Hostname: page-component-586b7cd67f-r5fsc Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-11-28T01:52:07.315Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Influence without Bribes: A Noncontracting Model of Campaign Giving and Policymaking

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  04 January 2017

Justin Fox
Affiliation:
Department of Political Science, Yale University, New Haven, CT 06520. e-mail: [email protected]
Lawrence Rothenberg*
Affiliation:
Department of Political Science, University of Rochester, Rochester, NY 14627
*
e-mail: [email protected] (corresponding author)

Abstract

Efforts to find empirical evidence that campaign money impacts policymaking choices have offered scant support for interest group influence. A possible explanation is that the hypothesis that those receiving campaign monies should adjust their policy choices to favor their donor requires the untenable assumption that interest groups and legislators can implement contracts. We develop a new, alternative, model in which legislators and interest groups cannot engage in any form of contracting, and legislators care about both the policy and fundraising implications of their policy choices. In our model, an interest group gives only to those it believes shares its policy preferences. Nonetheless, we show that the group's giving impacts incumbent policy choices. Importantly, when groups ideologically match, the relationship between actual contributions and bias is not straightforward. As long as a group is uncertain about a member's primitive policy preference, it can influence her policymaking even when it contributes to her challenger or abstains from giving altogether.

Type
Research Article
Copyright
Copyright © The Author 2011. Published by Oxford University Press on behalf of the Society for Political Methodology 

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

Footnotes

Authors' note: We thank Dan Butler, Steven Callander, Randy Calvert, Chris Chambers, Stacey Chen, Seok-Ju Cho, John Duggan, Andy Eggers, Sonying Fang, Mark Fey, Greg Huber, Jaehoon Kim, Carlos Maravall, Jianjun Miao, Juan Moreno-Ternero, Maggie Penn, David Primo, Alan Wiseman, and seminar participants at the Kellogg Graduate School of Management, New York University, the Stanford Graduate School of Business, the State University of New York at Stony Brook, the University of Michigan, the University of Minnesota, the University of Rochester, the University of Wisconsin, and Yale University for helpful comments and discussion on earlier versions of this paper. Supplementary materials for this article are available on the Political Analysis Web site.

References

Alvarez, Michael R. 1997. Information and elections. Ann Arbor, MI: University of Michigan Press.Google Scholar
Ansolabehere, Stephen, de Figueiredo, John M., and Snyder, James M. 2003. Why is there so little money in U. S. politics? Journal of Economic Perspectives 17(1): 105–30.Google Scholar
Austen-Smith, David. 1987. Interest groups, campaign contributions, and probabilistic voting. Public Choice 54(2): 123–39.Google Scholar
Ayres, Ian, and Bulow, Jeremey. 1998. The donation booth: Mandating donor anonymity to disrupt the market for political influence. Stanford Law Review 50(3): 837–91.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Baron, David P. 1994. Electoral competition with informed and uninformed voters. American Political Science Review 88(1): 3347.Google Scholar
Bartels, Larry M. 1986. Issue voting under uncertainty: An empirical test. American Journal of Political Science 30(4): 709–28.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bennedsen, Morten. 2003. Vote buying through resource allocation in a government controlled sector. Revista Economia Politica 93 (l): 4978.Google Scholar
Bergan, Daniel E. 2010. Estimating the effect of tobacco contributions on legislative behavior using panel data. Social Science Quarterly 91(3): 635–48.Google Scholar
Besley, Timothy, and Coate, Stephen. 2008. Issue unbundling via citzens' initiatives. Quarterly Journal of Political Science 3(4): 379–97.Google Scholar
Bronars, Stephen G., and Lott, John R. 1997. Do campaign contributions alter how a politician votes? Or, do donors support candidates who value the same things that they do? Journal of Law and Economics 40(1): 317–50.Google Scholar
Buckley v. Valeo. 1975.424 U. S. 1.Google Scholar
Canes-Wrone, Brandice, Herron, Michael C., and Shotts, Kenneth W. 2001. Leadership and pandering: A theory of executive policymaking. American Journal of Political Science 101(2): 273–88.Google Scholar
Chamon, Marcos, and Kaplan, Ethan. 2007. The iceberg theory of campaign contributions: Political threats and interest group behavior. Working paper. IMF.Google Scholar
Cho, Seok-Ju. 2009. Retrospective voting and political representation. American Journal of Political Science 53(2): 276–91.Google Scholar
Coate, Stephen, and Morris, Stephen. 1995. On the form of transfers to special interests. Journal of Political Economy 103(6): 1210–35.Google Scholar
Dal Bó, Ernesto. 2007. Bribing voters. American Journal of Political Science 51(4): 789803.Google Scholar
Dal Bó, Ernesto, Dal Bó, Pedro, and Di Tella, Rafael. 2006. ‘Plata o Plomo?’: Bribe and punishment in a theory of political influence. American Political Science Review 100(1): 4153.Google Scholar
Dal Bó, Ernesto, and Tella, Rafael Di. 2003. Capture by threat. Journal of Political Economy 111(5): 1123–54.Google Scholar
Dao, James. 2000. “The 2000 campaign: Gun control; Bradley tries to link Gore to the NRA.” New York Times, 11 February, sec A.Google Scholar
Denzau, Arthur T., and Munger, Michael C. 1986. Legislators and interest groups: How unorganized interests get represented. American Political Science Review 80(1): 89106.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Federal Election Commission v. National Conservative Political Action Committee. 1984.470 U. S. 480.Google Scholar
Gopoian, J. David. 1984. What makes a PAC tick? An analysis of the allocation patterns of economic interest groups. American Journal of Political Science 28(2): 259–81.Google Scholar
Grossman, Gene M., and Helpman, Elhanan. 1994. Protection for sale. American Economic Review 84(4): 833–50.Google Scholar
Grossman, Gene M., and Helpman, Elhanan. 1996. Electoral competition and special interest politics. Review of Economic Studies 63(2): 265–86.Google Scholar
Hall, Richard L., and Lin, Ann C. 2002. Campaign finance after the BCRA: Thinking oustide the box. Working paper. University of Michigan.Google Scholar
Hall, Richard L., and Wayman, Frank W. 1990. Buying time: Moneyed interests and the mobilization of bias in congressional committees. American Political Science Review 84(3): 797820.Google Scholar
Kroszner, Randall S., and Stratmann, Thomas. 1998. Interest-group competition and the organization of congress: Theory and evidence from financial services' political action committees. American Economic Review 88(5): 1163–87.Google Scholar
Levitt, Steven D. 1998. Are PACs trying to influence politicians or voters? Economics and Politics 10(1): 1935.Google Scholar
Mayhew, David R. 1975. Congress: The electoral connection. New Haven, CT: Yale University Press.Google Scholar
McCarty, Nolan, and Rothenberg, Lawrence S. 1996. Commitment and the campaign contribution contract. American Journal of Political Science 40(3): 872904.Google Scholar
Milyo, Jeffrey, Primo, David, and Groseclose, Timothy. 2000. Corporate PAC campaign contributions in perspective. Business and Politics 2(1): 7588.Google Scholar
Persily, Nathaniel, and Lammie, Kelli. 2004. Perceptions of corruption and campaign finance: When public opinion determines constitutional law. University of Pennsylvania Law Review 153(1): 119–80.Google Scholar
Poole, Keith T., Romer, Thomas, and Rosenthal, Howard. 1987. The revealed preferences of political action committees. American Economic Review 77(2): 298302.Google Scholar
Poole, Keith T., and Rosenthal, Howard. 1997. Congress: A political-economic history of roll call voting. New York: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Snyder, James M. 1991. On buying legislatures. Economics and Politics 3(2): 93103.Google Scholar
Tomz, Michael, and Van Houweling, Robert P. 2009. The electoral implications of candidate ambiguity. American Political Science Review 103(1): 8398.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wawro, Gregory. 2001. A panel probit analysis of campaign contributions and roll-call votes. American Journal of Political Science 45(3): 563–79.Google Scholar
Wright, John R. 1985. PACs, contributions, and roll calls: An organizational perspective. American Political Science Review 79(2): 400–14.Google Scholar
Supplementary material: PDF

Fox and Rothenberg supplementary material

Appendix

Download Fox and Rothenberg supplementary material(PDF)
PDF 339.4 KB