Hostname: page-component-586b7cd67f-2brh9 Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-11-22T12:13:35.341Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

When Are Gender Quotas Fulfilled? Party Strategy and Historical Memory in Ukrainian City Elections

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  20 June 2022

Frank C. Thames*
Affiliation:
Texas Tech University
Stephen Bloom
Affiliation:
Southern Illinois University
*
*Corresponding author. Email: [email protected]
Rights & Permissions [Opens in a new window]

Abstract

Many studies have investigated why countries adopt gender quotas for their elections. In this article, we answer a different question: why do political parties comply with gender quotas when the costs of noncompliance are absent or minimal? To answer this question, we analyze data from 1,600 party lists and 106 parties competing across 121 cities in the 2015 municipal elections in Ukraine. Our subnational approach tests whether contextual factors flagged by the broader gender literature explain variation in compliance across localities. The results of our models support our contention that Ukrainian political parties behaved strategically in terms of nominations and quota compliance. We find that urbanization and female incumbency fueled quota compliance. Parties, however, were less likely to comply with quotas in cities with more Ukrainian speakers. We suggest that the politics of memory explain this outcome, as Ukrainian speakers are more likely to remember of the costs of Soviet rule.

Type
Research Article
Copyright
© The Author(s), 2022. Published by Cambridge University Press on behalf of the Women, Gender, and Politics Research Section of the American Political Science Association

On October 25, 2015, Ukrainian voters went to the polls to elect city councils in 121 major cities.Footnote 1 For the first time in any election in the postindependence period, Ukraine employed a gender quota for all party lists. The Law on Local Elections, which was passed by parliament on July 14, 2015, established a 30% gender quota for all party lists. The original legislation, however, did not contain any penalty for not adhering to the quota, and the Central Election Commission (CEC) waited until September 23, 2015, to rule that parties that failed to meet the quota would remain eligible to participate in the election. While the CEC decision was appealed through the courts, its decision was ultimately upheld. Consequently, parties knew prior to the election that adherence to the gender quota was voluntary. Yet, when you examine the lists of the 106 Ukrainian political parties who competed in the city elections, you find a striking result—quite a few parties complied with the quotas even without official sanctions. Of the total 1,630 lists, parties met the 30% quota 79.8% of the time. In fact, the average percentage of women in city legislators increased to 26.8% from 21% elected in 2010.

Research shows that parties are often unwilling to comply with quotas (Bjarnegård and Zetterberg Reference Bjarnegård and Zetterberg2016; Hinojosa Reference Hinojosa2012). Thus, quota laws often contain punishments for parties that fail to abide by them. Research finds that quotas with stronger enforcement mechanisms are more likely to be followed than others (e.g., Davidson-Schmich Reference Davidson-Schmich2016; Schwindt-Bayer Reference Schwindt-Bayer2009; Baldez Reference Baldez2002; Htun and Jones Reference Htun, Jones, Craske and Molyneux2002; Murray Reference Murray2007). Yet, empirical studies of the effects of quotas on women’s representation find that quotas with no punishments or weak ones are still correlated with increases in women’s representation (Schwindt-Bayer Reference Schwindt-Bayer2009). The fact that quotas appear to increase women’s representation even if they are weakly enforced raises the question—why do parties abide by quotas that impose no formal costs for noncompliance?Footnote 2

Existing research suggests several explanations for this empirical pattern. Multiple studies have found that party characteristics matter, such as the commitment to gender equality (Kittilson Reference Kittilson2006; Krook Reference Krook2009; Murray, Krook, and Opello Reference Murray, Krook and Opello2012; Opello Reference Opello2006), the centralization of candidate selection mechanisms (Bjarnegård and Zetterberg Reference Bjarnegård and Zetterberg2016), the desire by party leaders to increase control over nominations (Weeks Reference Weeks2018), or the level of party institutionalization (Wiley Reference Wylie2018). Other research argues that parties abide by quotas to attract voters (e.g, Davidson-Schmich Reference Davidson-Schmich2006; Kittilson Reference Kittilson2006; Meier Reference Meier2004; Murray, Krook, and Opello Reference Murray, Krook and Opello2012). If parties perceive an electoral advantage to nominating female candidates, then it is likely that parties will have an incentive to abide by quota requirements to increase their share of female voters and other voters interested in gender equality.

The electoral logic behind quota compliance, we suggest, is complicated. We argue that variation in compliance for weakly enforced quotas is driven by two main factors: party ideology and characteristics of electoral districts. Parties with an ideological commitment are more likely to comply with weak quotas. In addition, we argue that the variation in preferences among voters implies that not all voters will respond to quota compliance similarly. The different possible voter reactions to female candidates suggest that parties may have an incentive to gauge their compliance based on the political and economic context of districts in which they compete for votes.

To test our arguments, we examine the party lists of all 106 parties that competed in the 2015 city elections in Ukraine. Ukraine provides us with several advantages. First, it is a good example of a case in which a weak quota existed; however, there is strong evidence that parties met the quota in multiple electoral districts. Second, there is significant regional variation in support for women’s representation tied to historical memories of the Soviet Union. We expect greater compliance with quotas in localities with more Russian-speaking voters, and less support in localities with more Ukrainian-speaking voters. Russian speakers are more likely to hold positive views of the Soviet past, while Ukrainian speakers are more likely to remember the costs of Soviet rule. As we explain in more detail later in the text, the divergent attitudes of Ukrainian and Russian speakers with respect to the Soviet past are a product of the different lived experiences of Ukrainians in western, central, southern, and eastern Ukraine. Several recent works on historical memory have used events in the Soviet period—including deaths during the1932–34 Ukrainian famine or Holodomor (Rozenas and Zhukov Reference Rozenas and Zhukov2019) and the indiscriminate repression in localities in western Ukraine in the 1940s and 1950s (Rozenas, Schutte, and Zhukov Reference Rozenas, Schutte and Zhukov2017) to predict current electoral behavior in Ukraine.

Our statistical analysis finds that parties acted strategically. Parties placed more women on lists in localities with a higher percentage of female deputies elected in 2010, and fewer women on lists in localities with more Ukrainian-speaking voters. In terms of quota compliance, we find again that parties were more likely to meet the quota in cities where more women were elected in 2010, and less likely to meet it in localities with larger Ukrainian-speaking populations. We find no evidence that party ideology independently affected the number of women on lists or quota compliance. These findings support our argument that parties acted strategically when nominating candidates and making decisions about quota compliance. They also support our argument that the electoral chances of female candidates and support for gender quotas vary across localities in Ukraine. Political parties anticipated the differential support for female candidates across Ukraine when making decisions about adding women to lists and meeting the gender quota. We submit that parties looked at past elections, the ethnolinguistic composition of the electorate, and the different memories of quotas and the Soviet past across Ukraine’s regions when making these strategic decisions.

This article makes four contributions to the literature. First, we analyze quota fulfillment at the subnational level. As stated by Davidson-Schmich (Reference Davidson-Schmich2016, 212), “One reason that the implementation of party quotas is understudied is that much of the research on women’s representation is focused on the national level.” Second, this research adds to our understanding of women’s representation in postcommunist Ukraine by looking beyond the national level to the possible causes of regional differences in women’s representation at the local level. Third, it extends our understanding of the strategic behavior of political parties in terms of quota compliance. While there is a significant amount of research on quota adoption, quota compliance is less studied. Fourth, we apply the politics of memory to study quota compliance. While multiple scholars have studied the effect of Soviet legacies on gender politics in Central and Eastern Europe (Dahlerup and Gaber Reference Dahlerup and Gaber2017; Horn Reference Horn2008; Kapoor Reference Kapoor2016), we analyze how the Soviet legacy plays out differently across Ukraine’s regions and ethnic groups.

The article proceeds as follows. First, we review the literature on quota compliance to develop our theory about how context affects the politics of quota compliance. Second, we discuss gender and electoral politics in Ukraine. In this section, we explain the specifics of the Ukrainian case and develop hypotheses that are in line with our theoretical expectations. Third, we present a quantitative analysis of the 2015 Ukrainian local elections. Our empirical results demonstrate that Ukrainian parties responded strategically to the context of the cities that they competed in when deciding on nomination strategies and quota compliance.

Understanding Quota Compliance

Broadly, there are three major types of gender quotas—reserved seat quotas, legislative quotas, and party quotas (Krook Reference Krook2007). Reserved seat quotas specify that a certain percentage of legislative seats must be held by female legislators. Much more common are compulsory party quotas that require political parties to nominate a certain percentage of female candidates (Tripp and Kang Reference Tripp and Kang2008). Such quotas are adopted by states and apply to all political parties. Finally, parties may voluntarily adopt quotas that require them to nominate slates that contain a certain percentage of women.

There is ample evidence that quotas increase women’s representation. Yet, parties often fail to comply with compulsory party quotas, even when there are costs for noncompliance, and with voluntary party quotas, which the parties adopt themselves (Bjarnegård and Zetterberg Reference Bjarnegård and Zetterberg2016; Hinojosa Reference Hinojosa2012). For parties, quota compliance presents a challenge. Parties are often wary of complying with quotas since meeting them challenges the existing power structure that favors men (Bjarnegård and Zetterberg Reference Bjarnegård and Zetterberg2016). After all, quotas require nominating more women, which entails replacing male candidates with female ones (Murray Reference Murray2007). Since quotas can destabilize the status quo, it is not a surprise that parties will, at times, resist them.

The reluctance of parties to comply with quotas does raise the question, why do parties decide to comply with quotas? Murray (Reference Murray2007) suggests three arguments to explain why parties implement quotas. First, the ideological approach argues that some parties have a greater ideological affinity for quotas than do others. Three factors push parties to ignore other factors and embrace quotas—whether parties display ideological support for the goal of gender equality, whether they agree that state intervention is necessary to solve the problem, and whether the party’s ideological support is strong enough to overcome obstacles to quotas (Murray Reference Murray2007). Current research supports this argument, showing that parties with a commitment to gender equity are more like to adopt quotas than are other parties (Kittilson Reference Kittilson2006; Krook Reference Krook2009; Murray, Krook, and Opello Reference Murray, Krook and Opello2012; Opello Reference Opello2006). Davidson-Schmich (Reference Davidson-Schmich2016) argues, however, that the adoption of quotas by parties across the ideological spectrum in the German case suggests that ideology alone is not sufficient to explain party quota adoption in all contexts.

Second, the institutional approach suggests that variation in quota compliance is explained by variation in institutions, such as electoral systems, party systems, or the quota legislation. Bjarnegård and Zetterberg (Reference Bjarnegård and Zetterberg2016) show that more bureaucratized candidate mechanisms increase compliance versus less formal ones.Footnote 3 Htun and Jones (Reference Htun, Jones, Craske and Molyneux2002) find that party quotas are more effective in closed-list proportional representation (PR) systems than they are in open-list PR systems; however, other research demonstrates that quotas in open-list PR systems are effective (Matland Reference Matland and Dahlerup2006; Schmidt and Saunders Reference Schmidt and Saunders2004). Wylie (Reference Wylie2018) argues that weakly institutionalized parties lack the resources to support female candidates and that this explains, in part, why Brazilian parties failed to comply with gender quotas.

Another factor is the compliance mechanism. There is a significant amount of research demonstrating that quotas with effective compliance requirements produce better results (Baldez Reference Baldez2002; Davidson-Schmich Reference Davidson-Schmich2006, Reference Davidson-Schmich2016; Htun and Jones Reference Htun, Jones, Craske and Molyneux2002; Schwindt-Bayer Reference Schwindt-Bayer2009). Murray (Reference Murray2007) argues that the funding penalties for quota non-fulfillment in France push smaller parties, who cannot afford losses in party funds, to abide by the quota, but not larger parties, which can afford the losses. Davidson-Schmich (Reference Davidson-Schmich2016) notes that while the voluntary party quotas enacted by German parties are written to be legally binding, the quota rules of many parties contained loopholes that allowed them to avoid fulfilling them under certain circumstances.

Finally, the electoral competition approach argues that quota compliance is the result of strategic behavior by parties seeking to maximize votes. Assuming that parties are rational actors whose primary preference is winning seats, parties will nominate candidates who are best able to secure votes, ignoring ideological or other factors. If parties assume that voters are less likely to vote for female than male candidates, then parties will discriminate against female candidates. The literature on electoral systems, for example, finds that women are less likely to be elected in systems that create personal vote incentives in comparison with more party-centric systems (Murray Reference Murray2007; Rule Reference Rule1987; Thames and Williams Reference Thames and Williams2010). This finding is explained, in part, by the concerns of party leaders that voters prefer male candidates. Thus, nominating female candidates risks losing vote share.Footnote 4

However, electoral competition may create incentives for nominating female candidates. One of the main explanations for the adoption of gender quotas assumes that parties use quotas to capture female votes (Davidson-Schmich Reference Davidson-Schmich2006; Kittilson Reference Kittilson2006; Meier Reference Meier2004; Murray, Krook, and Opello Reference Murray, Krook and Opello2012). The need to remain competitive among female voters pushes parties to support quotas when their opponents do (Davidson-Schmich Reference Davidson-Schmich2006; Giger et al. Reference Giger, Holli, Lefkofridi and Wass2014; Matland and Studlar Reference Matland and Studlar1996; Wängnerud Reference Wängnerud2000).Footnote 5 Electoral competition is seen by some as a crucial incentive for male elites to adopt quotas (Baldez Reference Baldez2002; Fréchette, Maniquet, and Morelli Reference Frechette, Maniquet and Morelli2008; Weeks Reference Weeks2018). Based on this logic, parties will fully implement quotas to the extent that it increases their vote share. Conversely, parties will avoid implementing quotas in situations in which it would lose them votes.

How voters respond to the gender of candidates depends on their ideology. There is evidence that voters who share more egalitarian attitudes as well as those who embrace left-wing ideologies are more likely to vote for female candidates (Caul Reference Caul1999; Dolan Reference Dolan2008; Kittilson Reference Kittilson2006; Salmond Reference Salmond2006). Religious and nationalist voters and parties, on the other hand, might be less open to female candidates. Regional and religious proxies for attitudes toward women appear to correlate with women’s representation in cross-national research (Tripp and Kang Reference Tripp and Kang2008). Inglehart and Norris (Reference Inglehart and Norris2003) find that less religious societies are more likely to hold attitudes that support gender equality and, by extension, female representation. National-level indicators, however, might mask variation within countries. Setzler (Reference Setzler2015) argues that support for women’s representation in Latin America varies based on religious faith. Nationalism has also been shown to depress female representation by stressing male leadership traits (Banerjee Reference Banerjee and Ghadially2007).Footnote 6 There is also research that finds less support for female candidates among voters on the far right (Erzeel and Caluwaerts Reference Erzeel and Caluwaerts2015; Golder et al. Reference Golder, Stephenson, Van der Straeten, Blais, Bol, Harfst and Laslier2017).

Political parties do matter. Badas and Stauffer (Reference Badas and Stauffer2019) find that gender affinity voting is more common in nonpartisan contexts than in partisan ones. This suggests that the likelihood that female, or even male, voters will support female candidates depends on partisanship. Dolan (Reference Dolan2014) argues that voter perceptions of candidates are filtered by partisanship. While there is strong evidence that voters evaluate candidates partly based on abstract gender stereotypes that often lead them to devalue female candidates (e.g., Fox and Smith Reference Fox and Smith1998; Huddy and Terkildsen Reference Huddy and Terkildsen1993; Lawless Reference Lawless2004), the effect of these stereotypes is diminished because of the importance of partisan concerns.

For parties seeking to maximize votes through quota compliance, the trick is identifying when and where compliance increases votes. Valdini (Reference Valdini2012) argues that party leaders are aware that voters may use gender as a cue, which may have negative connotations for some voters. What types of populations are more likely to support female candidates? Research finds correlations between district socioeconomic factors and support for female candidates. Districts and states that are wealthier, more urbanized, and feature less traditional political cultures are more likely to nominate and elect women (Diamond Reference Diamond1977; Fox Reference Fox2000; Hill Reference Hill1981; Nechemias Reference Nechemias1987; Ondercin and Welch Reference Ondercin and Welch2009). Thus, voters’ support for female candidates may vary based on local demographic factors.

Based on the foregoing discussion, we have two expectations concerning quota compliance. First, we expect that parties will behave strategically in terms of quota compliance. If the support for female legislators is not universal even among female voters, then parties have a strong incentive to behave strategically in terms of quota compliance. In systems in which the costs of compliance are high, it may not make sense for parties to comply with quotas, as the costs of doing so may outweigh the electoral benefits. In systems with weaker costs of noncompliance, parties have a strong incentive to uphold quotas in those areas where voters are more predisposed to support female candidates and not comply in areas where voters are, on average, less supportive of female candidates.

Second, we expect that the patterns of compliance will be heavily dependent upon context within countries. Support for female candidates should vary based on differences in key socioeconomic and demographic variables, not only between but, most importantly, within countries. In addition, compliance should vary based on important institutional differences such as electoral rules and compliance costs.

The Ukrainian Case

There is strong evidence of a patriarchal, traditional political culture in postcommunist Ukraine (e.g., Galligan and Clavero Reference Galligan and Clavero2008; Hankivsky and Salnykova Reference Hankivsky and Salnykova2010; Hrycak Reference Hrycak2005, Reference Hrycak2006, Reference Hrycak2010, Reference Hrycak2011; LaFont Reference LaFont2001; Martseniuk Reference Martseniuk and Chernova2016; Pyshulina Reference Ol’ha2016; Rubchak Reference Rubchak2012; Thames Reference Thames2018). For many, the role of women is limited to child rearing and home life. As a result, one can find only weak support for women as political leaders. A 2012 survey of Ukrainian adults found that 40% of respondents preferred male over female candidates and 77% believed that men were better suited for politics (Lake, Gotoff, and Pondel Reference Lake, Gotoff and Pondel2012). With the possible exception of figures such as Yuliia Tymoshenko—who was twice prime minister—women remain outside of traditional parties.

Yet, if you unpack the data, you find that the effect of gender on electoral outcomes in Ukraine is more complicated than it may seem. For example, research on elections to the national legislature—the Rada—finds that women make up an increasing number of legislators. While women constituted a mere 12.1% of members of parliament in 2014 (Martseniuk Reference Martseniuk and Chernova2016, 236), that share increased to 20.8% following the 2019 elections.Footnote 7 The research on women competing in single-member district (SMD) elections to the Rada shows that voters do not discriminate against female candidates; however, parties are more likely to nominate women in PR elections than in SMD elections (Thames Reference Thames2018). Thus, there is evidence that while discriminatory attitudes do exist, Ukrainian parties and voters will support female candidates.

In addition, Ukraine provides us an opportunity to analyze quota compliance at the local level, which remains understudied not just with respect to Ukraine but worldwide. Ukraine adopted a compulsory 30% party gender quota for the 2015 local elections. The quota was added to the Law on Local Elections, which passed in parliament on July 14, 2015, by an amendment proposed by Yurii Lutsenko, the leader of the pro-presidential Block of Petro Poroshenko (Blok Petra Poroshenka, BPP) (Antoniuk Reference Antoniuk2015, 145–47). While the law was signed by President Poroshenko, quota enforcement remained unsettled, as no costs were outlined in the legislation. On September 23, 2015, the CEC concluded that the failure to meet the quota did not prevent parties from registering party lists. On September 28, the decision was challenged in court with an appeal by deputies from the Self-Help (Samopomich) Party, which actively ran on the gender quota. The Kyiv Appellate Court sided with the Samopomich deputies and revoked the CEC decision. This decision, however, was further appealed to the High Administrative Court of Ukraine, which eventually upheld the CEC decision.Footnote 8 This meant that parties were not punished for failing to meet the quota. Consequently, while Ukraine adopted a compulsory party quota, the lack of enforcement mechanism meant that quota compliance was essentially voluntary.Footnote 9

Similar disputes also occurred at the regional level. On October 2, 2015, the Volyn’ Regional Electoral Commission denied the registration of lists from four parties that did not meet the gender quota. The candidates who were denied registration took their cases to the L’viv Appellate Court, which sided on behalf of the candidates whose lists were not registered. Oksana Yarosh, a political scientist from Volyn’, explained the lack of adherence to the gender quota in the following way: “as parties explained, the reason for not abiding by the gender quota (was) the absence of sanctions [tse vidsutnist’ sanktsii].”Footnote 10

Political actors were betting that courts at the regional or national level were unlikely to affirm the mandatory gender quota and block the registration of lists that failed to meet it. These court decisions should not be seen as a battle between political institutions. Ukrainian politicians understood which side was likely to win in the end. Ukraine’s judiciary is not independent, but rather “politicized and submissive” (Popova and Beers Reference Popova and Beers2020, 137). In this light, it is not odd that that the party that proposed the quota in the first place—the pro-presidential BPP—only adhered to it for 65% of its lists and made certain that the courts allowed the CEC to register lists that did not meet the gender quota. President Poroshenko had the ability to change the makeup of the CEC, whose members had been installed by his predecessor, Viktor Yanukovych. In the end, Poroshenko decided to keep them, likely because they showed their lack of independence. Ukrainian courts have been especially subservient to the government when it comes to electoral law (Popova Reference Popova2010, 1220–21).

Quota compliance can vary based on institutional factors such as the electoral system. In this case, all Ukrainian local elections utilized the same electoral system, allowing us to hold the electoral system constant across all cases. The electoral system employed to elect local governments in 2015 was new, and complicated, fundamentally changing the electoral rules that are used in provinces (oblasty), cities (mista), districts (raiony), and urban districts (raiony u mistakh). In Ukraine, the system is often referred to as open-list proportional representation. However, it differs fundamentally from other open-list PR systems. While the system awards seats proportionally to candidates who pass the electoral threshold, there is no intraparty competition for votes.Footnote 11

Intraparty dynamics might explain why women are not placed on lists. In most cases, party leaders maintained significant control over nominations. Rahat and Hazan (Reference Rahat and Hazan2001) place the potential selectorates of parties along a continuum from exclusive to inclusive. Using this framework, Ukrainian political parties would likely be considered exclusive. When asked how parties formed their lists in the 2012 parliamentary elections, Viktor Chumak, of the Ukrainian Democratic Alliance for Reform, explained that the decisions were generally made by the “members of the Politboro of the parties and rather influential groups [vliiatel’nykh grupp] in the party.”Footnote 12 If this is the case, men are likely overrepresented in the selectorates of most Ukrainian parties. In a forum on women’s representation organized by the Committee of Voters of Ukraine in the western Ukrainian city of Rivne in 2016, participants pointed out that increased female representation depended, beyond simply quotas, on parties themselves becoming more friendly (druzhnimy) toward women.Footnote 13 As these were local elections, local party members are likely to play an active role in candidate selection. We expect that these local party members broadly share the attitudes of a given locality with respect to the electoral viability of female candidates and the benefits of enforcing the gender quota. We argue that these attitudes are also shaped by the broader politics of memory.

Our theory claims that parties need to compete for votes; therefore, they will comply with quotas in cities where voters are more likely to support female candidates. On average, 79.8% of party lists in cities met the 30% gender quota. Why was compliance so high in this case? As indicated previously, there is evidence that quotas with weak or no enforcement often increase women’s representation (Schwindt-Bayer Reference Schwindt-Bayer2009). In addition, recent research on national elections in Ukraine finds little evidence that voters discriminate against female candidates (Thames Reference Thames2018). Thus, it is likely that parties have less fear that nominating women will undermine their votes. It is also likely that uncertainty over the quota enforcement specifics created an incentive for parties to meet the threshold to avoid possible sanctions.

Yet, there was significant variation in the number of lists that met the quota by party. Figure 1 plots the percentage of city lists by major party where parties met the 30% gender quota.Footnote 14 The data presented in Figure 2 reveal significant variation in quota compliance among major Ukrainian parties in the election. The Unity Party, which competed in only four cities, met the quota on all its lists. Yet, Trust Deeds met the quota in only 50% of cities.

Figure 1. Percentage of lists meeting quota by major party.

Figure 2. Average percentage of party lists in city elections meeting the quota by region.

What could explain the results in Figure 1? As discussed previously, quota adoption and compliance can vary by party ideology.Footnote 15 It is not easy to place Ukrainian political parties on a traditional left-right economic continuum. We distinguish here between left and ethnonationalist parties. While most parties in Ukraine offer voters populist economic appeals, especially before elections, parties that we code as left call for increasing the role of the state in the economy and maintaining social guarantees inherited from the Soviet era. Ukrainian parties also differ in their attitudes toward the Soviet past, relations with Russia, and the role of ethnic Ukrainians and the Ukrainian language in the polity. This ethnopolitical continuum has been a constant feature of elections since independence, but it has arguably hardened in the aftermath of Russia’s annexation of Crimea and the war with Russian-backed separatists in eastern Ukraine. Parties that we code as ethnonationalist aim their messages at Ukrainian speakers and support ethnic Ukrainian culture, traditions, and family and religious values. Ethnonationalist parties played key roles in anti-regime mobilization that initiated and sustained both the Orange Revolution in 2004–05 and the Euro-Maidan protests in 2013–14. A small number of parties that voiced the group-based demands of Hungarian and Russian speakers were also coded as ethnonationalist, as the broader scholarly literature suggests that ethnonationalist parties are less supportive of female representation. Ethnonationalist parties that seek the votes of Russian speakers generally look more favorably on the Soviet past and welcome closer ties with Russia. The Opposition Block, which emerged out of the ashes of the Party of Regions—the governing party of former president Viktor Yanukovych—currently aims its ethnonationalist messages at Russian-speaking voters.

How would the ideological positioning of Ukrainian parties along this ethnopolitical continuum affect their nomination strategies vis-à-vis female candidates? Ethnonationalist parties are more socially conservative and support traditional family values and gender roles. Many of these parties have their roots in Rukh, the Ukrainian national independence movement. While women participated in organizations that fought against Soviet rule, these organizations were typically founded on nationalist and traditional family values, and they were generally opposed to women’s political equality (Hrycak Reference Hrycak2006, Reference Hrycak2010). Ethnonationalist parties’ support of traditional family values is reinforced by Ukraine’s various Orthodox and Uniate churches. Even when women are employed, they are expected to maintain the home and rear the children. Bolzendahl and Gracheva (Reference Bolzendahl and Gracheva2018) find that opposition to feminism and gay rights in Eastern Europe is much higher among individuals who strongly identify with their nation. These individuals view the imposition of these “Western” norms as a violation of their national sovereignty.

Some ethnonationalists go so far as to claim that the 2015 gender quota was alien to Ukraine and imposed from abroad. Mar’ian Krеkoten’, a deputy from the extreme-right Svoboda (Freedom) party on the city council in Ternopil’ in western Ukraine, claimed that one had to be a “European idiot” to support the quota and suggested that “positive discrimination” was nonetheless sex discrimination and prohibited by the Ukrainian constitution.Footnote 16 Ukrainian ethnonationalist parties traditionally reject feminism and have advocated for legislation that would punish those who spread “gay propaganda.” Some groups have gone further. Gays and lesbians in Ukraine have been routinely attacked by members of nationalist and extreme-right groups. The hostility against those participating in gay pride marches is so intense that the police have had to form human shields to separate gay rights supporters from extreme-right attackers (Hrybanov and Kravchuk Reference Hrybanov and Kravchuk2018, 138–41). We hypothesize, therefore, that ethnonationalist parties are less likely to nominate female candidates and comply with quotas than are other parties.

Left-wing parties in Ukraine tend to be more statist and seek to maintain increase the role of the state in the economy, despite the already huge role played by the state in Ukraine’s semireformed economy. In the past, these voters often gravitated to socialist and communist parties. Russian speakers make up a major constituency of left parties. Not surprisingly, left parties also tend to look more favorably on the Soviet past, and call for the government to live up to Soviet-era “social guarantees.” We hypothesize, therefore, that left parties are more likely to nominate female candidates and comply with quotas than are other parties.

We believe, however, that differences in party ideology explain only part of the variation in quota compliance. Our theory emphasizes that contextual factors will also matter. In Ukraine, variation in party support, urbanization, and ethnicity exhibits a strong regional cleavage that defines Ukrainian politics (Bloom and Shulman Reference Bloom and Shulman2011; Holovakha and Panina Reference Holovakha and Panina1998; Katchanovski Reference Katchanovski2006; Khmelko and Wilson Reference Khmelko, Wilson and Kuzio1998; Wilson Reference Wilson1997, Reference Wilson2005). Differences in views from western to eastern Ukraine—including on controversial issues such as language use (Ukrainian or Russian) or NATO membership—are, at least in part, rooted in different historical experiences (Riabchuk Reference Riabchuk2003, 28–37). Western Ukraine was not incorporated into the Soviet Union until 1944, while the rest of Ukraine has deeper roots in the Russian Empire and the Soviet Union (Subtelny Reference Subtelny1994, 487–95). Eastern and southern Ukraine were also more affected by Russification policies. In the industrial cities of the east and south, immigrants from Russia and Ukrainians from the countryside worked together in factories and sent their children to Russian-language schools, fulfilling in some sense the Communist Party’s goals—introduced in the 1970s—of the merging of nationalities and the creation of “Soviet man” (Lieven Reference Lieven1999, 50–52). Russification and Sovietization were less pronounced in central Ukraine and absent in western Ukraine. As a result, views of the Soviet past vary significantly across Ukraine’s regions (Wanner Reference Wanner1998, 171–99).

Inglehart and Norris (Reference Inglehart and Norris2003, 135–46) suggest that the relative stability of support across time for gender quotas in Eastern European countries can be explained by their prior experience of gender quotas in the communist era. We are intrigued by the notion that the legacy of gender quotas in the Soviet era could explain quota compliance in the 2015 election. We do not, however, believe that the effect of historical memory will be uniform across Ukraine’s cities. Given the stark differences in attitudes about the Soviet period across Ukraine’s regions, we expect more support for the gender quotas in localities with more Russian-speaking voters—who have more sympathetic views of the Soviet Union, and less support in localities with more Ukrainian-speaking voters—who hold more negative views of the Soviet past.

Some might object to using past historical experiences to predict current political behavior. Historical arguments, however, are experiencing a renaissance of sorts in comparative politics research (Mares and Mohammed Reference Mares and Mohammed2019; Pop-Elecher and Tucker Reference Pop-Elcher and Tucker2017). Two articles by Arturas Rozenas and his colleagues use events in Soviet Ukraine—including the 1932–34 Ukrainian famine or Holodomor (Rozenas and Zhukov Reference Rozenas and Zhukov2019) and repression in localities in western Ukraine in the 1940s and 1950s (Rozenas, Schutte, and Zhukov Reference Rozenas, Schutte and Zhukov2017)—to predict political mobilization and electoral behavior during the late Soviet and postindependence periods. They find that localities that experienced more deaths during the Holodomor were less likely to vote for pro-Russian parties in elections from 2002 to 2014 (Rozenas and Zhukov Reference Rozenas and Zhukov2019, 576) and that the electoral margin for pro-Russian parties was lower in districts that experienced more Soviet-era deportations (Rozenas, Schutte, and Zhukov Reference Rozenas and Zhukov2019, 1153–54).

For any politics of memory argument, it is important to explain how historical legacies are transmitted across generations. Rozenas and Zhuvkov (Reference Rozenas and Zhukov2019, 570–71) discuss three possible modes of transmission. First, parents share their views of events and ideology with their children. Second, children learn about events in schools and churches. Third, individuals construct shared norms though their interactions with neighbors and peers. Many Ukrainians know about relatives that died during the Holodomor or were deported to Siberia. While this topic was taboo during the Soviet period, it is now openly discussed in families. The crimes of the Soviet Union are also part of the school curriculum in Ukrainian schools (Kosianov Reference Kosianov, Noack, Janssen and Comerford2014), although teachers in Russian-language schools in eastern Ukraine have been found to deflect criticism of Russia (Rodgers Reference Rodgers2007). Finally, Ukrainians undoubtedly learn from their daily interactions with peers. A key source of information, beyond social interactions, is the media. Ukrainian-language media is more likely to provide a negative view of today’s Russia and the Soviet past than Russian-language media.Footnote 17

Table 1 shows characteristics of Ukraine’s regions that might influence parties’ decisions about whether to fulfill the gender quota in specific localities, including several that have been flagged by the broader gender literature as factors affecting female representation. Western and central Ukraine are more ethnically and linguistically homogenous than southern and eastern Ukraine. The differences between the percentages of ethnic Ukrainian and Ukrainian speakers capture the effects of Russification in the east and south. Inhabitants of western Ukraine are the most religious, followed by those in the center. Measures of religiosity are lower in the south and east. Those living in the west and center are also more likely to support Christian democratic, national democratic, and nationalist parties. Support for these parties is lower in the south and totally absent in the east.

Table 1. Ukrainian regional differences (percentages)

Sources: Osoblyvosti relihiinoho (2018, 12, 19); Zlobina et al. (Reference Zlobina2017, 92); Ukrainian State Statistical Committee; Ukrainian Central Electoral Commission.

As previously noted, there is significant prior research that leads us to expect that support for female candidates will be lower in those cities with greater support for traditional political cultures. Unfortunately, we lack disaggregated survey data for cities to create a measure that directly captures differences in attitudes. Since polling data are not available at the level of cities, we rely on the percentage of the population that speaks Ukrainian across cities to measure traditional popular culture.Footnote 18 The Ukrainian-speaking population tracks fairly closely with levels of religiosity and support for Christian democratic, national democratic, and nationalist parties across cities, as well as attitudes toward the Soviet past. Residents of the south, and especially the east, are more likely to support communist parties. Consequently, we hypothesize that as the percentage of the Ukrainian-speaking population increases in a city, the percentage of women nominated on party lists and quota compliance will decrease.

Given the strong east-west/left-right cleavage in Ukraine, it is not surprising that we see variation in quota compliance regionally. Figure 2 plots a heat map of the average percentage of party lists in cities that met the 30% gender quota by state (oblast’). The data show a clear trend in quota compliance among oblasts in eastern and southern Ukraine, in comparison with those in central and especially western Ukraine.Footnote 19

Finally, for parties seeking to maximize votes through the nomination of female candidates, the best indicator of future support might be past success. Consequently, we expect parties to consider the results of the previous election, paying particular attention to the success of female candidates. In this case, parties may find that nominating women in cities that saw past success for female candidates will allow them to meet the quota and not lose vote share. Thus, we expect that the percentage of female candidates on city lists and quota compliance will increase as the percentage of elected female deputies in the 2010 election increases.

The remainder of this article will test our hypotheses.

Data and Methods

To test our hypotheses, we created a data set of all 106 parties that competed in the 121 cities of oblast significance in the 2015 Ukrainian elections.Footnote 20 Our data set totals 1,641 observations, and the unit of analysis is the party list/city.Footnote 21

We test our hypotheses with two dependent variables calculated using our sample of the 2015 electoral data. First, we calculate for each party list in each city the percentage of women on the list. Second, we create a dummy variable, met quota, that is coded 1 for all parties that complied with the 30% quota on the party list in the city and 0 for all those parties that did not meet the 30% quota. We employ two dependent variables to more fully understand party nomination strategies. Given that the percentage of women on the list variable is continuous, it contains more information than the simple met quota dummy variable does. Moreover, if our intuition is correct, then we should see the expected relationships between both the percentage of women on the list variable as well as the met quota variable.

We employ four independent variables to test our hypotheses. First, we include two dummy variables to test the impact of party ideology, based on the Ukrainian context—left party and ethnonationalist party. Parties are coded as left if their platforms or public statements focused on policies that would increase the role of the state in the economy and maintain social guarantees from the Soviet period. Parties are coded as ethnonationalist if their platforms or public statements were aimed primarily at co-ethnics and supported the culture and traditions of their group. The overwhelming majority of these parties targeted Ukrainian speakers, although some parties representing the interests of Russian and Hungarian speakers were also coded as ethnonationalist based on their platforms and public statements. A list of the 106 parties and their coding can be found in the supplementary materials online.Footnote 22 Second, we include a variable that codes each city by its percentage of Ukrainian-speaking population. Footnote 23 Finally, we calculate the percentage of female deputies in 2010 for each city and code all observations with its value.Footnote 24

All our models include several control variables. We control for differing economic conditions by including the percentage unemployment for all cities in our data set. As indicated in Table 1, unemployment was higher in eastern than western Ukraine.Footnote 25 We include the percentage of party deputies in 2010 for each party. This number is simply the percentage of each city legislature elected by party in the 2010 elections. We include this measure to control for the possibility that differences in overall party support will explain variation in the number of female candidates nominated by parties. We want to control for potential differences in the behavior of larger parties versus smaller parties. To do this, we include a variable measuring the percentage of cities in which parties ran lists. We also include the percentage of the vote that each party received in the 2014 PR election for the Ukrainian parliament, the Rada (percentage Rada vote 2014). It is possible that parties with strong national support may behave differently than those with only limited national support. Parties that did not compete in the 2014 Rada elections were coded as 0% of the vote. We include the log of party age to control for differences in party institutionalization. Women’s representation is often greater in urban areas; thus, we include the urbanization percentage, which is the percentage of the urban population for each city as measured in the 2001 Ukrainian census.Footnote 26 Some research finds a positive correlation between women’s representation and the number of legislative seats (e.g., Eder, Fortin-Rittberger, and Kroeber Reference Eder, Fortin-Rittberger and Kroeber2016; Kjaer and Elklit Reference Kjaer and Elklit2014). Other scholars, however, find mixed results (Salmond Reference Salmond2006). We code each city with its legislature’s number of seats to control for the potential effect of legislative size.

We use non-nested Bayesian hierarchical models estimated with PyStan (Stan Development Team 2018). We include random intercepts for both individual political parties and individual cities in all equations. The random intercepts allow us to control for potential error variances based on different cities and parties. Thus, we can control for heterogeneity based on different cities and parties. In addition, several of our independent variables are city or party level indicators, consequently it is appropriate to include random intercepts at the group level. For our models using the percentage of women on the list dependent variable, we use a linear regression model. We use a logit specification for our models using the met quota variable.Footnote 27

Results

Figure 3 plots the posterior medians and 90% credibility intervals of the independent variable first differences of Model 1 using the percentage women on the list dependent variable.Footnote 28 For dummy variables, the first difference represents the difference in the expected percentage of women on the list of changing the value of the variable from 0 to 1 while holding all other variables at their means and modes. For continuous variables, the first differences represent an increase in the value of the variable from one standard deviation below the mean to one standard deviation above it while holding the value of all other variables at their means and modes. The results presented in Figure 3 provide mixed support for our arguments. In our first two hypotheses, we predicted that the party ideology dummy variables, ethnonationalist party and left party, would impact the percentage of women on party lists. The results, however, show no statistically significant impact of party ideology on the number of women on party lists in the 2015 elections. Party ideology, therefore, is not a good predictor of the percentage of women on party lists.

Figure 3. First differences, Model 1 (DV = percentage women on the list).

We do, however, find support for our other two hypotheses. Increasing the percentage Ukrainian-speaking population variable from one standard deviation below to one standard deviation of the mean reduces the percentage of women on the list by 1.2%. Thus, our expectations concerning the effect Ukraine’s historical memory are supported. In addition, we find evidence that a city’s previous level of support for female legislators matters. Increasing the percentage of female deputies elected in 2010 from one standard deviation below to one standard deviation above its mean increases women’s representation on lists by 2.5%. This result also supports our hypothesis.

Our control variables provided a few interesting results. Increasing the percentage urban population from one standard deviation below to one standard deviation above their means increased the percentage of female candidate on party lists in cities by a modest 1%. Increasing the percentage unemployment from one standard deviation below its mean to one above increased the percentage of women on the list on average by 1.2%. Given that unemployment was higher in eastern and southern Ukraine compared to western Ukraine, this is, perhaps, not surprising. Changes in the log of party age, percentage of cities, percentage of party deputies elected in 2010 do not have an independent effect on the percentage of women nominated on party lists. A similar increase in number of seats variables decreased the percentage of women on party lists in cities by 1.7%. Thus, cities with a greater number of seats had fewer women on party lists, on average.

What about quota compliance? Figure 4 presents the posterior median average marginal effects and 90% credibility intervals for each of independent variables in Model 2 using the met quota dependent variable. We calculate the effects using changes in the values of the variables as we did for the results in Figure 3. Once again, we find no evidence that party ideology alone explains the likelihood of a party meeting the quota. Both the ethnonationalist party and left party variables are not statistically significant in Model 2. Thus, we find more evidence that party ideology does not have an independent effect on meeting the 2015 quota.

Figure 4. First differences, Model 2 (DV = met quota).

Yet, we find strong support for our two contextual variables—the percentage of Ukrainian-speaking population and the percentage of female deputies in 2010. We find a robust effect of increasing the percentage Ukrainian-speaking population variable, which results in a 5.1% decrease in the probability of meeting the quota. This is an important finding because it demonstrates parties responding to differences in context, regardless of party ideology. In addition, increasing the percentage of female deputies in 2010 variable improved the probability of complying with the gender quota by 5.4%. As we found in Model 1, Model 2 provides strong support for our final two hypotheses.

The impacts of the control variables are less consistent in Model 2. None of the control variables are statistically significant; therefore, they have little independent effect on whether parties met the 2015 quota law or not.

Discussion of Results

Taken together, the results of models using our two dependent variables, the percentage of women on the list and the met quota, provide support for our contention that Ukrainian political parties behaved strategically in terms of women’s overall nominations and quota compliance. On the one hand, we found little evidence that party ideology alone explains whether parties met the weakly enforced party quota. Model 1 found some evidence that parties that ran lists in a greater percentage of cities nominate fewer women; however, we did not find similar results in Model 2 using the met quota variable. The fact that we included measures of various party characteristics and included random intercepts for individual political parties strongly suggests that we controlled for party effects; however, the results imply that these characteristics did not independently explain variation in quota compliance. Thus, we found no support for our first two hypotheses regarding ideology.

On the other hand, we have strong evidence that variation in local context impacted party decisions. Our argument assumes that parties want to win votes and will behave strategically to get votes to maximize their seat share. Thus, when faced with a weakly enforced quota, parties will vary their compliance, placing a greater number of female candidates in those cities where support for female candidates is greater. Based on the politics of memory in Ukraine, we expected that parties would be less likely to meet the quota in those cities with greater proportions of Ukrainian speakers. The results of both our models support this contention. Parties clearly placed more female candidates and were more likely to reach the 30% quota in cities with fewer Ukrainian speakers. In addition, we found evidence that parties were more likely to nominate women and meet the quota in cities that elected more women in the 2010 election. This supports our contention that women’s nominations and quota compliance were greater in those cities where parties had evidence that voters rewarded female candidates. In those cities where fewer women won seats in 2010, parties were less likely to meet the quota, nominating fewer women.

Conclusion

In 2015, Ukraine enacted a 30% gender quota for local elections. The quota, however, was effectively costless since the legislation contained no enforcement mechanism or penalties for failing to meet the quota. Even with a weak quota, Ukraine not only increased the average percentage of women elected to city legislatures since the last election, to 26.8% from 21%, but 79.8% of the time, parties met the quota. Perhaps this finding is not unexpected, given that the literature finds that even weak quotas increase women’s representation (Schwindt-Bayer Reference Schwindt-Bayer2009); however, it does raise the question, why do parties comply with weakly enforced quotas?

Our review of the broader literature on quota compliance formed the basis for our expectations that parties would behave strategically, and that quota compliance would be affected by contextual factors as well as party ideology. Our statistical analysis provided mixed support for our expectations. We found little evidence that party ideology independently impacted the number of women parties nominated and quota compliance. Yet, we found strong evidence that contextual factors mattered. Quota compliance varied not only with the percentage of Ukrainian speakers in a city, but also with the percentage of women elected in the 2010 local elections.

For scholars of Ukraine and post-Soviet states more broadly, these results provide evidence that historical memory of the Soviet Union can influence more recent political outcomes. The Soviet Union created fundamentally different legacies across Ukraine. Soviet rule left inhabitants of eastern and southern Ukraine more Sovietized than Ukrainians living in central and western Ukraine, where more aspects of traditional culture—including religion and patriarchy—survived the Soviet experiment. As other studies have found, views of the Soviet past are passed down through generations. Political parties, we suggest, anticipated that voters in the east and south would be more open to the gender quota, and female candidates more generally, than voters in the center and west. This finding is line with recent research (Rozenas, Schutte, and Zhukov Reference Rozenas, Schutte and Zhukov2017; Rozenas and Zhukov Reference Rozenas and Zhukov2019) that also demonstrates how the Soviet experience continues to affect contemporary Ukraine.

With respect to future research, Ukraine’s adoption of a new, national-level electoral law in 2019 with a 40% gender quota raises the question, will we find similar patterns of quota compliance at the national level that we have seen at the city level? Davidson-Schmich (Reference Davidson-Schmich2016) correctly points out that much of the quota research focuses only on the national level. This article has sought to help rectify this issue. Nonetheless, the adoption of a national level quota in Ukraine provides research opportunities to determine whether national and regional patterns of compliance are similar or different.

The findings also add to our understanding of the effects of gender quotas more broadly. Research on gender quotas has found that enforcement provisions explain, in part, the effectiveness of quotas (e.g., Baldez Reference Baldez2002; Davidson-Schmich Reference Davidson-Schmich2016; Htun and Jones Reference Htun, Jones, Craske and Molyneux2002; Murray Reference Murray2007; Schwindt-Bayer Reference Schwindt-Bayer2009). The research presented here expands our understanding of quotas with weak enforcement mechanisms. The evidence from the 2015 Ukrainian local elections is clear—parties did not simply ignore the quota. Instead, parties varied their quota compliance based on the characteristics of electoral districts. Parties were willing to nominate more women and to meet the weakly enforced quota rules in those cities that were more likely to support female candidates. This is clear evidence that parties behave strategically when faced with weakly enforced gender quotas. More importantly, the findings explain conditions under which parties will abide by quota regulations even when they face little to no punishment for ignoring them. For scholars of gender quotas, this is important because it suggests that even weakly enforced quotas matter.

Our results pose one important question for future research—are our findings generalizable beyond the Ukrainian case? Ukraine is a good case to test our argument given its low level of gender equality, weakly enforced quota, clear evidence of compliance variation, and strong regional divisions. Yet, not all countries have similar regional cleavages or low levels of gender equality. In addition, the sources of strategic variation may differ in other contexts. Thus, more research on quota compliance in different contests must be done to further test our expectations.

The results also raise the possibility that the politics of memory may be an important determinant of gendered outcomes in other contexts. While the specifics of the Soviet experience may be unique to post-Soviet countries, there is little reason to expect that the effect of historical memory is limited to them. Further research on historical memory and gendered outcomes in other contexts will help us better understand the extent to which the past continues to influence the future.

Supplementary Materials

To view supplementary material for this article, please visit http://doi.org/10.1017/S1743923X22000125.

Footnotes

The authors thank Sergei Shevliuga for his research assistance.

1. These elections take place in a subset of cities that are designated as cities of regional significance (mista oblasnoho znachennia).

2. We are interested in what we define as the “formal” costs of quota noncompliance that are enshrined in the electoral code or electoral laws. There might be other costs to noncompliance from voters or party activists; however, in this article, we focus on the costs levied by the state.

3. Weeks (Reference Weeks2018) argues that party quotas are often supported by party leaders to better control nominations.

4. The research on this question finds little support that voters discriminate against female candidates in multiple settings including Ukraine (Black and Erickson Reference Black and Erickson2003; Brians Reference Brians2005; Murray Reference Murray2008; Norris, Vallance, and Lovenduski Reference Norris, Vallance and Lovenduski1992; Thames Reference Thames2018).

5. There is evidence that women prefer to vote for female candidates (Brians Reference Brians2005; Dolan Reference Dolan1998, Reference Dolan2008; Golder et al. Reference Golder, Stephenson, Van der Straeten, Blais, Bol, Harfst and Laslier2017; Marien, Schouteden, and Wauters Reference Marien, Schouteden and Wauters2017). Yet, other research finds that men are more likely than women to engage in same-sex voting (Giger et al. Reference Giger, Holli, Lefkofridi and Wass2014; Holli and Wass Reference Holli and Wass2010; Marien, Schouteden, and Wauters Reference Marien, Schouteden and Wauters2017) or shows little evidence of gender affinity voting at all (Goodyear-Grant and Croskil Reference Goodyear-Grant and Croskil2011; McDermott Reference McDermott2009; McElroy and Marsh Reference McElroy and Marsh2011). Increasingly, research on gender affinity voting recognizes that the process by which gender stereotypes translate into actual votes is complicated by other factors (Campbell and Heath Reference Campbell and Heath2017; Dolan Reference Dolan2008; Erzeel and Caluwaerts Reference Erzeel and Caluwaerts2015).

6. Other studies, however, have shown nationalist parties capable of increasing female representation (see, e.g., Russell, Mackay, and McAllister Reference Russell, McKay and McAllister2002).

7. Ukrainian State Electoral Commission: cvk.gov.ua (accessed January 2, 2020).

8. “Sud vse zhe razreshil TsVK ihnoryrovat’ hendernye kvoty na vyborakh,” Ukrains’ka Pravda, October 5, 2015.

9. For a thorough analysis of the twists and turns in the implementation of the 2015 gender quota, see an undated analysis by Maryna Stavniichuk at http://prportal.com.ua/Peredovitsa/shahraystvo-na-rivnosti-prav (accessed January 2, 2020).

10. “Zakon iakii ne vykonuet’sia- radshe nasmishka, vidomi volyniaky pro hendernu kvotu na vyborakh,” Volyn’ Post, October 13, 2015.

11. The reason there is no intraparty competition is that each council—regardless of level—is divided into subdistricts equal to the number of seats in the legislature. Any registered party submits a list of candidates for election in the multi-member district. The first candidate on the list receives the first seat won, if any, and is not assigned to a subdistrict. The remaining candidates are assigned to subdistricts; however, a party can only assign one candidate per subdistrict. In each subdistrict, voters receive ballots containing the names of each party in the multi-member district, the name of the top ranked candidate, and the name of the party’s candidate in the subdistrict, assuming a party nominated one. Voters cast a ballot for a party, indicating their support for the party and the individual district candidate. Party vote totals are aggregated across the vote results in each subdistrict. To receive a seat, a party must obtain at least 5% of the vote. Seats are awarded proportionally to all parties that pass the threshold. Once a party’s seat total has been established, individual list candidates are assigned seats. In all cases, the first candidate that receives a seat is the individual designated by the party as “first candidate.” If a party receives more than one seat, the remaining list candidates are rank ordered, with the next seat going to the candidate with the highest subdistrict total, and so on down the list.

12. Interview with the second author in Kyiv on June 26, 2013.

14. In all, 106 parties competed in the 2015 general elections. Major parties are those that received over 1% of the national vote. Only 16 parties met this threshold. The large number of parties is partly the result of the ease of registering parties in Ukraine.

15. The relationship between ideology and female candidacies has been studied in several different contexts. Kantola and Lombardo (Reference Kantola and Lombardo2019) argue that left parties are more favorable to feminists than populist parties, though both suffer from patriarchal party cultures, in Spain and Finland. Funk, Hinojosa, and Piscopo (Reference Funk, Hinojosa and Piscopo2017) argue that left parties are not more likely than right parties to nominate female candidates. In this article, we focus on a left-right ideological space specific to the post-Soviet Ukrainian context, which may differ from other contexts.

16. See Antoniuk (Reference Antoniuk2015, 148).

17. Nils Muižnieks and his colleagues (Muižnieks Reference Muižnieks2008) have analyzed how Russian media frame historical and current events in Latvia in a negative light for the Russian public, and for the broader Russian-speaking audience living in former Soviet republics. A similar playbook is employed for Ukraine.

18. These data come from the 2001 Ukrainian census. Individuals were asked to state their ethnicity (natsional’nist) and their native language (ridna mova).

19. We would like to compare the 2015 candidate data with the previous election in 2010; however, the CEC did not make public data on the candidates who ran in the 2010 elections.

20. This does not include elections in the capital city Kyiv, which did not compete in the 2010 elections. The electoral data were downloaded from the CEC website at https://www.cvk.gov.ua/pls/vm2015/wm001.html.

21. Unfortunately, we are not able to use survey data to test our argument. There are no surveys of voter attitudes concerning gender and local elections in Ukraine during this period.

22. See the supplementary materials for our party coding rules and a list of parties and their coding.

23. All these data were provided to us by the Ukrainian State Statistical Committee.

24. The percentage of female deputies elected was calculated using the results of the 2010 local elections. The CEC did not make public any data on the candidates in these elections. Our data come from a CEC document from 2011 posted on the CEC website at cvk.gov.ua: “Cherhovi Vybory Deputativ Verkhovnoi Rady Avtonomnoi Respubliky Krym, Mistsevykh Rad ta cil’s’kykh, selushchnykh, mis’kykh holiv 31 zhobvtnia 2010 roku. Informatsiine vydannia.”

25. The unemployment rate was calculated by dividing the number of people registered as unemployed in 2014 by the overall number of people in the labor force in a given locality. These data were again made available to us by the Ukrainian State Statistical Committee.

26. Urbanization for cities is measured by the percentage of inhabitants that live in the territory of a given city that is considered urban (mis’ke) and not rural (sil’ske) according to the 2001 Ukrainian census—the most recent census at the time of the 2015 elections. As the term “rural” denotes, the rural parts of cities generally have less infrastructure and look a lot like the surrounding countryside, but are technically within the boundaries of a city. The extent to which cities contain nonurban areas varies greatly across cities and arguably affects electoral behavior. Cities with larger rural populations might be expected to hold more traditional views of gender roles and less likely to support female candidates.

27. For all models, we estimate four chains with 10,000 iterations and a “burn-in” of 5,000 iterations, retaining 500 iterations per chain to form the posterior. Diagnostics for all models indicates that they converged.

28. The supplementary materials contain more detailed information about the individual parameter estimates for all models.

References

Antoniuk, Liliia. 2015. “A New Version of Ukrainian Politics or Another Political Trick: Reflections on the Role of the Electoral Quota for Women in Ukraine and Its Results.” Eastern Journal of European Studies 6 (2): 131–57.Google Scholar
Badas, Alex, and Stauffer, Katelyn. 2019. “Voting for Women in Nonpartisan and Partisan Elections.” Electoral Studies 57 (1): 245–55.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Baldez, Lisa. 2002. “Elected Bodies: The Gender Quota Law for Legislative Candidates in Mexico.” Legislative Studies Quarterly 29 (2): 231–58.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Banerjee, Sikata. 2007. “Gender and Nationalism: The Masculinization of Hinduism and Female Participation.” In Urban Women in Contemporary India: A Reader , edited by Ghadially, Rehana. New Delhi: Sage, 311–26.Google Scholar
Bjarnegård, Elin, and Zetterberg, Pär. 2016. “Political Parties and Gender Quota Implementation: The Role of Bureaucratized Candidate Selection Procedures.” Comparative Politics 48 (3): 393411.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Black, Jerome, and Erickson, Lynda. 2003. “Women Candidates and Voter Bias: Do Women Politicians Need to Be Better?Electoral Studies 22 (1): 81100.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bloom, Stephen, and Shulman, Stephen. 2011. “Interest versus Identity: Economic Voting in Ukrainian Presidential Elections.” Post-Soviet Affairs 27 (7): 410–28.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bolzendahl, Catherine, and Gracheva, Ksenia. 2018. “Rejecting the West? Homonegative Attitudes and Political Orientations in Contemporary Eastern Europe.” European Journal of Gender and Politics 1 (3): 345–66.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Brians, Craig. 2005. “Women for Women? Gender and Party Bias in Voting for Female Candidates.” American Politics Research 33 (3): 357–75.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Campbell, Rosie, and Heath, Oliver. 2017. “Do Women Vote for Women Candidates? Attitudes toward Descriptive Representation and Voting Behavior in the 2010 British Election.” Politics & Gender 13 (2): 209–31.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Caul, Miki. 1999. “Women’s Representation in Parliament.” Party Politics 5 (1): 7998.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dahlerup, Drude, and Gaber, Milicia Antic. 2017. “The Legitimacy and Effectiveness of Gender Quotas in Politics in CE Europe.” Teorija in Praksa 54 (2): 307–16.Google Scholar
Davidson-Schmich, Louise. 2006. “Implementation of Political Party Gender Quotas: Evidence from the German Lánder 1990–2000.” Party Politics 12 (2): 211–32.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Davidson-Schmich, Louise. 2016. Gender Quotas and Democratic Participation: Recruiting Candidates for Elective Offices in Germany. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Diamond, Irene. 1977. Sex Roles in the State House. New Haven, CT: Yale University Press Google Scholar
Dolan, Kathleen. 1998. “Voting for Women in the ‘Year of the Woman.’American Journal of Political Science 42 (1): 272–93.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dolan, Kathleen. 2008. “Is There a ‘Gender Affinity Effect’ in American Politics? Information, Affect, and Candidate Sex in U.S. House Elections.” Political Research Quarterly 61 (1): 7989.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dolan, Kathleen. 2014. “Gender Stereotypes, Candidate Evaluations, and Voting for Women Candidates: What Really Matters?Political Research Quarterly 67 (1): 96107.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Eder, Christina, Fortin-Rittberger, Jessica, and Kroeber, Corinna. 2016. “The Higher and Fewer? Patterns of Female Representation Across Levels of Government.” Parliamentary Affairs 69 (2): 366–86.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Erzeel, Silvia, and Caluwaerts, Didier. 2015. “Is It Gender, Ideology or Resources? Individual-Level Determinants of Preferential Voting for Male or Female Candidates.” Journal of Elections, Public Opinion and Parties 25 (3): 265–83.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fox, Richard. 2000. Gender and American Politics: Women, Men, and the Political Process. Armonk, NY: M.E. Sharpe.Google Scholar
Fox, Richard, and Smith, Eric. 1998. “The Role of Candidate Sex in Voter Decision-Making.” Political Psychology 19 (2): 405–19.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Frechette, Guillaume, Maniquet, Francois, and Morelli, Massimo. 2008. “Incumbents’ Interests and Gender Quotas.” American Journal of Political Science 52 (4): 891909.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Funk, Kendall, Hinojosa, Magda, and Piscopo, Jennifer. 2017. “Still Left Behind: Gender, Political Parties, and Latin America’s Pink Tide.” Social Forces 24 (4): 399424.Google Scholar
Galligan, Yvonne, and Clavero, Sara. 2008. “Prospects for Women’s Legislative Representation in Postsocialist Europe: The Views of Female Politicians.” Gender & Society 22 (2): 149–71.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Giger, Nathalie, Holli, Anne Maria, Lefkofridi, Zoe, and Wass, Hanna. 2014. “The Gender Gap in Same-Gender Voting: The Role of Context.” Electoral Studies 35 (3): 303–14.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Golder, Sona, Stephenson, Laura, Van der Straeten, Karine, Blais, Andre, Bol, Damien, Harfst, Philipp, and Laslier, Jean Francois. 2017. “Votes for Women: Electoral Systems and Support for Female Candidates.” Politics & Gender 13 (1): 107–31.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Goodyear-Grant, Elizabeth, and Croskil, Julie. 2011. “Gender Affinity Effects in Vote Choice in Westminster Systems: Assessing ‘Flexible’ Voters in Canada.” Politics & Gender 7 (2): 222–50.Google Scholar
Hankivsky, Olena, and Salnykova, Anastasiya. 2010. “Gender Mainstreaming in Post-Soviet Ukraine: Application and Applicability.” Journal of Communist Studies and Transition Politics 26 (3): 315–40.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hill, David. 1981. “Political Culture and Female Political Representation.” Journal of Politics 43 (1): 159–68.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hinojosa, Magda. 2012. Selecting Women, Electing Women: Political Representation and Candidate Selection in Latin America. Philadelphia: Temple University Press.Google Scholar
Holli, Anne Maria, and Wass, Hanna. 2010. “Gender-Based Voting in the Parliamentary Elections of 2007 in Finland. European Journal of Political Research 49 (5): 598630.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Holovakha, Evhen, and Panina, N.. 1998. Tendentsii rozvytku ukrains’koho suspil’stva (1994–1997r.r.) Sotsiolohichni pokaznyky [Tendencies in the development of Ukrainian society (1994–1997) sociological indicators]. Kyiv: Instytut sotsiolohii.Google Scholar
Horn, Denise. 2008. “US and Nordic Gender Policies in the Estonian Transition to Democracy.” International Feminist Journal of Politics 10 (1): 5977.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hrybanov, Anatolii, and Kravchuk, Andrii. 2018. Raiduzhna Knyga [Rainbow book]. Kyiv: Tsentr Nash Svit.Google Scholar
Hrycak, Alexandra. 2005. “Coping with Chaos: Gender and Politics in a Fragmented State.” Problems of Post-Communism 52 (5): 6981.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hrycak, Alexandra. 2006. “Foundation Feminism and the Articulation of Hybrid Feminisms in Post-Socialist Ukraine.” East European Politics and Societies 20 (1): 69100.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hrycak, Alexandra. 2010. “Orange Harvest? Women’s Activism and Civil Society in Ukraine, Belarus and Russia since 2004.” Canadian-American Slavic Studies 44 (1–2): 151–77.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hrycak, Alexandra. 2011. “The ‘Orange Princess’ Runs for President: Gender and the Outcomes of the 2010 Presidential Election.” East European Politics & Societies 25 (1): 6887.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Htun, Mala, and Jones, Mark. 2002. “Engendering the Right to Participate in Decision-Making: Electoral Quotas and Women’s Leadership in Latin America.” In Gender and the Politics of Rights and Democracy in Latin America, eds. Craske, Nikki and Molyneux, Maxine. Basingstoke: Palgrave Macmillan, 3256.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Huddy, Leonie, and Terkildsen, Nayda. 1993. “Gender Stereotypes and the Perception of Male and Female Candidates.” American Journal of Political Science 37 (1): 119–47.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Inglehart, Ronald, and Norris, Pippa. 2003. Rising Tide: Gender Equality and Cultural Change around the World. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kantola, Johanna and Lombardo, Emanuela. 2019. “Populism and Feminist Politics: the Cases of Finland and Spain.” European Journal of Political Research 58 (4): 1108–28.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Kapoor, Nevedita. 2016. “Women in the Duma: Why Post-Soviet Russia Has Low Female Representation.” Spravnitelnii Analiz Lokaln’ogo Opyta 2 (23): 114.Google Scholar
Katchanovski, Ivan. 2006. “Regional Political Divisions in Ukraine in 1991–2006.” Nationalities Papers 34 (5): 507–32.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Khmelko, Valeri, and Wilson, Andrew. 1998. “Regionalism and Ethic and Linguistic Cleavages in Ukraine.” In Contemporary Ukraine: Dynamics of Post-Soviet Transformation, ed. Kuzio, Taras. London: M.E. Sharpe, 6080.Google Scholar
Kittilson, Miki Caul. 2006. Challenging Parties, Changing Parliaments. Columbus: Ohio State University Press.Google Scholar
Kjaer, Ulrik, and Elklit, Jørgen. 2014. “The Impact of Assembly Size on Representativeness.” Journal of Legislative Studies 20 (2): 156–73.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kosianov, Heorhiy. 2014. “Holodomor and the Politics of Memory in Ukraine After Independence.” In Holodomor and Gorta Mor—Histories, Memories and Representations of Famine in Ukraine and Ireland, eds. Noack, Christian, Janssen, Lindsay, and Comerford, Vincent. London: Anthem, 167–88.Google Scholar
Krook, Mona Lena. 2007. “Candidate Gender Quotas: A Framework for Analysis.” European Journal of Political Research 46 (3): 367–94.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Krook, Mona Lena. 2009. Quotas for Women in Politics: Gender and Candidate Selection Reform Worldwide. New York: Oxford University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
LaFont, Suzanne. 2001. “One Step Forward, Two Steps Back: Women in the Post-Communist States.” Communist and Post-Communist Studies 34 (2): 203–20.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Lake, Celinda, Gotoff, Daniel, and Pondel, Kristin. 2012. Public Perceptions of the 2012 Elections & Women’s Role Politics and Government: Findings from a Survey of 1,210 Adults over the Age of 18 Ukraine. Washington, DC: Lake Research Partners.Google Scholar
Lawless, Jennifer. 2004. “Politics of Presence? Congresswomen and Symbolic Representation.” Political Research Quarterly 57 (1): 8199.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lieven, Anatol. 1999. Ukraine and Russia: A Fraternal Rivalry. Washington, DC: United States Institute of Peace Press.Google Scholar
Mares, Isabela, and Mohammed, Ahmed. 2019. “From Violence to Political Compromise: The Historical Origins of Institutional Trust.” Presented at the Annual Meeting of the Midwest Political Science Association, Chicago, April 4–7.Google Scholar
Marien, Sofie, Schouteden, Anke, and Wauters, Bran. 2017. “Voting for Women in Belgium’s Flexible List System.” Politics & Gender 13 (2): 305–35.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Martseniuk, Tamara. 2016. “Zaluchenist’ zhinok u polityku: krainy ES i Ukraina” [Attracting women to politics: EU countries and Ukraine]. In Henderna rivnist’ i rozvytok: pohliad u konteksti evropeis’koi stratehii Ukraini [Gender equality and development: Examples and context of Ukraine’s European strategy], ed. Chernova, Alla. Kyiv: Tsentr Razumkova, 235–44.Google Scholar
Matland, Richard. 2006. “Electoral Quotas: Frequency and Effectiveness.” In Women, Quotas, and Politics, ed. Dahlerup, Drude. New York: Routledge, 275–92.Google Scholar
Matland, Richard, and Studlar, Donley. 1996. “The Contagion of Women Candidates in Single-Member Districts and Proportional Representation: Canada and Norway.” Journal of Politics 58 (3): 707–33.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
McDermott, Monika. 2009. “Religious Stereotyping and Voter Support for Evangelical Candidates.” Political Research Quarterly 62 (2): 340–54.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
McElroy, Gail, and Marsh, Michael. 2011. “Electing Women to the Dail: Gender Cues and the Irish Voter.” Irish Political Studies 26 (4): 521–34.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Meier, Petra. 2004. “The Mutual Contagion Effect of Legal and Party Quotas: A Belgian Perspective.” Party Politics 10 (5): 538600.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Muižnieks, Nils, ed. 2008. Manufacturing Enemy Images? Russian Media Portrayal of Latvia. Riga: Latvijas Universitāte.Google Scholar
Murray, Rainbow. 2007. “How Parties Evaluate Compulsory Quotas: A Study of the Implementation of the ‘Parity’ Law in France.” Parliamentary Affairs 60 (4): 568–84.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Murray, Rainbow. 2008. “The Power of Sex and Incumbency.” Party Politics 14 (5): 539–54.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Murray, Rainbow, Krook, Mona Lena, and Opello, Katherine. 2012. “Why Are Gender Quotas Adopted? Party Pragmatism and Parity in France.” Political Research Quarterly 65 (3): 529–43.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Nechemias, Carol. 1987. “Changes in the Election of Women to U. S. State Legislative Seats.” Legislative Studies Quarterly 12 (1): 125–42.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Norris, Pippa, Vallance, Elizabeth, and Lovenduski, Joni. 1992. “Do Candidates Make a Difference? Race, Gender, Ideology, and Incumbency.” Parliamentary Affairs 45 (4): 496547.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ondercin, Heather, and Welch, Susan. 2009. “Comparing Predictors of Women?s Congressional Election Success.” American Politics Research 37 (4): 593613.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Opello, Katherine. 2006. Gender Quotas, Parity Reform and Political Parties in France. New York: Lexington Books.Google Scholar
Osoblyvosti relihiinoho i tserkovno-relihiinoho samovyznachennia ukrains’kykh hromadian : tendentsii 2010–2018 rr [Particularities of religious and church self-identification of Ukrainian citizens: Tendencies 2010–2018]. 2018. Kyiv: Tsentr Razumkova.Google Scholar
Pop-Elcher, Grigore, and Tucker, Joshua. 2017. Communism’s Shadow: Historical Legacies and Contemporary Attitudes. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Popova, Maria. 2010. “Political Competition as an Obstacle to Judicial Independence: Evidence from Russia and Ukraine.” Comparative Political Studies 43 (10): 1202–29.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Popova, Maria, and Beers, Daniel. 2020. “No Revolution of Dignity for Ukraine’s Judges: Judicial Reform after the Euromaidan.” Demokratizatsiya: The Journal of Post-Soviet Democratization. 28 (1): 113–42.Google Scholar
Ol’ha, Pyshulina, ed. 2016. Henderna Rivnist’ i Rozvyto: Pohliad u Konteksti Evropeis’koi Stratehi Ukrainy [Gender equality and development: Examples in the context of Ukraine’s European strategy]. Kyiv: Tsentr Razumkova.Google Scholar
Rahat, Gideon, and Hazan, Reuven. 2001. “Candidate Selection Mechanisms: An Analytical Framework.” Party Politics 7 (3): 297322.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Riabchuk, Mykola. 2003. Dvi Ukrainy: real’ni mezhi, virtual’ni viiny [Two Ukraines: Real borders, virtual wars]. Kyiv: Krytyka Google Scholar
Rodgers, Peter. 2007. “Compliance or Contradiction? Teaching History in the New Ukraine: A View from Ukraine’s Eastern Borderland.” Europe-Asia Studies 59 (3): 503–19.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rozenas, Arturas, Schutte, Sebastian, and Zhukov, Yuri. 2017. “The Long-Term Impact of Stalin’s Repression in Ukraine.” Journal of Politics 79 (4): 1147–61.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rozenas, Arturas, and Zhukov, Yuri. 2019. “Mass Represion and Political Loyalty: Evidence from Stalin’s ‘Terror by Hunger.’American Political Science Review 113 (2): 569–83.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rubchak, Marian. 2012. “Seeing Pink: Searching for Gender Justice through Opposition in Ukraine.” European Journal of Women’s Studies 19 (1): 5572.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rule, Wilma. 1987. “Electoral Systems, Contextual Factors, and Women’s Opportunity for Election to Parliament in Twenty-Three Democracies.” Western Political Quarterly 40 (3): 477–98.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Russell, M., McKay, F., and McAllister, L.. 2002. “Women’s Representation in the Scottish Parliament and National Assembly for Wales: Party Dynamics for Achieving Critical Mass.” Journal of Legislative Studies 8 (2): 4976.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Salmond, Rob. 2006. “Proportional Representation and Female Parliamentarians.” Legislative Studies Quarterly 31 (2): 175204.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Schmidt, Gregory and Saunders, Kyle. 2004. “Effective Quotas, Relative Party Magnitude, and the Success of Female Candidates.” Comparative Political Studies 37 (6): 704–34.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Schwindt-Bayer, Leslie. 2009. “Making Quotas Work: The Effect of Gender Quota Laws on the Election of Women.” Legislative Studies Quarterly 34 (1): 528.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Setzler, Mark. 2015. “Does Religion Bias Individuals Against Female Leadership in Latin America?The Latin Americanist 59 (4): 4772.Google Scholar
Stan Development Team. 2018. PyStan: the Python interface to Stan, Version 2.17.1.0. http://mc-stan.org.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Subtelny, Orest. 1994. Ukraine: A History. 2nd ed. Toronto: University of Toronto Press.Google Scholar
Thames, Frank. 2018. “The Electoral System and Women’s Legislative Underrepresentation in Post-Communist Ukraine.” Comparative Politics 50 (2): 251–72.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Thames, Frank, and Williams, Margaret. 2010. “Incentives for Personal Votes and Women’s Representation in Legislatures.” Comparative Political Studies 43 (12): 15751600.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Tripp, Aili, and Kang, Alice. 2008. “The Global Impact of Quotas: On the Fast Track to Increased Female Legislative Representation.” Comparative Political Studies 41 (3): 338–61.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Valdini, Melody Ellis. 2012. “A Deterrent to Diversity: The Conditional Effect of Electoral Rules on the Nomination of Women Candidates.” Electoral Studies 31 (4): 740–49.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wängnerud, Lena. 2000. “Testing the Politics of Presence: Women’s Representation in the Swedish Riksdag.” Scandinavian Politics 23 (1): 6791.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wanner, Catherine. 1998. Burden of Dreams: History and Identity in Post-Soviet Ukraine . University Park: Penn State University Press.Google Scholar
Weeks, Ana Catalano. 2018. “Why Are Gender Quota Laws Adopted by Men? The Role of Inter- and Intraparty Competition.” Comparative Political Studies 51 (14): 1935–73.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wylie, Kristin. 2018. Party Institutionalization and Women’s Representation in Democratic Brazil. New York: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wilson, Andrew. 1997. Ukrainian Nationalism in the 1990s: A Minority Faith. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Wilson, Andrew. 2005. Ukraine’s Orange Revolution. New Haven, CT: Yale University Press.Google Scholar
Zlobina, O. H., et al. 2017. Stan Suchasnoho Ukrains’koho suspilstva: tsyvilizatsiinyi zymir [Status of current Ukrainian Society: Civilizational survey]. Kyiv: Institut Sotsiolohii.Google Scholar
Figure 0

Figure 1. Percentage of lists meeting quota by major party.

Figure 1

Figure 2. Average percentage of party lists in city elections meeting the quota by region.

Figure 2

Table 1. Ukrainian regional differences (percentages)

Figure 3

Figure 3. First differences, Model 1 (DV = percentage women on the list).

Figure 4

Figure 4. First differences, Model 2 (DV = met quota).

Supplementary material: File

Thames and Bloom supplementary material

Thames and Bloom supplementary material
Download Thames and Bloom supplementary material(File)
File 17.9 KB