent increments of Lévy processes, we get that

\begin{align*} A_{4}(p,q)& ={\rm E}^{Q}[e^{p(\vartheta_{1}\delta_{1}+\beta_{1}\theta)\frac{1}{n}\sum_{j=1}^{n}\tilde{X}(t_{j})+q(\vartheta_{2}\delta_{2}+\beta_{2}\theta)\tilde{X}(T)}]\\ & ={\rm E}^{Q}[e^{p(\vartheta_{1}\delta_{1}+\beta_{1}\theta)\frac{1}{n}\sum_{j=1}^{n}(n+1-j) \Delta \tilde{X}_{j}+q(\vartheta_{2}\delta_{2}+\beta_{2}\theta)\sum_{j=1}^{n} \Delta \tilde{X}_{j}}] \\ & =\prod_{j=1}^{n}{\rm E}^{Q}[e^{i[{-}ip(\vartheta_{1}\delta_{1}+\beta_{1}\theta)\frac{n+1-j}{n}-iq(\vartheta_{2}\delta_{2}+\beta_{2}\theta)]\Delta \tilde{X}_{j}}] \\ & =\prod_{j=1}^{n}\psi _{\Delta X}({-}ip(\vartheta_{1}\delta_{1}+\beta_{1}\theta)\frac{n+1-j}{n}-iq(\vartheta_{2}\delta_{2}+\beta_{2}\theta)), \end{align*}

and

\begin{align*} A_{5}(p,q)& ={\rm E}^{Q}[e^{p\vartheta_{1}\frac{1}{n}\sum_{j=1}^{n}\tilde{Y}_{1}(t_{j})}] \\ & ={\rm E}^{Q}[e^{\sum_{j=1}^{n}p\frac{\vartheta_{1}}{n}(n+1-j)\, \Delta \tilde{Y}_{j}}] \\ & =\prod_{j=1}^{n}\psi _{\Delta Y}\left({-}ip\frac{\vartheta_{1}}{n}(n+1-j)\right). \end{align*}

Lastly, $A_{6}(p,q)$ can be simply written in the form of its characteristic function,

\begin{align*} A_{6}(p,q)& ={\rm E}^{Q}[e^{q\vartheta_{2}Y_{2}(T)}] \\ & =\psi_{Y_{2}}({-}iq\vartheta_{2}). \end{align*}

This completes the proof of Proposition 2.1.

Footnotes

1 European options with default risk are investigated in Klein and Inglis [Reference Klein and Inglis18,Reference Klein and Inglis19], Liao and Huang [Reference Liao and Huang26], Liang and Ren [Reference Liang and Ren24], Yang et al. [Reference Yang, Lee and Kim43], Niu and Wang [Reference Niu and Wang32], Wang et al. [Reference Wang, Wang and Zhou41], Yang et al. [Reference Yang, Ching, He and Siu44] and Liang and Wang [Reference Liang and Wang25].

2 A partial list of the studies on default-free Asian options includes Fusai and Meucci [Reference Fusai and Meucci15], Cai and Kou [Reference Cai and Kou5], Cai et al. [Reference Cai, Song and Kou6], Fusai and Kyriakou [Reference Fusai and Kyriakou14] and Song et al. [Reference Song, Cai and Kou34].

References

Antonelli, F., Ramponi, A., & Scarlatti, S. (2021). CVA and vulnerable options pricing by correlation expansions. Annals of Operation Research 299: 401427.10.1007/s10479-019-03367-zCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ballotta, L. & Kyriakou, I. (2014). Monte Carlo simulation of the CGMY process and option pricing. Journal of Futures Markets 34: 10951121.10.1002/fut.21647CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Brigo, D., Morini, M., & Pallavicini, A. (2013). Counterparty credit risk, collateral and funding: with pricing cases for all asset classes. New York: Wiley.10.1002/9781118818589CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Brunetti, C. & Caldarera, A. (2006). Asset prices and asset correlations in illiquid markets. Working Paper.Google Scholar
Cai, N. & Kou, S. (2012). Pricing Asian options under a hyper-exponential jump diffusion model. Operations Research 60: 6477.10.1287/opre.1110.1006CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cai, N., Song, Y., & Kou, S. (2015). A general framework for pricing Asian options under Markov processes. Operations Research 63: 540554.10.1287/opre.2015.1385CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Carr, P. & Madan, D. (1999). Option valuation using the fast fourier transform. Journal of Computational Finance 2: 6173.10.21314/JCF.1999.043CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Carr, P., Geman, H., Madan, D., & Yor, M. (2002). The fine structure of asset returns: an empirical investigation. Journal of Business 75: 305332.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cont, R. & Tankov, P. (2004). Non-parametric calibration of jump-diffusion option pricing models. Journal of Computational Finance 7: 149.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cruz, J. & Ševčovič, D. (2018). Option pricing in illiquid markets with jumps. Applied Mathematical Finance 25: 395415.10.1080/1350486X.2019.1585267CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Elliott, R., Chan, L., & Siu, T. (2005). Option pricing and Esscher transform under regime switching. Annals of Finance 1: 423432.10.1007/s10436-005-0013-zCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Figueroa-López, J., Gong, R., & Houdré, C. (2017). Third-order short-time expansions for close-to-the-money option prices under the CGMY model. Applied Mathematical Finance 24: 547574.10.1080/1350486X.2018.1429935CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Frame, S. & Ramezani, C. (2014). Bayesian estimation of asymmetric jump-diffusion processes. Annals of Financial Economics 9: 1450008.10.1142/S2010495214500080CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fusai, G. & Kyriakou, I. (2016). General optimized lower and upper bounds for discrete and continuous arithmetic Asian options. Mathematics of Operations Research 41: 531559.10.1287/moor.2015.0739CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fusai, G. & Meucci, A. (2008). Pricing discretely monitored Asian options under Lévy processes. Journal of Banking and Finance 32: 20762088.10.1016/j.jbankfin.2007.12.027CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Jeon, J., Yoon, J., & Kang, M. (2016). Valuing vulnerable geometric Asian options. Computers and Mathematics with Applications 71: 676691.10.1016/j.camwa.2015.12.038CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Klein, P. (1996). Pricing Black-Scholes options with correlated credit risk. Journal of Banking and Finance 20: 12111229.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Klein, P. & Inglis, M. (1999). Valuation of European options subject to financial distress and interest rate risk. Journal of Derivatives 6: 4456.10.3905/jod.1999.319118CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Klein, P. & Inglis, M. (2001). Pricing vulnerable European options when the option's payoff can increase the risk of financial distress. Journal of Banking and Finance 25: 9931012.10.1016/S0378-4266(00)00109-6CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kou, S. & Wang, H. (2004). Option pricing under a double exponential jump diffusion model. Management Science 50: 11781192.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Leippold, M. & Schärer, S. (2017). Discrete-time option pricing with stochastic liquidity. Journal of Banking and Finance 75: 116.10.1016/j.jbankfin.2016.11.014CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Li, Z., Zhang, W., & Liu, Y. (2018). Analytical valuation for geometric Asian options in illiquid markets. Physica A: Statistical Mechanics and its Applications 507: 175191.10.1016/j.physa.2018.05.069CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Li, Z., Zhang, W., Liu, Y., & Zhang, Y. (2019). Pricing discrete barrier options under jump-diffusion model with liquidity risk. International Review of Economics and Finance 59: 347368.10.1016/j.iref.2018.10.002CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Liang, G. & Ren, X. (2007). The credit risk and pricing of OTC options. Asia-Pacific Financial Markets 14: 4568.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Liang, G. & Wang, X. (2021). Pricing vulnerable options in a hybrid credit risk model driven by Heston-Nandi GARCH processes. Review of Derivatives Research 24: 130.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Liao, S. & Huang, H. (2005). Pricing Black-Scholes options with correlated interest rate risk and credit risk: an extension. Quantitative Finance 5: 443457.10.1080/14697680500362718CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Liu, H. & Yong, J. (2005). Option pricing with an illiquid underlying asset market. Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control 29: 21252156.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Madan, D. & Cherny, A. (2010). Markets as a counterparty: an introduction to conic finance. International Journal of Theoretical and Applied Finance 13: 11491177.10.1142/S0219024910006157CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Madan, D. & Schoutens, W. (2016). Applied conic finance. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Madan, D. & Yor, M. (2008). Representing the CGMY and Meixner Lévy processes as time changed Brownian motions. Journal of Computational Finance 12: 2747.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Merton, R. (1976). Option pricing when underlying stock returns are discontinuous. Journal of Financial Economics 3: 125144.10.1016/0304-405X(76)90022-2CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Niu, H. & Wang, D. (2016). Pricing vulnerable options with correlated jump-diffusion processes depending on various states of the economy. Quantitative Finance 16: 11291145.10.1080/14697688.2015.1090623CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Pasricha, P. & Goel, A. (2019). Pricing vulnerable power exchange options in an intensity based framework. Journal of Computational and Applied Mathematics 355: 106115.10.1016/j.cam.2019.01.019CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Song, Y., Cai, N., & Kou, S. (2018). Computable error bounds of Laplace inversion for pricing Asian options. Informs Journal on Computing 30: 634645.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Tian, L., Wang, G., Wang, X., & Wang, Y. (2014). Pricing vulnerable options with correlated credit risk under jump-diffusion processes. Journal of Futures Markets 34: 957979.10.1002/fut.21629CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Tsao, C. & Liu, C. (2012). Asian options with credit risks: pricing and sensitivity analysis. Emerging Markets Finance and Trade 48: 96115.10.2753/REE1540-496X4805S306CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wang, X. (2017). Differences in the prices of vulnerable options with different counterparties. Journal of Futures Markets 37: 148163.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wang, X. (2020). Analytical valuation of Asian options with counterparty risk under stochastic volatility models. Journal of Futures Markets 40: 410429.10.1002/fut.22064CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wang, X. (2020). Valuation of Asian options with default risk under GARCH models. International Review of Economics and Finance 70: 2740.10.1016/j.iref.2020.06.019CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wang, X. (2021). Pricing vulnerable options with jump risk and liquidity risk. Review of Derivatives Research 24: 243260.10.1007/s11147-021-09177-5CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wang, G., Wang, X., & Zhou, K. (2017). Pricing vulnerable options with stochastic volatility. Physica A: Statistical Mechanics and its Applications 485: 91103.10.1016/j.physa.2017.04.146CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Xu, G., Shao, X., & Wang, X. (2019). Analytical valuation of power exchange options with default risk. Finance Research Letters 28: 265274.10.1016/j.frl.2018.05.007CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Yang, S., Lee, M., & Kim, J. (2014). Pricing vulnerable options under a stochastic volatility model. Applied Mathematics Letters 34: 712.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Yang, Q., Ching, W., He, W., & Siu, T. (2019). Pricing vulnerable options under a Markov-modulated jump-diffusion model with fire sales. Journal of Industrial and Management Optimization 15: 293318.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Figure 0

Table 1. Asian option prices in three models. Model $1$ is the one proposed in this paper, which reduces to Model $2$ by discarding default risk and further to Model $3$ by assuming liquidity risk away.

Figure 1

FIGURE 1. Prices of Asian call options against time to maturities. The solid, dashed, dot-solid, dotted and dot-dashed lines correspond to prices of Asian options with ($G=G_0,\ M=M_0$), prices of Asian options with ($G=0.5G_0,\ M=M_0$), prices of Asian options with ($G=2G_0,\ M=M_0$), prices of Asian options with ($G=G_0,\ M=0.5M_0$) and prices of Asian options with ($G=G_0,\ M=2M_0$), respectively.

Figure 2

FIGURE 2. Risk compensation $\bar {k}_{1}$ against the parameter $G$ in the CGMY process with $C=C_0, M=M_0,\ Y=Y_0$.

Figure 3

FIGURE 3. Prices of Asian call options against strike prices. The solid, dashed, dot-solid, dotted and dot-dashed lines correspond to prices of Asian options with ($G=G_0,\ M=M_0$), prices of Asian options with ($G=0.5G_0,\ M=M_0$), prices of Asian options with ($G=2G_0,\ M=M_0$), prices of Asian options with ($G=G_0,\ M=0.5M_0$) and prices of Asian options with ($G=G_0,\ M=2M_0$), respectively.

Figure 4

FIGURE 4. Prices of Asian call options against the values of $\theta$. The solid, dashed, dot-solid, dotted and dot-dashed lines correspond to prices of Asian options with ($G=G_0,\ M=M_0$), prices of Asian options with ($G=0.5G_0,\ M=M_0$), prices of Asian options with ($G=2G_0,\ M=M_0$), prices of Asian options with ($G=G_0,\ M=0.5M_0$) and prices of Asian options with ($G=G_0,\ M=2M_0$), respectively.

Figure 5

FIGURE 5. Prices of Asian call options against the values of the parameter $Y$ in the CGMY process. The solid, dashed, dot-solid, dotted and dot-dashed lines correspond to prices of Asian options with ($G=G_0,\ M=M_0$), prices of Asian options with ($G=0.5G_0,\ M=M_0$), prices of Asian options with ($G=2G_0,\ M=M_0$), prices of Asian options with ($G=G_0,\ M=0.5M_0$) and prices of Asian options with ($G=G_0,\ M=2M_0$), respectively.

Figure 6

FIGURE 6. Prices of vulnerable Asian call options against maturities. The solid, dashed, dot-solid, dotted and dot-dashed lines correspond to prices of Asian options with ($G=G_0,\ M=M_0$), prices of Asian options with ($G=0.5G_0,\ M=M_0$), prices of Asian options with ($G=2G_0,\ M=M_0$), prices of Asian options with ($G=G_0,\ M=0.5M_0$) and prices of Asian options with ($G=G_0,\ M=2M_0$), respectively.

Figure 7

FIGURE 7. Prices of vulnerable Asian call options against strike prices. The solid, dashed, dot-solid, dotted and dot-dashed lines correspond to prices of Asian options with ($G=G_0,\ M=M_0$), prices of Asian options with ($G=0.5G_0,\ M=M_0$), prices of Asian options with ($G=2G_0,\ M=M_0$), prices of Asian options with ($G=G_0,\ M=0.5M_0$) and prices of Asian options with ($G=G_0,\ M=2M_0$), respectively.

Figure 8

FIGURE 8. Prices of vulnerable Asian call options against the values of $\theta$. The solid, dashed, dot-solid, dotted and dot-dashed lines correspond to prices of Asian options with ($G=G_0,\ M=M_0$), prices of Asian options with ($G=0.5G_0,\ M=M_0$), prices of Asian options with ($G=2G_0,\ M=M_0$), prices of Asian options with ($G=G_0,\ M=0.5M_0$) and prices of Asian options with ($G=G_0,\ M=2M_0$), respectively.

Figure 9

FIGURE 9. Prices of vulnerable Asian call options against the parameter $Y$ in the CGMY process. The solid, dashed, dot-solid, dotted and dot-dashed lines correspond to prices of Asian options with ($G=G_0,\ M=M_0$), prices of Asian options with ($G=0.5G_0,\ M=M_0$), prices of Asian options with ($G=2G_0,\ M=M_0$), prices of Asian options with ($G=G_0,\ M=0.5M_0$) and prices of Asian options with ($G=G_0,\ M=2M_0$), respectively.

Figure 10

FIGURE 10. Price differences between Asian call options and vulnerable Asian call options against against the values of $\theta$. The solid, dashed, dot-solid, dotted and dot-dashed lines correspond to ($G=G_0,\ M=M_0$), ($G=0.5G_0,\ M=M_0$), ($G=2G_0,\ M=M_0$), ($G=G_0,\ M=0.5M_0$) and ($G=G_0,\ M=2M_0$), respectively.

Figure 11

FIGURE 11. Prices of vulnerable Asian call options against the recover rate $\alpha$. The solid, dashed, dot-solid, dotted and dot-dashed lines correspond to prices of Asian options with ($G=G_0,\ M=M_0$), prices of Asian options with ($G=0.5G_0,\ M=M_0$), prices of Asian options with ($G=2G_0,\ M=M_0$), prices of Asian options with ($G=G_0,\ M=0.5M_0$) and prices of Asian options with ($G=G_0,\ M=2M_0$), respectively.

Figure 12

FIGURE 12. Prices of vulnerable Asian call options against initial values of issuer's assets $V(0)$. The solid, dashed, dot-solid, dotted and dot-dashed lines correspond to prices of Asian options with ($G=G_0,\ M=M_0$), prices of Asian options with ($G=0.5G_0,\ M=M_0$), prices of Asian options with ($G=2G_0,\ M=M_0$), prices of Asian options with ($G=G_0,\ M=0.5M_0$) and prices of Asian options with ($G=G_0,\ M=2M_0$), respectively.

Figure 13

FIGURE 13. Prices of vulnerable Asian call options against the default barrier $D$. The solid, dashed, dot-solid, dotted and dot-dashed lines correspond to prices of Asian options with ($G=G_0,\ M=M_0$), prices of Asian options with ($G=0.5G_0,\ M=M_0$), prices of Asian options with ($G=2G_0,\ M=M_0$), prices of Asian options with ($G=G_0,\ M=0.5M_0$) and prices of Asian options with ($G=G_0,\ M=2M_0$), respectively.