Hostname: page-component-cd9895bd7-mkpzs Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-12-22T10:44:20.752Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Some Simple Tests of Rational Voting and Agenda Setting

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  21 October 2014

Abstract

This article analyzes election data that permit simple tests of rational voting and agenda setting. The voting test pertains to aggregate election results. The prediction is that when voters have single-peaked preferences, there will be more opposition to the second of two budget proposals that are voted on simultaneously. Unlike the standard binary choice setting, not all voters have weakly undominated voting strategies, but the game among the voters can be solved simply by iterative application of weak dominance. The agenda-setting prediction tested is that agenda setters should make one proposal rather than two when given the option. The data come from Oregon school district financial elections from 1980–83, years in which the rules for these elections were abruptly changed.

Type
Original Articles
Copyright
Copyright © The European Political Science Association 2014 

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

Footnotes

Sean Corcoran is Associate Professor of Education Economics, Steinhardt School of Culture, Education, and Human Development, New York University, New York, NY 10012, USA ([email protected]). Thomas Romer is Professor of Politics and Public Affairs in the Woodrow Wilson School and the Department of Politics, Princeton University, Princeton, NJ 08544, USA ([email protected]). Howard Rosenthal is Professor of Politics, Wilf Family Department of Politics, New York University, New York, NY 10012, USA ([email protected]). We thank Alexander Ruder for extensive and effective research assistance. We also thank seminar participants at Columbia University for comments on an earlier draft. Thanks are also in order to the referees and the editor. The data collection for this study was supported by the Russell Sage Foundation.

References

Berkman, Michael B., and Plutzer, Eric. 2005. Ten Thousand Democracies: Politics and Public Opinion in America’s School Districts. Washington, DC: Georgetown University Press.Google Scholar
Cox, Gary W. 1994. ‘Strategic Voting Equilibria Under the Single Nontransferable Vote’. American Political Science Review 88:608662.Google Scholar
Feddersen, Timothy, and Pesendorfer, Wolfgang. 1997. ‘Voting Behavior and Information Aggregation in Elections with Private Information’. Econometrica 65:10291058.Google Scholar
Feddersen, Timothy, and Pesendorfer, Wolfgang. 1999. ‘Abstention in Elections with Asymmetric Information and Diverse Preferences’. American Political Science Review 93:381398.Google Scholar
Filimon, Radu, Romer, Thomas, and Rosenthal, Howard. 1982. ‘Asymmetric Information and Agenda Control: The Bases of Monopoly Power in Public Spending’. Journal of Public Economics 17:5170.Google Scholar
Fudenberg, Drew, and Tirole, Jean. 1991. Game Theory. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.Google Scholar
Gramlich, Edward, and Rubinfeld, Daniel. 1982. ‘Micro Estimates of Public Spending: Demand Functions and Tests of the Tiebout and Median-voter Hypotheses’. Journal of Political Economy 90:536560.Google Scholar
Hartman, William T., and Hwang, C.S.. 1985. ‘Effectiveness of Property Tax Relief in Oregon’. Journal of Education Finance 10:339359.Google Scholar
Hinich, Melvin J., and Ordeshook, Peter C.. 1969. ‘Abstention and Equilibrium in the Electoral Process’. Public Choice 7:81106.Google Scholar
Ledyard, John O. 1984. ‘The Pure Theory of Large Two-candidate Elections’. Public Choice 44:743.Google Scholar
Mebane, Walter R Jr. 2000. ‘Coordination, Moderation, and Institutional Balancing in American Presidential and House Elections’. American Political Science Review 94:3757.Google Scholar
Niskanen, William. 1971. Bureaucracy and Representative Government. Chicago: Aldine-Atherton.Google Scholar
Palfrey, Thomas R., and Rosenthal, Howard. 1985. ‘Voter Participation and Strategic Uncertainty’. American Political Science Review 79:6278.Google Scholar
Palfrey, Thomas R. 1989. ‘A Mathematical Proof of Duverger's Law’. In Models of Strategic Choice in Politics, edited by Peter C. Ordeshook, 6991. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press.Google Scholar
Riker, William, and Ordeshook, Peter C.. 1968. ‘A Theory of the Calculus of Voting’. American Political Science Review 62:2542.Google Scholar
Romer, Thomas, and Rosenthal, Howard. 1978. ‘Political Resource Allocation, Controlled Agendas, and the Status Quo’. Public Choice 33:2743.Google Scholar
Romer, Thomas, and Rosenthal, Howard. 1979. ‘Bureaucrats vs. Voters’. Quarterly Journal of Economics 93:563587.Google Scholar
Romer, Thomas, and Rosenthal, Howard. 1982a. Median Voters or Budget Maximizers: Evidence from School Expenditure Referenda’. Economic Inquiry 20:556578.Google Scholar
Romer, Thomas, and Rosenthal, Howard. 1982b. An Exploration in the Politics and Economics of Local Public Services’. In Public Production, edited by Dieter Bös, Richard A. Musgrave and Jack Wiseman, 105126. New York: Springer.Google Scholar
Romer, Thomas, Rosenthal, Howard, and Munley, Vincent. 1992. ‘Economic Incentives and Political Institutions: Spending and Voting in School Budget Referenda’. Journal of Public Economics 49:133.Google Scholar
Rosenthal, Howard. 1990. ‘The Setter Model’. In Advances in the Spatial Theory of Voting, edited by James Enelow and Melvin Hinich, 199234. New York: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Stiglitz, Joseph E.. 1974. ‘The Demand for Education in Public and Private School Systems’. Journal of Public Economics 3:349385.Google Scholar
Supplementary material: Link

Corcoran et al Dataset

Link