Hostname: page-component-cd9895bd7-gvvz8 Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-12-22T15:29:45.408Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Case selection and Supreme Court pivots

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  02 December 2020

Greg Sasso*
Affiliation:
Emory University, Atlanta, USA
Gleason Judd
Affiliation:
Princeton University, Princeton, USA
*
*Corresponding author. Email: [email protected]

Abstract

How does the Rule of Four affect Supreme Court decisions? We show two effects of changing a “hearing pivot” justice who is decisive for case selection. First, a court with more extreme hearing pivots will hear cases with more moderate precedents. For example, as the conservative hearing pivot becomes more extreme, the court hears a broader range of cases with liberal status quo precedents. Second, more extreme hearing pivots shrink dispositional majorities and lead to more polarized rulings. If the median justice becomes more extreme without changing the hearing pivots, then rulings are more extreme. The effect on the range of cases heard, however, is smaller than that from changing hearing pivots. Finally, we show that case selection can also depend on non-median, non-hearing-pivot justices. Replacing an extreme justice with someone even more extreme can lead to a smaller set of heard cases, as final rulings can shift away from the binding hearing pivot, making status quo precedents more appealing.

Type
Research Note
Copyright
Copyright © The Author(s), 2020. Published by Cambridge University Press on behalf of the European Political Science Association

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

Beim, D (2017) Learning in the judicial hierarchy. Journal of Politics 79, 591604.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bonica, A, Chilton, A and Sen, M (2020) The “Odd Party Out” Theory of Certiorari. Available at SSRN 3205620.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bryan, AC and Ringsmuth, EM (2016) Jeremiad or weapon of words?: The power of emotive language in Supreme Court dissents. Journal of Law and Courts 4, 159185.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Buchanan, L and Yourish, K (2018) After Kennedy's exit, Supreme Court's center is likely to shift right. The New York Times. Available at https://www.nytimes.com/interactive/2018/06/27/us/politics/supreme-court-moves-right.html.Google Scholar
Callander, S and Clark, TS (2017) Precedent and doctrine in a complicated world. American Political Science Review 111, 184203.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cameron, CM and Kastellec, JP (2016) Are Supreme Court nominations a move-the-median game? American Political Science Review 110, 778797.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cameron, CM and Kornhauser, LA (2010) Modeling collegial courts (3): adjudication equilibria. NYU School of Law, Public Law Research Paper 0929.Google Scholar
Cameron, CM and Kornhauser, LA (2017) Theorizing the US Supreme Court. Oxford Research Encyclopedia of Politics.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Carrubba, CJ and Clark, TS (2012) Rule creation in a political hierarchy. American Political Science Review 106, 622643.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Carrubba, CJ, Friedman, B, Martin, AD and Vanberg, G (2012) Who controls the content of Supreme Court opinions? American Journal of Political Science 56, 400412.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Clark, TS and Kastellec, JP (2013) The Supreme Court and percolation in the lower courts: an optimal stopping model. Journal of Politics 75, 150168.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fang, S, Johnson, TR and Roberts, JM (2007) Will of the minority: Rule of Four on the United States Supreme Court. Available at SSRN 998492.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fox, J and Vanberg, G (2014) Narrow versus broad judicial decisions. Journal of Theoretical Politics 26, 355383.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ginsburg, RB (2010) The role of dissenting opinions. Minnesota Law Review 95, 1.Google Scholar
Johnson, B (2018) The Supreme Court's political docket: how ideology and the Chief Justice control the court's agenda and shape law. Connecticut Law Review 50, 581.Google Scholar
Kastellec, JP (2017) The judicial hierarchy. Oxford Research Encyclopedia of Politics.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kastellec, JP and Lax, JR (2008) Case selection and the study of judicial politics. Journal of Empirical Legal Studies 5, 407446.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Krehbiel, K (2007) Supreme Court appointments as a move-the-median game. American Journal of Political Science 51, 231240.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lax, JR (2003) Certiorari and compliance in the judicial hierarchy: discretion, reputation and the rule of four. Journal of Theoretical Politics 15, 6186.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lax, JR and Cameron, CM (2007) Bargaining and opinion assignment on the US Supreme Court. The Journal of Law, Economics, and Organization 23, 276302.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Moraski, BJ and Shipan, CR (1999) The politics of Supreme Court nominations: a theory of institutional constraints and choices. American Journal of Political Science 43, 10691095.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Parameswaran, G (2018) Endogenous cases and the evolution of the common law. The RAND Journal of Economics 49, 791818.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Parameswaran, G, Cameron, CM and Kornhauser, LA (2019) Bargaining and strategic voting on Appellate Courts. Available at SSRN 3397299.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Roeder, O (2018) John Roberts has cast a pivotal liberal vote only 5 times. FiveThirtyEight. Available at https://fivethirtyeight.com/features/john-roberts-has-cast-a-pivotal-liberal-vote-only-5-times/.Google Scholar
Supplementary material: PDF

Sasso and Judd supplementary material

Sasso and Judd supplementary material

Download Sasso and Judd supplementary material(PDF)
PDF 120.1 KB