Hostname: page-component-586b7cd67f-t7czq Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-11-22T02:19:16.378Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Party Competition and the Inter-Industry Structure of US Trade Protection*

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  24 November 2016

Abstract

Why do some declining industries receive more compensation through protectionist policies than others, even without actively engaging in lobbying? How does the political representation of industries affect their chances for protectionist relief? This paper argues that political parties seek to optimize electoral returns through the strategic allocation of distributive benefits generated by trade barriers. The inter-industry structure of protection is thus explained by the interaction between industries’ trade preferences and political characteristics. Using data on protection and subnational employment for US industries and district-level election outcomes in the 1990s, this paper finds that the concentration of industries in competitive constituencies not only increases their chances of receiving higher tariffs, but also magnifies the marginal effect of comparative disadvantage on tariff and nontariff protection.

Type
Original Articles
Copyright
© The European Political Science Association 2016 

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

Footnotes

*

Su-Hyun Lee is an Assistant Professor in the S. Rajaratnam School of International Studies, Nanyang Technological University, 639798, Singapore ([email protected]). The author thanks William Clark, Alan Deardorff, Robert Franzese, Allen Hicken, and George Tsebelis for their helpful comments; and Daniel Kono for kindly sharing his data on US NTBs. To view supplementary material for this article, please visit https://doi.org/10.1017/psrm.2016.47

References

Abramowitz, Alan I., Alexander, Brad, and Gunning, Matthew. 2006. ‘Incumbency, Redistricting, and the Decline of Competition in U.S. House Elections’. Journal of Politics 68(1):7588.Google Scholar
Alt, James E., and Gilligan, Michael J.. 1994. ‘The Political Economy of Trading States: Factor Specificity, Collective Action Problems and Domestic Political Institutions’. Journal of Political Philosophy 2(2):165192.Google Scholar
Anderson, Kym, and Baldwin, Robert. 1981. ‘The Political Market for Protection in Industrial Countries: Empirical Evidence’. Staff Working Paper No. 492, World Bank, Washington DC.Google Scholar
Ansolabehere, Stephen, and Snyder, James M.. 2006. ‘Party Control of State Government and the Distribution of Public Expenditures’. Scandinavian Journal of Economics 108(4):547569.Google Scholar
Ansolabehere, Stephen, Snyder, James M., and Stewart III, Charles. 2001. ‘The Effects of Party and Preferences on Congressional Roll-Call Voting’. Legislative Studies Quarterly 26(4):533572.Google Scholar
Ansolabehere, Stephen, de Figueiredo, John M., and Snyder, James M.. 2003. ‘Why is There so Little Money in U.S. Politics?Journal of Economic Perspectives 17(1):105130.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Beck, Nathaniel, and Katz, Jonathan N.. 1995. ‘What to Do (and Not to Do) with Time-Series Cross-Section Data’. American Political Science Review 89(3):634647.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Berry, William D., Golder, Matt, and Milton, Daniel. 2012. ‘Improving Tests of Theories Positing Interaction’. Journal of Politics 74(3):653671.Google Scholar
Block, Fred. 2008. ‘Swimming Against the Current: The Rise of a Hidden Developmental State in the United States’. Politics & Society 36(2):169206.Google Scholar
Busch, Marc L., and Reinhardt, Eric. 1999. ‘Industrial Location and Protection: The Political and Economic Geography of U.S. Nontariff Barriers’. American Journal of Political Science 43(4):10281050.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Busch, Marc L., and Reinhardt, Eric. 2000. ‘Geography, International Trade, and Political Mobilization in U.S. Industries’. American Journal of Political Science 44(4):703719.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Busch, Marc L., and Reinhardt, Eric. 2005. ‘Industrial Location and Voter Participation in Europe’. British Journal of Political Science 35(4):713730.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Canes-Wrone, Brandice, Brady, David W., and Cogan, John F.. 2002. ‘Out of Step, Out of Office: Electoral Accountability and House Members’ Voting’. American Political Science Review 96(1):127140.Google Scholar
Caves, Richard E. 1976. ‘Economic Models of Political Choice: Canada’s Tariff Structure’. Canadian Journal of Economics 9(2):278300.Google Scholar
Cox, Gary W., and McCubbins, Matthew D.. 1986. ‘Electoral Politics as a Redistributive Game’. Journal of Politics 48(2):370389.Google Scholar
Dixit, Avinash, and Londregan, John. 1995. ‘Redistributive Politics and Economic Efficiency’. American Political Science Review 89(4):856866.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ellison, Glenn, and Glaeser, Edward L.. 1997. ‘Geographic Concentration in U.S. Manufacturing Industries: A Dartboard Approach’. Journal of Political Economy 105(5):889927.Google Scholar
Finger, Joseph M., Hall, H. Keith, and Nelson, Douglas R.. 1982. ‘The Political Economy of Administered Protection’. American Economic Review 72(3):452466.Google Scholar
Forbes, Kristin J. 2000. ‘A Reassessment of the Relationship Between Inequality and Growth’. American Economic Review 90(4):869887.Google Scholar
Franzese, Robert J., and Hays, Jude C.. 2006. ‘Strategic Interaction Among EU Governments in Active Labor Market Policymaking: Subsidiarity and Policy Coordination Under the European Employment Strategy’. European Union Politics 7(2):167189.Google Scholar
Gawande, Kishore, and Bandyopadhyay, Usree. 2000. ‘Is Protection for Sale? Evidence on the Grossman-Helpman Theory of Endogenous Protection’. Review of Economics and Statistics 82(1):139152.Google Scholar
Goodhart, Lucy. 2008. ‘Trade Protection as Pork: Districts and Electoral Law as Determinants of Trade Policy’. Paper presented at the Annual Meeting of the Midwest Political Science Association. Chicago, IL, 2–6 April.Google Scholar
Gopinath, Munisamy, Pick, Daniel, and Li, Yonghai. 2004. ‘An Empirical Analysis of Productivity Growth and Industrial Concentration in US Manufacturing’. Applied Economics 36(1):17.Google Scholar
Grier, Kevin B., Munger, Michael C., and Roberts, Brian E.. 1994. ‘The Determinants of Industry Political Activity, 1978–1986’. American Political Science Review 88(4):911926.Google Scholar
Griffin, John. 2006. ‘Electoral Competition and Democratic Responsiveness: A Defense of the Marginality Hypothesis’. Journal of Politics 68(4):911921.Google Scholar
Grossman, Gene M., and Helpman, Elhanan. 1994. ‘Protection for Sale’. American Economic Review 84(4):833850.Google Scholar
Hansen, Wendy L. 1990. ‘The International Trade Commission and the Politics of Protectionism’. American Political Science Review 84(1):2146.Google Scholar
Hauk, William R. 2011. ‘Protection with Many Sellers: An Application to Legislatures with Malapportionment’. Economics and Politics 23(3):313344.Google Scholar
Holmes, Thomas J., and Stevens, John J.. 2004. ‘Spatial Distribution of Economic Activities in North America’. In J. Vernon Henderson and Jacques-François Thisse (eds), Handbook of Regional and Urban Economics, vol. 4 27972843. Amsterdam: Elsevier.Google Scholar
Irwin, Douglas A. 1998. ‘Changes in U.S. Tariffs: The Role of Import Prices and Commercial Policies’. American Economic Review 88(4):10151026.Google Scholar
Kono, Daniel Y. 2006. ‘Optimal Obfuscation: Democracy and Trade Policy Transparency’. American Political Science Review 100(3):369384.Google Scholar
Larcinese, Valentino, Rizzo, Leonzio, and Testa, Cecilia. 2006. ‘Allocating the U.S. Federal Budget to the States: The Impact of the President’. Journal of Politics 68(2):447456.Google Scholar
Lavergne, Real. 1983. The Political Economy of U.S. Tariffs: An Empirical Analysis. New York: Academic Press.Google Scholar
Lee, Jong-Wha, and Swagel, Phillip. 1997. ‘Trade Barriers and Trade Flows Across Countries and Industries’. Review of Economics and Statistics 79(3):372382.Google Scholar
Levendusky, Matthew S., Pope, Jeremy C., and Jackman, Simon D.. 2008. ‘Measuring District-Level Partisanship with Implications for the Analysis of U.S. Elections’. Journal of Politics 70(3):736753.Google Scholar
Levitt, Steven D., and Snyder, James M.. 1995. ‘Political Parties and the Distribution of Federal Outlays’. American Journal of Political Science 39(4):958980.Google Scholar
Lindbeck, Assar, and Weibull, Jörgen W.. 1987. ‘Balanced-Budget Redistribution as the Outcome of Political Competition’. Public Choice 52(3):273297.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Maggi, Giovanni, and Rodríguez-Clare, Andrés. 2000. ‘Import Penetration and the Politics of Trade Protection’. Journal of International Economics 51(2):287304.Google Scholar
Mansfield, Edward D., and Busch, Marc L.. 1995. ‘The Political Economy of Nontariff Barriers: A Cross-National Analysis’. International Organization 49(4):723749.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Marvel, Howard P., and Ray, Edward J.. 1983. ‘The Kennedy Round: Evidence on the Regulation of International Trade in the United States’. American Economic Review 73(1):190197.Google Scholar
McGillivray, Fiona. 1997. ‘Party Discipline as a Determinant of the Endogenous Formation of Tariffs’. American Journal of Political Science 41(2):584607.Google Scholar
McGillivray, Fiona. 2004. Privileging Industry: The Comparative Politics of Trade and Industrial Policy. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Milner, Helen V. 1988. Resisting Protectionism: Global Industries and the Politics of International Trade. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Muûls, Mirabelle, and Petropoulou, Dimitra. 2013. ‘A Swing-State Theory of Trade Protection in the Electoral College’. Canadian Journal of Economics 46(2):705724.Google Scholar
Nielson, Daniel L. 2003. ‘Supplying Trade Reform: Political Institutions and Liberalization in Middle-Income Presidential Democracies’. American Journal of Political Science 47(3):470491.Google Scholar
O’Halloran, Sharyn. 1994. Politics, Process, and American Trade Policy. Ann Arbor, MI: University of Michigan Press.Google Scholar
Olson, Mancur. 1965. The Logic of Collective Action. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Pierce, Justin R., and Schott, Peter K.. 2012. ‘A Concordance Between Ten-Digit U.S. Harmonized System Codes and SIC/NAICS Product Classes and Industries’. Journal of Economic and Social Measurement 37:6196.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Pincus, Jonathan J. 1975. ‘Pressure Groups and the Pattern of Tariffs’. Journal of Political Economy 83(4):757778.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rodrik, Dani. 1995. ‘Political Economy of Trade Policy’. In Gene Grossman and Kenneth Rogoff (eds), Handbook of International Economics, vol. 3 14571494. Amsterdam: North-Holland.Google Scholar
Rogowski, Ronald, Kayser, Mark, and Kotin, Daniel. 1999. ‘How Geographical Concentration Affects Industrial Influences: Evidence from U.S. Data’. Paper presented at the Annual Meeting of the American Political Science Association, Atlanta, GA, 2–5 September.Google Scholar
Rose, Andrew K. 2004. ‘Do WTO Members Have More Liberal Trade Policy?Journal of International Economics 63(2):209235.Google Scholar
Scheve, Kenneth, and Slaughter, Matthew J.. 2004. ‘Economic Insecurity and the Globalization of Production’. American Journal of Political Science 48(4):662674.Google Scholar
Schonhardt-Bailey, Cheryl. 1991. ‘Lessons in Lobbying for Free Trade in 19th-Century Britain: To Concentrate or Not’. American Political Science Review 85(1):3758.Google Scholar
Schott, Peter K. 2008. ‘The Relative Sophistication of Chinese Exports’. Economic Policy 23(53):549.Google Scholar
Subramanian, Arvind, and Wei, Shang-Jin. 2007. ‘The WTO Promotes Trade, Strongly But Unevenly’. Journal of International Economics 72(1):151175.Google Scholar
Trefler, Daniel. 1993. ‘Trade Liberalization and the Theory of Endogenous Protection: An Economic Study of U.S. Import Policy’. Journal of Political Economy 101(1):138160.Google Scholar
Link
Supplementary material: PDF

Lee supplementary material

Appendix

Download Lee supplementary material(PDF)
PDF 464.4 KB