Hostname: page-component-586b7cd67f-t7fkt Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-11-28T05:56:45.675Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Testing the Predictions of the Multidimensional Spatial Voting Model with Roll Call Data

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  10 September 2007

Gyung-Ho Jeong*
Affiliation:
Department of Political Science, Washington University in St. Louis, Campus Box 1063, One Brookings Drive, St. Louis, MO 63130, e-mail: [email protected]

Abstract

This paper develops a procedure for locating proposals and legislators in a multidimensional policy space by applying agenda-constrained ideal point estimation. Placing proposals and legislators on the same scale allows an empirical test of the predictions of the spatial voting model. I illustrate this procedure by testing the predictive power of the uncovered set—a solution concept of the multidimensional spatial voting model—using roll call data from the U.S. Senate. Since empirical tests of the predictive power of the uncovered set have been limited to experimental data, this is the first empirical test of the concept's predictive power using real-world data.

Type
Research Article
Copyright
Copyright © The Author 2007. Published by Oxford University Press on behalf of the Society for Political Methodology 

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

Aldrich, J., and Rohde, D. 1998. Theories of party in the legislature and the transition to republican rule in the house. Political Science Quarterly 112: 112–35.Google Scholar
Aldrich, J., and Rohde, D. 2001. The logic of conditional party government: Revisiting the electoral connection. In Congress reconsidered, ed. Dodd, L. and Oppenheimer, B., 262–92. Washington, DC: CQ Press.Google Scholar
Bafumi, J., Gelman, A., Park, D. K., and Kaplan, N. 2005. Practical issues in implementing and understanding Bayesian ideal point estimation. Political Analysis 13: 171–87.Google Scholar
Bianco, W. T., Jeliazkov, I., and Sened, I. 2004. The uncovered set and the limits of legislative action. Political Analysis 12: 256–76.Google Scholar
Bianco, W. T., Lynch, M. S., Miller, G. J., and Sened, I. 2006. A theory waiting to be discovered and used: A reanalysis of canonical experiments on majority rule decision-making. Journal of Politics 68: 838–51.Google Scholar
Bianco, W. T., and Sened, I. 2005. Uncovering evidence of conditional party government: Reassessing majority party influence in congress and state legislatures. American Political Science Review 99: 361–71.Google Scholar
Broz, J. L. 1997. The international origins of the Federal Reserve System. Itaca, NY: Cornell University Press.Google Scholar
Clinton, J., Jackman, S., and Rivers, D. 2004. The statistical analysis of roll call data. American Political Science Review 98: 355–70.Google Scholar
Clinton, J. D., and Meirowitz, A. 2001. Agenda constrained legislator ideal points and the spatial voting model. Political Analysis 9: 242–59.Google Scholar
Clinton, J. D., and Meirowitz, A. 2003. Integrating voting theory and roll call analysis: A framework. Political Analysis 11: 381–96.Google Scholar
Clinton, J. D., and Meirowitz, A. 2004. Testing explanations of strategic voting in legislatures: A reexamination of the compromise of 1790. American Journal of Political Science 48: 675–89.Google Scholar
Glass, C. 1927. An adventure in constructive finance. Garden City, NY: Arno Press.Google Scholar
Greider, W. 1987. Secrets of the temple: How the federal reserve runs the country. New York: Simon & Schuster Inc.Google Scholar
Hyndman, R. 1996. Computing and graphing highest density regions. American Statistician 50: 120–6.Google Scholar
Jackman, S. 2001. Multidimensional analysis of roll call data via Bayesian simulation: Identification, estimation, inference, and model checking. Political Analysis 9: 227–41.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Krehbiel, K. 1999. Paradoxes of parties in congress. Legislative Studies Quarterly 24: 3164.Google Scholar
Krehbiel, K. 2000. Party discipline and measures of partisanship. American Journal of Political Science 44: 212–27.Google Scholar
Krehbiel, K., and Rivers, D. 1988. The analysis of committee power: An application to senate voting on the minimum wage. American Journal of Political Science 32: 1151–74.Google Scholar
Londregan, J. 1999. Estimating legislators' preferred points. Political Analysis 8: 3556.Google Scholar
Martin, A. D., and Quinn, K. M. 2002. Dynamic ideal point estimation via Markov chain Monte Carlo for the U.S. Supreme Court, 1953-1999. Political Analysis 10: 134–53.Google Scholar
McKelvey, R. D. 1976. Intransitivities in multidimensional voting models and some implications for agenda control. Journal of Economic Theory 12: 472–82.Google Scholar
McKelvey, R. D. 1986. Covering dominance and institution free properties of social choice. American Journal of Political Science 30: 283314.Google Scholar
Miller, N. 1980. A new solution set for tournament and majority voting. American Journal of Political Science 24: 6896.Google Scholar
Oleszek, W. J. 1996. Congressional procedures and the policy process. Washington, DC: CQ Press.Google Scholar
Poole, K. T., and Rosenthal, H. 1997. Congress: A political economic history of roll call voting. New York: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Schofield, N. 1978. Instability of simple dynamic games. Review of Economic Studies 45: 575–94.Google Scholar
Shepsle, K., and Weingast, B. R. 1984. Uncovered sets and sophisticated voting outcomes with implications for agenda institutions. American Journal of Political Science 28: 4974.Google Scholar
Spiegelhalter, D. J., Thomas, A., and Best, N. G. 1999. WinBUGS Version 1.4. Cambridge: MRC Biostatistics Unit.Google Scholar