Hostname: page-component-cd9895bd7-dzt6s Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-12-27T10:01:29.824Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Multiple Hands on the Wheel: Empirically Modeling Partial Delegation and Shared Policy Control in the Open and Institutionalized Economy

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  04 January 2017

Robert J. Franzese Jr.*
Affiliation:
Department of Political Science, The University of Michigan, Ann Arbor, MI 48106-1248. e-mail: [email protected]

Abstract

The causal arguments of modern, positive political science often imply complex interactions among multiple explanatory factors. In one example from comparative and international political economy (C&IPE), sharing of monetary-policymaking control between partially autonomous central banks and politically responsive governments yields inflation as a convex combination of the rates that would have held under full-government and full-central-bank policy control. The anti-inflationary effect of central bank independence (autonomy plus conservatism: CBA) therefore depends on all political—economic variables to which central banks and governments respond differently, and, vice versa, CBA mutes the inflation effects of all such factors. Extending that logic of shared policy control to open political economies: insofar as domestic monetary authorities fix exchange rates, they effectively delegate inflation control to foreign (peg-currency) authorities, and policymakers in small and financially exposed economies must match domestic inflation to foreign (global) rates to avoid massive exchange-rate pressures. Thus, analogously, the domestic-inflation effects of fixed exchange rates and of monetary exposure depend on each other and on many other institutional and structural aspects of the domestic and foreign political economies, and, vice versa, the effects of all domestic and foreign political—economic conditions depend on degrees of exchange-rate fixity and financial openness at home and abroad. This article shows how to model such complexly interactive hypotheses empirically compactly and substantively meaningfully, and demonstrates the postwar inflation records of 21 developed democracies to favor such specifications decidedly over standard linear-additive or linear-interactive alternatives. The concluding sections discuss specific results and implications and then suggest several more potential applications of this general approach to further instances of shared policy control and other substantive contexts that induce the multiple, complex interactions characteristic of modern, positive political science in general and C&IPE especially.

Type
Research Article
Copyright
Copyright © Political Methodology Section of the American Political Science Association 2003 

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

Alesina, A., and Summers, L. 1993. “Central Bank Independence and Macroeconomic Performance: Some Comparative Evidence.” Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking 25(2): 151163.Google Scholar
Beck, N., and Katz, J. 2001. “Random Coefficient Models for Time-Series-Cross-Section Data.” Political Methodology 2001 Working Paper. (Available from http://web.polmeth.ufl.edu/articles/01/beck01b.pdf.) Google Scholar
Bernhard, W. 2002. Commitment, Continuity, and Change: Political Parties and Central Bank Independence. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press.Google Scholar
Bleaney, M. 1996. “Central Bank Independence, Wage-Bargaining Structure, and Macroeconomic Performance in OECD Countries.” Oxford Economic Papers 48:2038.Google Scholar
Calmfors, L., and Driffill, J. 1988. “Centralisation of Wage Bargaining and Macroeconomic Performance.” Economic Policy 6:1361.Google Scholar
Carlin, W., and Soskice, D. 1990. Macroeconomics and the Wage Bargain: A Modern Approach to Employment, Inflation and the Exchange Rate. Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Clark, W., Reichert, U. N., Lomas, S. L., and Parker, K. L. 1998. “International and Domestic Constraints on Political Business Cycles in OECD Economies.” International Organization 52:87120.Google Scholar
Cukierman, A. 1992. Central Bank Strategy, Credibility, and Independence: Theory and Evidence. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.Google Scholar
Cukierman, A., Edwards, S., and Tabellini, G. 1992. “Seigniorage and Political Instability.” American Economic Review 82:537555.Google Scholar
Eijffinger, S. C. W., and De Haan, J. 1996. “The Political Economy of Central Bank Independence.” Special Papers in International Economics #19. International Finance Section, Department of Economics, Princeton University.Google Scholar
Franzese, R. 1999. “Partially Independent Central Banks, Politically Responsive Governments, and Inflation.” American Journal of Political Science 43:681706.Google Scholar
Franzese, R. 2001. “Institutional and Sectoral Interactions in Monetary Policy and Wage-Price Bargaining.” In Varieties of Capitalism: The Institutional Foundations of Comparative Advantage. eds. Hall, P. and Soskice, D. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, pp. 104144.Google Scholar
Franzese, R. 2002a. “Electoral and Partisan Cycles in Economic Policies and Outcomes.” Annual Review of Political Science 5:369422.Google Scholar
Franzese, R. 2002b. Macroeconomic Policies of Developed Democracies. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Franzese, R. 2003a. “Quantitative Empirical Methods and Context Conditionality.” APSA-CP: Newsletter of the Organized Section on Comparative Politics of the American Political Science Association 14(1): 2024.Google Scholar
Franzese, R. 2003b. “Strategic Interactions of the ECB, Wage Bargainers, and Governments: A Review of Theory, Evidence, and Recent Experience.” In Institutional Conflicts and Complementarities: Monetary Policy and Wage Bargaining Institutions in EMU. eds. Mooslechner, P., Schuerz, M., Franzese, R. Amsterdam: Kluwer Academic Press.Google Scholar
Franzese, R., and Nooruddin, I. 2002. “Geographic and Partisan Bases of Representation: Distributive Politics and the Effective Number of Constituencies.” American Political Science Association Annual Meetings, Boston.Google Scholar
Gourevitch, P. 1986. Politics in Hard Times: Comparative Responses to International Economic Crises. Ithaca, NY: Cornell University Press.Google Scholar
Hall, P. 1986. Governing the Economy: The Politics of State Intervention in Britain and France. New York: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Hall, P. 2003. “Adapting Methodology to Ontology in Comparative Politics.” The Political Economist 11:17.Google Scholar
Hall, P., and Franzese, R. 1998. “Mixed Signals: Central Bank Independence, Coordinated Wage-Bargaining, and European Monetary Union.” International Organization 52(3): 505535.Google Scholar
Hall, P., and Soskice, D. 2001. Varieties of Capitalism: The Institutional Foundations of Comparative Advantage. Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Hirsch, F., and Goldthorpe, J. H., eds. 1978. The Political Economy of Inflation. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Iversen, T. June 1998. “The Political Economy of Inflation: Bargaining Structure or Central Bank Independence?Public Choice 99:237258.Google Scholar
Jonsson, G. 1995. “Institutions and Macroeconomic Outcomes—The Empirical Evidence.” Swedish Economic Policy Review 2:181212.Google Scholar
Katzenstein, P. 1985. Small States in World Markets: Industrial Policy in Europe. Ithaca, NY: Cornell University Press.Google Scholar
King, G., Keohane, R., and Verba, S. 1994. Designing Social Inquiry. Princeton: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Kraus, L.B., and Salant, W.S., eds. 1977. Worldwide Inflation: Theory and Recent Experience. Washington, DC: Brookings.Google Scholar
Layard, R., Nickell, S., and Jackman, R. 1991. Unemployment: Macroeconomic Performance and the Labour Market. New York: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Levitt, S. 1996. “How Do Senators Vote? Disentangling the Role of Voter Preferences, Party Affiliation, and Senate Ideology.” American Economic Review 86:425441.Google Scholar
Lindberg, L.N., and Maier, C.S., eds. 1985. The Politics of Inflation and Economic Stagnation. Washington, DC: Brookings.Google Scholar
Lohmann, S. 1992. “Optimal Commitment in Monetary Policy: Credibility Versus Flexibility.” American Economic Review 82:273286.Google Scholar
Lohmann, S. 1998. “Federalism and Central Bank Independence: The Politics and German Monetary Policy, 1957-1992.” World Politics 50(3): 401446.Google Scholar
Nordhaus, W. 1975. “The Political Business Cycle.” Review of Economic Studies 42(1): 169190.Google Scholar
Oatley, T. 1999. “How Constraining is Capital Mobility? The Partisan Hypothesis in an Open Economy.” American Journal of Political Science 43:10031027.Google Scholar
Posen, A. 1995a. “Central Bank Independence and Disinflationary Credibility: A Missing Link?Brookings Papers on Economic Activity.Google Scholar
Posen, A. 1995b. “Declarations Are Not Enough: Financial Sector Sources of Central Bank Independence.” NBER Macroeconomics Annual 10:253274.Google Scholar
Romer, D. 1993. “Openness and Inflation: Theory and Evidence.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 108:869903.Google Scholar
Quinn, D., and Inclan, C., 1997. “The Origins of Financial Openness: A Study of Current and Capital Account Liberalization.” American Journal of Political Science 41:771813.Google Scholar
Simmons, B. 1996. “Rulers of the Game: Central Bank Independence during the Interwar Years.” International Organization 50(3): 407443.Google Scholar
Soskice, D. 1990. “Wage Determination: The Changing Role of Institutions in Advanced Industrialized Countries.” Oxford Review of Economic Policy 6:3661.Google Scholar
Way, C. 2000. “Central Banks, Partisan Politics, and Macroeconomic Outcomes.” Comparative Political Studies 33(2): 196224.Google Scholar
Western, B. 1998. “Causal Heterogeneity in Comparative Research: A Bayesian Hierarchical Modeling Approach.” American Journal of Political Science 42:12331259.Google Scholar