Hostname: page-component-cd9895bd7-hc48f Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-12-25T18:41:29.526Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Uncertainty and Turnout

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  04 January 2017

Mitchell S. Sanders*
Affiliation:
Department of Political Science, 570 Bellamy Building, Florida State University, Tallahassee, Florida 32306-2230. e-mail: [email protected]:http://garnet.acns.fsu.edu/∼msanders

Abstract

This article develops a model that simultaneously considers individual turnout and vote choice while also accounting for uncertainty about candidates. The theoretical development of this model implies that the effects of uncertainty on turnout vary with the strength of individual preferences. Application of the model to individual choice in the 1996 American presidential election confirms that decreasing uncertainty about the character traits of the candidates decreases the probability of abstention for individuals with strong preferences but increases the probability of abstention for individuals with weak preferences.

Type
Research Article
Copyright
Copyright © 2001 by the Society for Political Methodology 

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

Achen, Christopher H. 1992. “Social Psychology, Demographic Variables, and Linear Regression: Breaking the Iron Triangle in Voting Research.” Political Behavior 14: 195211.Google Scholar
Alvarez, R. Michael. 1997. Information and Elections. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Alvarez, R. Michael, and Brehm, John. 1997. “Are Americans Ambivalent Towards Racial Policies.” American Journal of Political Science 41: 345374.Google Scholar
Alvarez, R. Michael, and Franklin, Charles H. 1994. “Uncertainty and Political Perceptions.” Journal of Politics 56: 671688.Google Scholar
Alvarez, R. Michael, and Nagler, Jonathan. 1995. “Economics, Issues and the Perot Candidacy: Voter Choice in the 1992 Presidential Election.” American Journal of Political Science 39: 719744.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Alvarez, R. Michael, and Nagler, Jonathan. 1998. “Economics, Entitlements, and Social Issues: Voter Choice in the 1996 Presidential Election.” American Journal of Political Science 42: 13491363.Google Scholar
Bartels, Larry M. 1986. “Issue Voting Under Uncertainty: An Empirical Test.” American Journal of Political Science 30: 709728.Google Scholar
Born, Richard. 1990. “Surge and Decline, Negative Voting, and the Midterm Loss Phenomenon: A Simultaneous Choice Analysis.” American Journal of Political Science 34: 615645.Google Scholar
Brady, Henry E., and Ansolabehere, Stephen. 1989. “The Nature of Utility Functions in Mass Publics.” American Political Science Review 83: 143163.Google Scholar
Burden, Barry C., and Lacy, Dean. 1999. “Including Abstention in Vote Choice Models: A Rationale and Method Applied to the 1992 U.S. Presidential Election.” American Journal of Political Science 43: 233255.Google Scholar
Deacon, Robert, and Shapiro, Perry. 1975. “Private Preferences for Collective Goods Revealed Through Voting on Referenda.” American Economic Review 65: 943955.Google Scholar
Carpini, Delli, Michael, X., and Keeter, Scott. 1996. What Americans Know About Politics and Why It Matters. New Haven, CT: Yale University Press.Google Scholar
Downs, Anthony. 1957. An Economic Theory of Democracy. New York: Harper and Row.Google Scholar
Dubin, Jeffrey A., and Rivers, Douglas. 1990. “Selection Bias in Linear Regression, Logit and Probit Models.” Sociological Methods and Research 18: 360390.Google Scholar
Enelow, James, and Hinich, Melvin J. 1984. The Spatial Theory of Voting. New York: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Filer, John E., and Kenney, Lawrence W. 1980. “Voter Turnout and the Benefits of Voting.” Public Choice 35: 575585.Google Scholar
Franklin, Charles H. 1991. “Eschewing Obfuscation? Campaigns and the Perception of U.S. Senate Incumbents.” American Political Science Review 84: 11931214.Google Scholar
Glasgow, Garrett, and Michael Alvarez, R. 2000. “Uncertainty and Candidate Personality Traits.” American Politics Quarterly 28: 2649.Google Scholar
Greene, William H. 1997. Econometric Analysis. Upper Saddle River, NJ: Prentice-Hall.Google Scholar
Herron, Michael C. 1998. “The Presidential Election of 1988: Low Voter Turnout and the Defeat of Michael Dukakis.” Unpublished manuscript.Google Scholar
Long, J. Scott. 1997. Regression Models for Categorical and Limited Dependent Variables. Thousand Oaks, CA: Sage.Google Scholar
Luce, Duncan R. 1956. “Semiorders and a Theory of Utility Discrimination.” Econometrica 24: 178191.Google Scholar
Noll, Roger G. 1993. “Downsian Thresholds and the Theory of Political Advertising.” In Information, Participation and Choice, Grofman, Bernard, ed. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press.Google Scholar
Page, Benjamin I. 1978. Choices and Echoes in Presidential Elections. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
Riker, William H., and Ordeshook, Peter C. 1968. “A Theory of the Calculus of Voting.” American Political Science Review 62: 2542.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rosenstone, Steven, and Hansen, John Mark. 1993. Mobilization, Participation, and Democracy in America. New York: Macmillan.Google Scholar
Sanders, Mitchell S. 1999a. “Unified Models of Turnout and Vote Choice for Two-Candidate and Three-Candidate Elections.” Political Analysis 7: 89115.Google Scholar
Sanders, Mitchell S. 1999b. “The Dual Effects of Information on Voter Turnout.” Unpublished manuscript.Google Scholar
Shepsle, Kenneth A. 1972. “The Strategy of Ambiguity.” American Political Science Review 66: 555568.Google Scholar
Wolfinger, Raymond E., and Rosenstone, Steven J. 1980. Who Votes? New Haven, CT: Yale University Press.Google Scholar